Skip to main content Accessibility help
×
Hostname: page-component-77c89778f8-rkxrd Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-07-24T10:31:35.842Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Bibliography

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  22 September 2009

Serge-Christophe Kolm
Affiliation:
Ecole des Hautes Etudes en Sciences Sociales, Paris
Get access

Summary

Image of the first page of this content. For PDF version, please use the ‘Save PDF’ preceeding this image.'
Type
Chapter
Information
Reciprocity
An Economics of Social Relations
, pp. 354 - 377
Publisher: Cambridge University Press
Print publication year: 2008

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

References

Adam, C., and Tannery, P. (eds.) (1965), René Descartes: Oeuvres Complètes, Paris: Vrin.Google Scholar
Adams, J. S. (1963), ‘Wage inequities, productivity and work quality’, Industrial Relations 3: 9–16.Google Scholar
Adams, J. S. (1965), ‘Inequity in social exchange’, in: Berkowitz, L. (ed.), Advances in Experimental Social Psychology, vol. II, New York: Academic Press, 267–99.Google Scholar
Adams, J. S., and Rosenbaum, W. B. (1964), ‘The relationship of worker productivity to cognitive dissonance about wage inequalities’, Journal of Abnormal and Social Psychology 69: 19–25.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Adolphs, R. (2000), ‘Social cognition and the human brain’, Trends in Cognitive Science 3: 469–79.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Akerlof, G. (1982), ‘Labor contract as partial gift exchange’, Quarterly Journal of Economics 97: 543–69.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Alesina, A., and Ferrara, E. (2000a), ‘Participation in heterogeneous communities’, Quarterly Journal of Economics 115 (3): 847–904.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Alesina, A., and Ferrara, E. (2000b), Who Trusts Others?, Discussion Paper no. 2646, Centre for Economic Policy Research, London.Google Scholar
Alesina, A., and Ferrara, E. (2002), ‘Who trusts others?’, Journal of Public Economics 85 (2), 207–34.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Altman, I. (1973), ‘Reciprocity of interpersonal exchange’, Journal of Theory of Social Behaviour 3: 249–61.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ames, R., and Marwell, G. (1979), ‘Experiments on the provision of public goods: resources, interest, group size, and the free-rider problem’, American Journal of Sociology 84: 1335–60.Google Scholar
Andreoni, J. (1988a), ‘Privately provided public goods in a large economy: the limits of altruism’, Journal of Public Economics 35 (1): 57–73.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Andreoni, J. (1988b), ‘Why free ride? Strategies and learning in public goods experiments’, Journal of Public Economics 37 (3): 291–304.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Andreoni, J. (1989), ‘Giving with impure altruism: applications to charity and Ricardian equivalence’, Journal of Political Economy 97: 1447–58.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Andreoni, J. (1990), ‘Impure altruism and donations to public goods: a theory of warm-glow giving’, Economic Journal 100: 464–77.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Andreoni, J. (1995), ‘Warm-glow versus cold-prickle: the effects of positive and negative framing on cooperation in experiments’, Quarterly Journal of Economics 110 (1): 1–21.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Archibald, G. C., and Donaldson, D. (1976), ‘Non-paternalism and the basic theorems of welfare economics’, Canadian Journal of Economics 9: 492–507.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Aronfreed, J. (1970), ‘The socialization of altruistic and sympathetic behavior: some theoretical and experimental analyses’, in: Macaulay, J. and Berkowitz, L. (eds.), Altruism and Helping Behavior, New York: Academic Press, 103–26.Google Scholar
Aronfreed, J., and Paskal, V. (1965), ‘Altruism, empathy, and the conditioning of positive affect’, unpublished manuscript, University of Pennsylvania.Google Scholar
Arrow, K. J. (1972), ‘Gifts and exchanges’, Philosophy and Public Affairs1: 343–62.Google Scholar
Arrow, K. J. (1979), Optimal and Voluntary Income Distribution, Technical Report no. 288 (Economic Series), Institute for Mathematical Studies in the Social Sciences, Stanford University, CA., and in (1981), Economic Welfare and the Economics of Soviet Socialism: Essays in Honor of Abram Bergson, Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 267–88.Google Scholar
Axelrod, R. (1981), ‘Emergence of cooperation among egoists’, American Political Science Review 75: 306–18.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Axelrod, R. (1984), The Evolution of Cooperation, New York: Academic Press.Google Scholar
Banks, S. (1979), ‘Gift-giving: a review and an interactive paradigm’, in: Wilkie, W. (ed.), Advances in Consumer Research, vol. VI, Ann Arbor: Michigan Association for Consumer Research, 319–24.Google Scholar
Baron, J. N. (1988), ‘The employment relation as a social relation’, Journal of the Japanese and International Economies 2: 492–525.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Basu, K. (1977), ‘Information and strategy in iterated prisoners’ dilemma’, Theory and Decision 8: 293–8.Google Scholar
Basu, K. (1987), ‘Modelling finitely repeated games with uncertain termination’, Economic Letters 23: 147–51.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Becker, G. S. (1961), Notes on an Economic Analysis of Philanthropy, working paper, National Bureau of Economic Research, New York.Google Scholar
Becker, G. S. (1974), ‘A theory of social interaction’, Journal of Political Economy 82 (6): 1063–93.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Becker, G. S. (1976a), ‘Altruism, egoism and genetic fitness: economics and sociobiology’, Journal of Economic Literature 14: 817–26.Google Scholar
Becker, G. S. (1976b), The Economic Approach to Human Behavior, Chicago: University of Chicago Press.Google Scholar
