Skip to main content Accessibility help
×
Hostname: page-component-7479d7b7d-wxhwt Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-07-13T03:43:10.436Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

TEN - Why Governments Tax or Subsidize Agricultural Trade

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  05 July 2011

Kishore Gawande
Affiliation:
Texas A&M University
Bernard Hoekman
Affiliation:
World Bank in Washington, DC
Kym Anderson
Affiliation:
University of Adelaide
Get access

Summary

Why governments choose the instruments they do to restrict or promote trade is not well understood by scholars in economics and political science (Rodrik 1995). That poor understanding helps explain why much of the theoretical and empirical work in international economics has failed to have much of an impact on policy makers, especially when it comes to agricultural trade policies. In practice, episodes of liberalization and reform are often made in the context of crises or under pressure from outside forces (e.g., trade negotiations) rather than from an internal consensus among policy makers about the efficiency gains from agricultural reform. There are significant differences across sectors, countries, and time, but when it comes to agriculture, government interventions across the world have been particularly widespread and persistent, with significant variance in the aim of policies and the types of instruments used.

This chapter is motivated by the question of what motivates governments to tax or subsidize imports and exports. This question, in turn, is important in understanding the constraints that governments perceive they face economically and politically, and in understanding the broader question of the choice of instruments to regulate trade. Better understanding of this question should help in designing multilateral negotiations and agreements that will lead to real reform. A more informed view of the political economy forces that underpin status quo policies is critical in designing and implementing reform strategies.

Type
Chapter
Information
Publisher: Cambridge University Press
Print publication year: 2010