Becker, G. S. (1981), ‘Altruism in the family and selfishness in the market place’, Econometrica 48: 1–15.Google Scholar
Becker, H. (1956a), ‘Empathy, sympathy and Scheler’, International Journal of Sociometry1: 15–22.Google Scholar
Becker, H. (1956b), Man in Reciprocity: Introductory Lectures on Culture, Society and Personality, New York: Praeger.Google Scholar
Benabou, R., and Tirole, J. (2003), ‘Intrinsic and extrinsic motivation’, Review of Economic Studies 70 (3): 489–520.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ben-Porath, Y. (1980), ‘The F-connection: families, friends, and firms and the organization of exchange’, Population and Development Review 6: 1–30.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bentham, J. (1789), Principles of Morals and Legislation, Oxford: Clarendon Press.Google Scholar
Bereby-Meyer, Y., and Niederle, M. (2005), ‘Fairness in bargaining’, Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization 56 (2): 173–86.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Berg, J., Dickhaut, J. and K. A. McCabe, (1995), ‘Trust, reciprocity and social history’, Games and Economic Behavior 10: 122–42.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bergstrom, T. C. (1970), ‘A “Scandinavian consensus” solution for efficient income distribution among non-malevolent consumers’, Journal of Economic Theory 2: 383–98.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Berkowitz, L. (1966), ‘A laboratory investigation of social class and national differences in helping behavior’, International Journal of Psychology1.Google Scholar
Berkowitz, L. (1968), ‘Responsibility, reciprocity, and social distance in help-giving: an experimental investigation of English social class differences’, Journal of Experimental Psychology 4: 46–63.Google Scholar
Berkowitz, L. (1970), ‘The self, selfishness and altruism’, in: Macaulay, J and Berkowitz, L. (eds.), Altruism and Helping Behavior, New York: Academic Press, 143–54.Google Scholar
Berkowitz, L. (1971), ‘Social norms, feelings and other factors affecting helping behavior and altruism’, unpublished manuscript, University of Wisconsin.Google Scholar
Berkowitz, L., and Daniels, L. (1963), ‘Responsibility and dependency’, Journal of Abnormal and Social Psychology 66: 429–37.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Berkowitz, L., and Friedman, P. (1967), ‘Some social class differences in helping behavior’, Journal of Personality and Social Psychology 5: 217–25.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bernheim, B. D., Shleifer, A. and Summers, L. H. (1985), ‘The strategic bequest motive’, Journal of Political Economy 93: 1045–76.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bewley, T. F. (1995), ‘A depressed labor market as explained by participants’, American Economic Review 85 (2): 250–4.Google Scholar
Bewley, T. F. (1999), ‘Work motivation’, Review of the Federal Reserve Bank of St Louis 81 (3): 35–50.Google Scholar
Bianchi, M. (1993), ‘How to learn sociality: true and false solutions to Mandeville's problem’, History of Political Economy 25 (2): 209–38.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Binmore, K., McCarthy, J., Ponti, G., Samuelson, L. and Shaked, A. (2002), ‘A backward induction experiment’, Journal of Economic Theory 104 (1): 48–88.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bishop, J. (1987), ‘The recognition and reward of employee performance’, Journal of Labor Economics 5: S36–S56.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Boehm, C. (1993), ‘Egalitarian behavior and reverse dominance hierarchy’, Current Anthropology 34 (3): 227–40.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bolton, G., Brandts, J. and Ockenfels, A. (1998), ‘Measuring motivations for the reciprocal responses observed in simple dilemma games’, Experimental Economics 1 (3): 207–19.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bolton, G. and Ockenfels, A. (1998), ‘Strategy and equity: an ERC-analysis of the Güth–van Damme game’, Journal of Mathematical Psychology 42 (2): 215–26.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bolton, G. and Ockenfels, A. (2000), ‘ERC: a theory of equity, reciprocity and competition’, American Economic Review 90 (1): 166–93.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Boudon, R. (1979), La logique du social, Paris: Hachette.Google Scholar
Boulding, K. (1973), The Economy of Love and Fear, Belmont, CA: Wadsworth.Google Scholar
Bowles, S. (1998), ‘Endogenous preferences: the cultural consequences of markets and other economic institutions’, Journal of Economic Literature 36 (1): 75–111.Google Scholar
Bryan, J. H., and Test, M. A. (1967), ‘Models and helping: naturalistic studies in aiding behavior’, Journal of Personality and Social Psychology 6: 400–7.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Buchan, N., Croson, R. and Dawes, R. (2002), Swift Neighbors and Persistent Strangers: A Cross-Cultural investigation of Trust and Reciprocity in Social Exchange, paper presented at the Microeconomic Seminar, Universitat Pompeu Fabra, Barcelona, 17 December.Google Scholar
Camerer, C. (1988), ‘Gifts as economic signals and social symbols’, American Journal of Sociology 94: 5180–214.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Campbell, D. T. (1965), ‘Ethnocentric and other altruistic motives’, in: Levine, D. (ed.), Nebraska Symposium on Motivation, Lincoln: University of Nebraska Press, 283–311.Google Scholar
Carmichael, H. L., and Macleod, W. B. (1997), ‘Gift giving and the evolution of cooperation’, International Economic Review 38 (3): 485–509.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Charness, G., and Haruvy, E. (2002), ‘Altruism, equity, and reciprocity in a gift-exchange experiment: an encompassing approach’, Games and Economic Behavior 40 (2): 203–31.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Charness, G., and Rabin, M. (2002), ‘Understanding social preferences with simple tests’, Quarterly Journal of Economics 117 (3): 817–69.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Cialdini, R. C., and M. R. Trost (1998), ‘Social influence: social norms, conformity, and compliance’, in: Gilbert, D. T., Fiske, S. T. and Lindzey, G. (eds.), The Handbook of Social Psychology, Boston: McGraw-Hill, 151–85.Google Scholar
Coate, S., and Ravallion, M. (1993), ‘Reciprocity without commitment’, Journal of Economic Development 40: 1–24.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Collard, D. (1978), Altruism and the Economy: A Study in Non-Selfish Economics, Oxford: Martin Robertson.Google Scholar
Coricelli, G., K. McCabe and V. Smith (2000), ‘Theory-of-mind mechanism in personal exchange’, in: Hotano, G., Okada, N. and Tanabe, H. (eds.), Affective Minds, Amsterdam: Elsevier, 249–59.Google Scholar
Cox, J. C. (2004), ‘How to identify trust and reciprocity’, Games and Economic Behavior 46 (2): 260–81.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Croson, R. T. A. (1999), Theories of Altruism and Reciprocity: Evidence from Linear Public Good Games, discussion paper, Wharton School, University of Pennsylvania.Google Scholar
Daly, G., and Giertz, F. (1972), ‘Welfare economics and welfare reform’, American Economic Review 62 (1): 131–8.Google Scholar
Danner, P. L. (1973), ‘Sympathy and exchangeable value: keys to Adam Smith's social philosophy’, Review of Social Economy 34 (3): 317–31.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Darwin, C. (1871 [1981]), La descendance de l'homme, et la sélection sexuelle (trans. Barbier, E.), Brussels: Editions Complexe.Google Scholar
Dasgupta, P. (2000), ‘Economic progress and the idea of social capital’, in: Dasgupta, P. and Serageldin, I. (eds.), Social Capital: A Multifaceted Perspective, World Bank: Washington, DC, 325–424.Google Scholar
Davis, J. (1975), ‘The particular theory of exchange’, Archives Européennes de Sociologie 16 (2): 151–68.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Dawes, R., and Thaler, R. (1982), ‘Cooperation’, Journal of Economic Perspectives 2: 187–97.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Dawes, R. M., Kragt, A. J. C. and Orbell, J. M. (1988), ‘Not me or thee but we: the importance of group identity in eliciting cooperation in dilemma situations’, Acta Psychologica 68: 83–97.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Doland, D., and Adelberg, K. (1967), ‘The learning of sharing behavior’, Child Development 38: 695–700.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Dufwenberg, M., and Kirchsteiger, G. (2004), ‘A theory of sequential reciprocity’, Games and Economic Behavior 47 (2): 268–98.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Durkheim, E. (1958), Professional Ethics and Civic Morals (trans. C. Brookfield), Glencoe, IL: Free Press.Google Scholar
Edgeworth, F. Y. (1881), Mathematical Psychics: An Essay on the Application of Mathematics to the Moral Sciences, London: London School of Economics.Google Scholar
Eglar, Z. E. (1958), Vartan Bhanji: Institutionalized Reciprocity in a Changing Punjab Village, PhD thesis, Columbia University NY.Google Scholar
Ekstein, R. (1972), ‘Psychoanalysis and education for the facilitation of positive human qualities’, Journal of Social Issues 28 (3): 71–85.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Elster, J. (1989), The Cement of Society: A Study of Social Order, Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Elster, J. (1998), ‘Emotions and economic theory’, Journal of Economic Literature 36: 47–74.Google Scholar
Elster, J. (2007), Disinterestedness, Lectures at the College de France.Google Scholar
Elster, J. (forthcoming), Le Désintéressement, Paris: Editions du Seuil.Google Scholar
Falk, A., Fehr, E. and Fischbacher, U. (2000), Informal Sanctions, Working Paper no. 59, Institute for Empirical Research in Economics, University of Zurich.Google Scholar
Falk, A., Fehr, E. and Fischbacher, U. (2003), ‘On the nature of fair behavior’, Economic Inquiry 41 (1): 20–6.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Falk, A., and Fischbacher, U. (1999), A Theory of Reciprocity, Working Paper no. 6, Institute for Empirical Research in Economics, University of Zurich.Google Scholar
Falk, A., and Fischbacher, U. (2001), A Theory of Reciprocity, Discussion Paper no. 3014, Centre for Economic Policy Research, London.Google Scholar
Falk, A., and U. Fischbacher (2005), ‘Modeling strong reciprocity’, in: Gintis, H., Bowles, S., Boyd, R. and Fehr, E. (eds.), Moral Sentiments and Material Interests: The Foundations of Cooperation in Economic Life, Cambridge, MA: MIT Press, 193–214.Google Scholar
Fehr, E., and Gächter, S. (1998), ‘How effective are trust- and reciprocity-based incentives?’, in: A. Ben-Ner and L. Putterman, Economics, Values and Organizations, Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 337–63.Google Scholar
Fehr, E., and Gächter, S. (2000a), ‘Fairness and retaliation: the economics of reciprocity’, Journal of Economic Perspectives 14 (3): 159–81.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Fehr, E., and Gächter, S. (2000b), ‘Cooperation and punishment in public goods experiments’, American Economic Review 90 (4): 980–94.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Fehr, E., and Gächter, S. (2002), Do Incentive Contracts Crowd out Voluntary Cooperation?, Working Paper no. 34, University of Zurich.Google Scholar
Fehr, E., Gächter, S. and Kirchsteiger, G. (1996), ‘Reciprocal fairness and noncompensating wage differentials’, Journal of Institutional and Theoretical Economics 152 (4): 608–40.Google Scholar