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

References

Anderson, K. (1995), “Lobbying Incentives and the Pattern of Protection in Rich and Poor Countries,”Economic Development and Cultural Change 43: 401–23.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Anderson, K., Croser, J., Sandri, D. and Valenzuela, E. (2010), “Agricultural Distortion Patterns since the 1950s: What Needs Explaining?” Ch. 2 in this volume.
Anderson, K., Hayami, Y. and Others (1986), The Political Economy of Agricultural Protection: East Asia in International perspective, Sydney: Allen and Unwin.Google Scholar
Anderson, K., Martin, W. and Valenzuela, E. (2006), “The Relative Importance of Global Agricultural Subsidies and Market Access,”World Trade Review 5(3): 357–76.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Anderson, K., Kurzweil, M., Martin, W., Sandri, D. and Valenzuela, E. (2008), “Measuring Distortions to Agricultural Incentives, Revisited,”World Trade Review 7(4): 1–30.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Anderson, K. and Valenzuela, E. (2008), Global Estimates of Distortions to Agricultural Incentives, 1955 to 2007, database available at http://www.worldbank.org/agdistortionsGoogle Scholar
Baldwin, R.E. (1985), The Political Economy of US Import Policy, Cambridge MA: MIT Press.Google Scholar
Baron, D.P. (1994), “Electoral Competition with Informed and Uninformed Voters,”American Political Science Review 88: 33–47.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Beck, T., Clarke, G., Groff, A. and Keefer, P. (2001), “New Tools in Comparative Political Economy: The Database of Political Institutions,”World Bank Economic Review 15(1): 165–76.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Beck, T., Keefer, P.E. and Clarke, G.R. (2008), Database of Political Institutions, accessible at http://go.worldbank.org/2EAGGLRZ40.Google Scholar
Bhagwati, J. and Ramaswami, V.K. (1963), “Domestic Distortions, Tariffs and the Theory of the Optimum Subsidy,”Journal of Political Economy 71: 44–50.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Gorter, H. and Swinnen, J.F.M. (2002), “Political Economy of Agricultural Policy,” pp. 1893–1943 in Gardner, B.L. and Rausser, G. (eds.), Handbook of Agricultural Economics, vol. 2B, Amsterdam, Elsevier.Google Scholar
Deardorff, A.V. (1987), “Why Do Governments Prefer Nontariff Barriers?”Carnegie-Rochester Conference Series on Public Policy 26: 191–216.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Dutt, P. and Mitra, D. (2002), “Endogenous Trade Policy Through Majority Voting: An Empirical Investigation,”Journal of International Economics 58: 107–33.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Dutt, P. and Mitra, D. (2005), “Political Ideology and Endogenous Trade Policy: An Empirical Investigation,”Review of Economics and Statistics 87: 59–72.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Dutt, P. and Mitra, D. (2006), “Labor versus Capital in Trade-Policy: The Role of Ideology and Inequality,”Journal of International Economics 69(2): 310–20.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Gawande, K. and Bandyopadhyay, S. (2000), “Is Protection for Sale? A Test of the Grossman–Helpman Theory of Endogenous Protection,”Review of Economics and Statistics 82: 139–52.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Gawande, K. and Hoekman, B. (2006), “Lobbying and Agricultural Policy in the United States,”International Organization 60(3): 527–61.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Grossman, G.M. and Helpman, E. (1994), “Protection for Sale,”American Economic Review 84: 833–50.Google Scholar
Grossman, G.M. and Helpman, E. (1996), “Electoral Competition and Special Interest Politics,”Review of Economic Studies 63: 265–86.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hoekman, B., Ng, F. and Olarreaga, M. (2004), “Reducing Agricultural Tariffs versus Domestic Support: What is More Important for Developing Countries?”World Bank Economic Review 18(2): 175–204.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Honma, M. (1993), “Japan's Agricultural Policy and Protection Growth,” in Ito, T. and Krueger, A.O. (eds.), Trade and Protectionism, Chicago: University of Chicago Press.Google Scholar
Johnson, H.G. (1965), “Optimal Trade Interventions in the Presence of Domestic Distortions,” pp. 3–34 in Caves, R., Johnson, H. G. and Kenen, P. (eds.), Trade, Growth and Balance of Payments, Amsterdam: North-Holland.Google Scholar
Mayer, W. (1984), “Endogenous Tariff Formation,”American Economic Review 74: 970–85.Google Scholar
McMillan, M. (2001), “Why Kill the Golden Goose? A Political-Economy Model of Export Taxation,”Review of Economics and Statistics 83(1): 170–84.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Naoi, M. (2009), “Shopping for Protection: The Politics of Choosing Trade Instruments in a Partially-Legalized World,”International Studies Quarterly 53(2), forthcoming.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Olper, A. and Raimondi, V. (2010), “Constitutional Rules and Agricultural Policy Outcomes,” Ch. 14 in this volume.
Pender, J. (1999), “Rural Population Growth, Agricultural Change and Natural Resource Management in Developing Countries: A Review of Hypothesis and Some Evidence from the Honduras,” EPTD Discussion Paper 48, International Food Policy Research Institute, Washington DC.
Rodrik, D. (1986), “Tariffs, Subsidies and Welfare with Endogenous Policy,”Journal of International Economics 21: 285–96.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Rodrik, D. (1992), “Conceptual Issues in the Design of Trade Policy for Industrialization,”World Development 20: 301–20.Google Scholar
Rodrik, D. (1995), “Political Economy of Trade Policy,” pp. 1457–94 in Grossman, G.M. and Rogoff, K. (eds.), Handbook of International Economics, Vol. 3, Amsterdam: North-Holland.Google Scholar
,World Bank (2007), World Development Indicators 2007, Washington DC: World Bank.Google Scholar

Save book to Kindle

To save this book to your Kindle, first ensure coreplatform@cambridge.org is added to your Approved Personal Document E-mail List under your Personal Document Settings on the Manage Your Content and Devices page of your Amazon account. Then enter the ‘name’ part of your Kindle email address below. Find out more about saving to your Kindle.

Note you can select to save to either the @free.kindle.com or @kindle.com variations. ‘@free.kindle.com’ emails are free but can only be saved to your device when it is connected to wi-fi. ‘@kindle.com’ emails can be delivered even when you are not connected to wi-fi, but note that service fees apply.

Find out more about the Kindle Personal Document Service.

Available formats
×

Save book to Dropbox

To save content items to your account, please confirm that you agree to abide by our usage policies. If this is the first time you use this feature, you will be asked to authorise Cambridge Core to connect with your account. Find out more about saving content to Dropbox.

Available formats
×

Save book to Google Drive

To save content items to your account, please confirm that you agree to abide by our usage policies. If this is the first time you use this feature, you will be asked to authorise Cambridge Core to connect with your account. Find out more about saving content to Google Drive.

Available formats
×