Fehr, E., Gächter, S. and Kirchsteiger, G. (1997), ‘Reciprocity as a contract enforcement device: experimental evidence’, Econometrica 65 (4): 833–60.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Fehr, E., Kirchler, E., Weichbold, A. and Gächter, S. (1998), ‘When social norms overpower competition: gift exchange in experimental labor markets’, Journal of Labor Economics 16 (2): 324–51.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Fehr, E., Kirchsteiger, G. and Riedl, A. (1993), ‘Does fairness prevent market clearing? An experimental investigation’, Quarterly Journal of Economics 108 (2): 437–59.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Fehr, E., and Schmidt, K. M. (1999), ‘A theory of fairness, competition and cooperation’, Quarterly Journal of Economics 114 (3): 817–68.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Fehr, E., and Schmidt, K. M. (2002), ‘Fairness, incentives, and contractual choices’, European Economic Review 44 (4–6): 1057–68.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Fehr, E., and K. M. Schmidt (2003), ‘Theories of fairness and reciprocity: evidence and economic applications’, in: Dewatripont, M., Hansen, L. P. and Turnovsky, S. J. (eds.), Advances in Economics and Econometrics: 8th World Congress. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 208–57.Google Scholar
Fellner, C. H., and J.-R. Marshall (1970), ‘Kidney donors’, in: Macaulay, J. and Berkowitz, L. (eds.), Altruism and Helping Behavior, New York: Academic Press, 269–81.Google Scholar
Firth, R. (ed.) (1957), Man and Culture: An Evaluation of the Work of Bronislaw Malinowski, New York: Humanities Press.Google Scholar
Fischbacher, U., Gächter, S. and Fehr, E. (1999), Are People Conditionally Cooperative? Evidence from a Public Good Experiment, Working Paper no. 16, Institute for Empirical Research in Economics, University of Zurich.Google Scholar
Frank, R. H. (1988), Passions within Reason: The Strategic Role of the Emotions, New York: Norton.Google Scholar
Frank, R. H. (1990), ‘A theory of moral sentiments’, in: Mansbridge, J. (ed.), Beyond Self-Interest, Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 71–96.Google Scholar
Freuchen, P. (1961), Book of the Eskimos, Cleveland and New York: World Publishing.Google Scholar
Frey, B. (1997), Not Just for the Money: An Economic Theory of Personal Motivation, Cheltenham: Edward Elgar.Google Scholar
Friedrichs, R. W. (1960), ‘Alter versus ego: an exploratory assessment of altruism’, American Sociological Review 25: 496–508.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Frisch, D. M., and Greenberg, M. S. (1968), ‘Reciprocity and intentionality in the giving of help’, in: Proceedings of the 76th Annual Convention of the American Psychological Association, vol. III, Washington, DC: American Psychological Assocciation, 383–4.Google Scholar
Gächter, S., and Falk, A. (2002), ‘Population and reciprocity: consequences for the labour relation’, Scandinavian Journal of Econometrics104: 1–27.Google Scholar
Geanakoplos, J., Pearce, D. and Stacchetti, E. (1989), ‘Psychological games and sequential rationality’, Games and Economic Behavior 1 (1): 60–79.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Gérard-Varet, L.-A., Kolm, S.-Ch. and Ythier, J. Mercier (eds.) (2000), The Economics of Reciprocity, Giving and Altruism, London: Macmillan.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Gergen, K. J., Gergen, M. and Meter, K. (1972), ‘Individual orientations to prosocial behavior’, Journal of Social Issues 28 (3): 105–30.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Gergen, K. J., , M. S. Greenberg and Willis, R. H. (eds.) (1980), Social Exchange: Advances in Theory and Research, New York: Plenum Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Gide, C. (1905), Economie sociale, Paris: Librairie de la Société du Recueil général des lois et des arrêts.Google Scholar
Gintis, H. (2000), ‘Strong reciprocity and human sociality’, Journal of Theoretical Biology 206: 169–79.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Gintis, H., Bowles, S., Boyd, R. and Fehr, E. (eds.) (2005), Moral Sentiments and Material Interests: The Foundations of Cooperation in Economic Life, Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.Google Scholar
Glaeser, E. L., Laibson, D., Scheinkman, J. A. and Sautter, C. I. (2000), ‘Measuring trust’, Quarterly Journal of Economics 115: 811–46.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Goeree, J. K., and Holt, C. A. (2000), ‘Asymmetric inequality aversion and noisy behaviour in alternating-offer bargaining games’, European Economic Review 44 (4–6): 1079–89.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Goldfarb, R. S. (1970), ‘Pareto optimal redistribution: comment’, American Economic Review 60 (4): 994–6.Google Scholar
Goodstadt, M. S. (1971), ‘Helping and refusal to help: a test of balance and reactance theories’, Journal of Experimental Social Psychology 7: 610–22.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Goranson, R. E., and Berkowitz, L. (1966), ‘Reciprocity and responsibility reactions to prior help’, Journal of Personality and Social Psychology 3: 227–32.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Gouldner, A. (1960), ‘The norm of reciprocity: a preliminary statement’, American Sociological Review 25: 161–78.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Greenberg, J. (1978), ‘Effects of reward value and retaliative power on allocation decisions: justice, generosity or greed?’, Journal of Personality and Social Psychology 36: 367–79.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Greenberg, M. S. (1980), ‘A theory of indebtedness’, in: Gergen, K. J., Greenberg, M. S. and Willis, R. H. (eds.), Social Exchange: Advances in Theory and Research, New York: Plenum Press 2–26.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Greenberg, M. S., and Frisch, D. (1972), ‘Effect of intentionality on willingness to reciprocate a favor’, Journal of Experimental Social Psychology 8: 99–111.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Greenglass, E. R. (1969), ‘Effects of prior help and hindrance on willingness to help another: reciprocity or social responsibility’, Journal of Personality and Social Psychology 11: 224–32.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Gregory, C. A. (1982), Gifts and Commodities, London: Academic Press.Google Scholar
Gregory, C. A. (1987), ‘Gifts’, in: Eatwell, J., Milgate, M. and Newman, P. (eds.), The New Palgrave: A Dictionary of Economics, London: Mackmillan, 524–8.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Gui, B. (2000), ‘Beyond transactions: on the interpersonal dimension of economic reality’, Annals of Public and Cooperative Economics 71 (2): 139–68.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Gui, B., and Sugden, R. (eds.) (2005), Economics and Social Interaction: Accounting for Interpersonal Relations, Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Güth, W. (1995a), ‘An evolutionary approach to explaining cooperative behavior by reciprocal incentives’, International Journal of Game Theory 24 (4): 323–44.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Güth, W. (1995b), ‘On ultimatum bargaining experiments a personal review’, Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization 27 (3): 329–44.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Güth, W., Ockenfels, P. and Wendel, M. (1977), ‘Cooperation based on trust: an experimental investigation’, Journal of Economic Psychology 18: 15–43.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Güth, W., Schmitterberger, R. and Schwarze, B. (1982), ‘An experimental analysis of ultimatum bargaining’, Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization 3: 367–88.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Güth, W., and M. E. Yaari (1992), ‘An evolutionary approach to explain reciprocal behavior in a simple strategic game’, in: Witt, U. (ed.), Explaining Process and Change: Approaches to Evolutionary Economics, Ann Arbor: University of Michigan Press, 23–4.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Guttman, J. M. (2000), ‘On the evolutionary stability of preferences for reciprocity’, European Journal of Political Economy 16 (1): 31–50.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Guyer, P. (1993), Kant and the Experience of Freedom, Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hamilton, W. D. (1971), ‘Selection of selfish and altruistic behavior in some extreme models’, in: Eisenberg, J. F. and Dillon, W. S. (eds.), Man and Beast: Comparative Social Behavior, Washington, DC: Smithsonian Institution Press, 57–91.Google Scholar
Hammond, P. (1975), ‘Charity: altruism or cooperative egoism?’, in: Phelps, E. (ed.), Altruism, Morality, and Economic Theory, New York: Russell Sage Foundation, 115–32.Google Scholar
Handlon, B. J., and Gross, P. (1959), ‘The development of sharing behavior’, Journal of Abnormal and Social Psychology 59: 425–8.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hardin, G. (1968), ‘The tragedy of the commons’, Science 162: 1243–8.Google Scholar
Harris, L. A. (1967), ‘A study of altruism’, Elementary School Journal 68: 135–41.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Harris, M. (1970), ‘Reciprocity and generosity: some determinants of sharing behavior’, Child Development 41: 313–28.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hartmann, H. (1960), Psychoanalysis and Moral Values, New York: International Universities Press.Google Scholar
Heider, F. (1958), The Psychology of Interpersonal Relations, New York: Wiley.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Helliwell, J. F., and Putnam, R. D. (1999), Education and Social Capital, Working Paper no. 7121, National Bureau of Economic Research, Cambridge, MA.
Henrich, J., Boyd, R., Bowles, S., Gintis, H., Fehr, E., McElreath, R. and Camerer, C. (2001), ‘In search of Homo economicus: behavioral experiments in 15 small-scale societies’, American Economic Review 91 (2): 73–8.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Herold, F. (2003), Carrot or Stick? Group Selection and the Evolution of Reciprocal Preferences. Discussion Paper 2003–05, Department of Economics, University of Munich.Google Scholar
Hobhouse, L. T. (1906 [1951]), Morals in Evolution: A Study in Comparative Ethics, London: Chapman and Hall.Google Scholar
Hochman, H. M., and Rodgers, J. D. (1969), ‘Pareto optimal redistribution’, American Economic Review 59 (3): 542–57.Google Scholar
Hoffman, E., and Spitzer, M. L. (1982), ‘The Coase theorem: some experimental tests’, Journal of Law and Economics 95: 73–98.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hoffman, M. (1970), ‘Moral development’, in: Mussen, P. (ed.), Carmichael's Manual of Child Development, New York: Wiley.Google Scholar
Holesovsky, V. (1977), Economic System Analysis and ComparisonTokyo: McGraw-Hill, Kogakusha.Google Scholar
Holländer, H. (1990), ‘A social exchange approach to voluntary cooperation’, American Economic Review 80 (5): 1157–67.Google Scholar
Holmstrom, B., and Milgrom, P. (1991), ‘Multitask principal–agent analyses: incentive contracts, asset ownership, and job design’, Journal of Law, Economics and Organization 7 (Special issue): 24–52.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Homans, G. (1958), ‘Social behavior as exchange’, American Journal of Sociology 68: 597–606.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hornstein, H. A. (1970), Experiments in the Social Psychology of Prosocial Behavior: Final Report, Washington, DC: National Science Foundation.Google Scholar
Hornstein, H. A., Fisch, E. and Holmes, M. (1968), ‘Influence of a model's feelings about his behavior and his relevance as a comparison on the observers’ helping behavior’, Journal of Personality and Social Psychology 10: 222–6.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Isaac, M. R., McCue, K. F. and Plott, C. (1985), ‘Public goods provision in an experimental environment’, Journal of Public Economics 26: 51–74.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Isaac, M. R., and Walker, J. M. (1988a), ‘Communication and free-riding behavior: the voluntary contribution mechanism’, Economic Inquiry 26: 585–608.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Isaac, M. R., and Walker, J. M. (1988b), ‘Group size effects in public goods provision: the voluntary contribution mechanism’, Quarterly Journal of Economics 103: 179–99.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Isaac, M. R., Walker, J. M. and Thomas, S. H. (1984), ‘Divergent evidence on free riding: an experimental examination of possible explanations’, Public Choice 43 (2): 113–49.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Isaac, M. R., Walker, J. M. and Williams, A. M. (1994), ‘Group size and the voluntary provision of public goods: experimental evidence utilizing large groups’, Journal of Public Economics 75: 1–36.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Isen, A. M., and Levin, P. F. (1972), ‘Effect of feeling good on helping: cookies and kindness’, Journal of Personality and Social Psychology 21: 384–8.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kahneman, D., and Knetsch, J. L. (1992), ‘Valuing public goods: the purchase of moral satisfaction’, Journal of Environmental Economics and Management 22 (1): 57–70.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kahneman, D., Knetsch, J. L. and Thaler, R. H. (1986a), ‘Fairness as a constraint on profit seeking: entitlements in the market’, American Economic Review 76 (3): 728–41.Google Scholar
Kahneman, D., Knetsch, J. L. and Thaler, R. H. (1986b), ‘Fairness and the assumptions of economics’, Journal of Business 59: S285–S300.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kant, I. (1790 [1952]), Critique of Judgement (ed. and trans. Meredith, J. C.), Oxford: Clarendon Press.Google Scholar
Kant, I. (1797 [1991]), The Metaphysic of Morals (trans. Gregor, M. J.), Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Keser, C., and Winden, F. (2000), ‘Conditional cooperation and voluntary contributions to public goods’, Scandinavian Journal of Economics 102 (1): 23–39.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kim, O., and Walker, M. (1984), ‘The free rider problem: experimental evidence’, Public Choice 43 (1): 3–24.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kimball, M. (1988), ‘Farmer's cooperatives as behavior toward risk’, American Economic Review 78 (1): 224–32.Google Scholar
Knack, S., and P. Keefer, (1997), ‘Does social capital have an economic payoff? A cross-country investigation’, Quarterly Journal of Economics 112: 1251–88.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kolm, S.-C. (1959), Les hommes du Fouta-Toro, Saint-Louis, Senegal: MAS.Google Scholar
Kolm, S.-Ch. (1966), ‘The optimal production of social justice’, International Economic Association Conference on Public Economics, Biarritz, proceedings, H. Guitton and J. Margolis, eds. Reproduced in (1968), Economie Publique (Paris: CNRS) 109–77, and (1969), Public Economics(London: Macmillan) 145–200.Google Scholar
Kolm, S.-Ch. (1971), Justice et équité, Paris: CEPREMAP. (Reprint 1972, Paris: CNRS). [Published in English 1998, Justice and Equity (trans. H. F. See), Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.]Google Scholar
Kolm, S.-Ch. (1973), La théorie de la réciprocité, Paris: CEPREMAP.Google Scholar
Kolm, S.-Ch. (1975), La réciprocité générale, Paris: CEPREMAP.Google Scholar
Kolm, S.-Ch. (1976), ‘Unequal inequalities’, Journal of Economic Theory, Part I, 12: 416–42; Part II, 13: 82–111.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kolm, S.-Ch. (1977), ‘Multidimensional egalitarianism’, Quarterly Journal of Economics 91: 1–13.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kolm, S.-Ch. (1979), Fondements de la théorie du don, de la réciprocité, et du choix des systèmes économiques, Paris: CEPREMAP.Google Scholar
Kolm, S.-Ch. (1980), ‘Psychanalyse et théorie des choix’, Social Science Information 19 (2): 269–339.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kolm, S.-Ch. (1981a), ‘Altruisme et efficacité: le sophisme de Rousseau’, Social Science Information 20: 293–344.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kolm, S.-Ch. (1981b), ‘Efficacité et altruisme: le sophisme de Mandeville, Smith et Pareto’, Revue Economique 32: 5–31.Google Scholar
Kolm, S.-Ch. (1982), Le Bonheur-Liberté (Bouddhisme Profond et Modernité), Paris: Presses Universitaires de France.Google Scholar
Kolm, S.-Ch. (1983a), ‘Altruism and efficiency’, Ethics 94: 18–65. Reprinted in Zamagni, S. (ed.), The Economics of Altruism, op. cit.Google Scholar
Kolm, S.-Ch. (1983b), ‘Introduction à la réciprocité générale’, Social Science Information 22 (4–5) 569–621.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kolm, S.-Ch. (1984a), La Bonne Economie: la Réciprocité Générale, Paris: Presses Universitaires de France.Google Scholar
Kolm, S.-Ch. (1984b), ‘Théorie de la réciprocité et du choix des systèmes économiques’, Revue Economique 35: 871–910.Google Scholar
Kolm, S.-Ch. (1985), Le Contrat Social Liberal, Paris: Presses Universitaires de France.Google Scholar
Kolm, S.-Ch. (1986), ‘Is only egoism productive?’, Development3.Google Scholar
Kolm, S.-Ch. (1987), ‘Public economics’, in: Eatwell, J., M. Milgate and P. Newman (eds.), The New Palgrave: A Dictionary of Economics, London: Macmillan, 1047–55.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kolm, S.-Ch. (1989), ‘Le devoir général de réciprocité’, Revue d'Ethique et de Théologie Morale 168 (supplement: Les Devoirs de l'Homme): 135–46.Google Scholar
Kolm, S.-Ch. (1990), ‘Employment and fiscal policies with a realistic view of the social role of wages’, in: Champsaur, P., Deleau, M., Grandmont, J.-M., Guesnerie, R., Henry, C., Laffont, J.-J., Laroque, G., Mairesse, J., Monfort, A. and Younes, Y. (eds.), Edmond Malinvaud: Essays in His Honor, Cambridge, MA: MIT Press, 226–86.Google Scholar
Kolm, S.-Ch. (1992), ‘Reciprocity’, Political Economy of the Good Society Newsletter 2 (Summer): 1–6.Google Scholar
Kolm, S.-Ch. (1994), ‘The theory of reciprocity and of the choice of economic systems’, Investigaciones Económicas 18 (1): 67–95.Google Scholar
Kolm, S.-Ch. (1995), ‘The theory of social sentiments: the case of envy’, Japanese Economic Review 1 (46): 63–87.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kolm, S.-Ch. (1996a), Modern Theories of Justice, Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.Google Scholar
Kolm, S.-Ch. (1996b), ‘The theory of justice’, Social Choice and Welfare 13: 151–82.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kolm, S.-Ch. (1998), ‘Une introduction à la théorie de la réciprocité et du choix des systèmes économiques’, in: Mahieu, F.-R. and Rapoport, H. (eds.), Altruisme: Analyses Economiques, Paris: Economica 17–50.Google Scholar
Kolm, S.-Ch. (1999), ‘Rational foundations of income inequality measurement’, in: Silber, J., Handbook on Income Inequality Measurement, Boston: Kluwer Academic, 19–94.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kolm, S.-Ch. (2000a), ‘Introduction to the economics of reciprocity, giving and altruism’, in: Gérard-Varet, L.-A., Kolm, S.-C. and Ythier, J. Mercier (eds.), The Economics of Reciprocity, Giving and Altruism, London: Macmillan, 1–44.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kolm, S.-Ch. (2000b), ‘The theory of reciprocity’, in: Gérard-Varet, L.-A., Kolm, S.-C. and Ythier, J. Mercier (eds.), The Economics of Reciprocity, Giving and Altruism, London: Macmillan, 1115–41.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kolm, S.-Ch. (2000c), ‘The logic of good social relations’, Annals of Public and Cooperative Economics 72 (2): 171–89.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kolm, S.-Ch. (2004), Macrojustice: The Political Economy of Fairness, New York: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kolm, S.-Ch. (2005), ‘The logic of good social relations’, in: B. Gui, and Sugden, R. (eds.), Economics and Social Interaction: Accounting for Interpersonal Relations, Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, chap. 8.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kolm, S.-Ch. (2006), ‘Introduction to the economics of giving, altruism and reciprocity’, in: Kolm, S.-C. and Ythier, J. Mercier (eds.), Handbook of the Economics of Giving, Altruism and Reciprocity, 1–122.Google Scholar
Kolm, S.-Ch. (2008), ‘The paradox of the alleviation of poverty, joint giving and efficient transfers’, mimeo.Google Scholar
Kolm, S-Ch., and Mercier Ythier, J. (eds.) (2006), Handbook of the Economics of Giving, Altruism and Reciprocity, Amsterdam: North Holland Publishing Company.Google Scholar
Kolpin, V. (1993), ‘Equilibrium refinements in psychological games’, Games and Economic Behavior 4 (2): 218–31.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kranich, L. J. (1998), ‘Altruism and efficiency: a welfare analysis of the Walrasian mechanism with transfers’, Journal of Public Economics 36: 369–86.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kranton, R. E. (1996), ‘Reciprocal exchange: a self-sustaining system,’American Economic Review 86 (4): 830–51.Google Scholar
Kreps, D. M. (1997), ‘Intrinsic motivation and extrinsic incentives,’American Economic Review 87 (2): 359–64.Google Scholar
Kreps, D. M., Milgrom, P., Roberts, J. and Wilson, R. (1982), ‘Rational cooperation in the finitely repeated prisoners’ dilemma’, Journal of Economic Theory 27 (2): 245–52.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kropotkin, P. (1892), La conquête du pain, Paris: Tresse and Stock.Google Scholar
Kropotkin, P. (1896), ‘Co-operation: a reply to Herbert Spencer, part 1’, Freedom 13 (12).Google Scholar
Kropotkin, P. (1897), ‘Co-operation: a reply to Herbert Spencer, part 2’, Freedom 14 (1).Google Scholar
Kropotkin, P. (1902 [1972]), Mutual Aid: A Factor of Evolution, London: Penguin.Google Scholar
Kropotkin, P. (1913), La Science Moderne et l'Anarchie, Paris: Stock.Google Scholar
Kropotkin, P. (1927), L'Ethique, Paris: Stock.Google Scholar
Kurz, M. (1978a), ‘Altruism as an outcome of social interaction’, American Economic Review 68 (2): 216–22.Google Scholar
Kurz, M. (1978b), ‘Altruism as an outcome of social interaction’, Journal of Public Economics 36: 369–86.Google Scholar
Kurz, M. (1979), ‘Altruistic equilibrium’, in: Balassa, B. and Nelson, R. (eds.), Economic Progress, Private Values and Policy, Amsterdam: North-Holland, 177–200.Google Scholar
Lambert, P. (2001), The Distribution and Redistribution of Income, Oxford: Basil Blackwell.Google Scholar
Landa, J. T. (1994), Trust, Ethnicity and Identity: Beyond the New Institutional Economics of Ethnic Trading Networks, Contract Law, and Gift-Exchange, Ann Arbor: University of Michigan Press.Google Scholar
Latané, B., and Darley, J. (1970), The Unresponsive Bystander: Why Doesn't He Help?, New York: Appleton-Century-Croft.Google Scholar
Ledyard, J. (1995), ‘Public goods: a survey of experimental research’, in: Roth, A. and Kagel, J. (eds.), Handbook of Experimental Economics, Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press, 111–94.Google Scholar
Leeds, R. (1963), ‘Altruism and the norm of giving’, Merrill-Palmer Quarterly 9: 229–40.Google Scholar
Lenrow, P. (1965), ‘Studies in sympathy’, in: Tomlins, S. S. and Izard, C. E. (eds.), Affect, Cognition, and Personality: Empirical Studies, New York: Springer, 264–94.Google Scholar
Leventhal, G. S., and Anderson, D. (1970), ‘Self-interest and the maintenance of equity’, Journal of Personality and Social Psychology 15: 57–62.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Leventhal, G. S., Weiss, T. and Long, G. (1969), ‘Equity, reciprocity and reallocating rewards in the dyad’, Journal of Personality and Social Psychology 13: 300–5.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Levine, D. K. (1991), You Get What You Pay for: Tests of Efficiency Wage Theories in the United States and Japan, Working Paper no. 1054, University of California, Berkeley, Institute of Industrial Relations.Google Scholar
Levine, D. K. (1993), ‘Fairness, markets, and ability to pay: evidence from compensation executives’, American Economic Review 83 (5): 1241–59.Google Scholar
Levine, D. K. (1997), ‘Modeling altruism and spitefulness in experiments’, Review of Economic Dynamics 1 (3): 593–622.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lévi-Strauss, C. (1949), ‘The principle of reciprocity’, in: Coser, L. A. and Rosenberg, G. (eds.), New York: Macmillan, Sociological Theory: A Book of Readings, 84–94.
Lindbeck, A., and Weibull, J. (1988), ‘Altruism and time consistency: the economics of the fait accompli’, Journal of Political Economy 96: 1165–82.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lindbeck, A., Nyberg, S. and Weibull, J. (1999), ‘Social norms and economic incentives in the welfare state’, Quarterly Journal of Economics 116 (1): 1–35.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Macaulay, J., and Berkowitz, L. (eds.) (1970), Altruism and Helping Behavior, New York: Academic Press.Google Scholar
Malinowski, B. (1932), Crime and Custom in Savage Society, London: Paul, Trench, Trubner.Google Scholar
Mandeville, B. (1705), The Grumbling Hive, or: Knaves Turn'd Honest, London.Google Scholar
Mandeville, B. (1714), The Fable of the Bees, or: Private Vices, Publick Benefits, London.Google Scholar
Margolis, H. (1981), Selfishness, Altruism and Rationality, Cambridge:Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Marwell, G., and Ames, R. (1979), ‘Experiments on the provision of public goods: resources, interest, group size, and the free-rider problem’, American Journal of Sociology 84: 1335–60.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Marwell, G., and Ames, R. (1981), ‘Economists free ride, does anyone else? Experiments on the provision of public goods, Ⅳ’, Journal of Public Economics 15: 295–310.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Mauss, M. (1924), ‘Essai sur le don, forme archaïque de l’échange’, Année Sociologique n.s. 1: 30–186. (English trans., The Gift: Forms and Function of Exchange in Archaic Societies, 1967, New York: Norton).Google Scholar
McCabe, K. A., Rassenti, S. J. and Smith, V. L. (1996), ‘Game theory and reciprocity in some extensive form experimental games’, Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences of the United States of America 93 (23): 13, 421–8.Google Scholar
McCabe, K. A., Rassenti, S. J. and Smith, V. L. (1998), ‘Reciprocity, trust, and payoff privacy in extensive form bargaining’, Games and Economic Behavior 24 (1–2): 10–24.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Mead, G. H. (1934), Mind, Self and Society, Chicago: University of Chicago Press.Google Scholar
Meidinger, C. (2000), ‘Equity, fairness equilibria and coordination in the ultimatum game’, in: Gérard-Varet, L.-A., Kolm, S.-C. and Ythier, J. Mercier (eds.), The Economics of Reciprocity, Giving and Altruism, London: Macmillan, 142–52.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Mercier Ythier, J. (1993), ‘Equilibre général de dons individuels’, Revue Economique 44 (5): 925–50.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Mercier Ythier, J. (1998), ‘The distribution of wealth in the liberal social contract’, European Economic Review 42: 329–47.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Merton, R. (1957), Social Theory and Social Structure, New York: Free Press.Google Scholar
Midlarsky, E. (1968), ‘Aiding responses: an analysis and review’, Merrill-Palmer Quarterly 14: 229–60.Google Scholar
Miller, A. A. (ed.) (1970), Selected Writings on Anarchism and Revolution, Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.Google Scholar
Miller, D. (1988), ‘Altruism and the welfare state’, in: Moon, J. Donald (ed.), Responsibility, Rights, and Welfare: The Theory of the Welfare State, Boulder, Co, and London: Westview Press, 163–88.Google Scholar
Mishan, E. J. (1972), ‘The futility of Pareto-efficient distribution’, American Economic Review 62 (4): 971–6.Google Scholar
Morelly, (1755 [1953]), Code de la Nature, Paris: Editions sociales.Google Scholar
Morris, W. (1890 [1993]), News from Nowhere and Other Writings, London: Penguin.Google Scholar
Musgrave, R. A. (1970), ‘Pareto optimal redistribution: comment’, American Economic Review 60 (5): 991–3.Google Scholar
Nagel, T. (1970), The Possibility of Altruism, Oxford: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Nagel, T. (1986), The View from Nowhere, Oxford: Clarendon Press.Google Scholar
Neuberger, E., and Duffy, W. (1976), Comparative Economic Systems: A Decision-Making Approach, Boston: Allyn and Bacon.Google Scholar
Nicole, P. (1675), Essais de Morale, Paris.Google Scholar
Offer, A. (1997), ‘Between the gift and the market: the economy of regard’, Economic History Review 50 (3): 450–76.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Olsen, E. O. (1971), ‘Some theorems in the theory of efficient transfers’, Journal of Political Economy 79: 166–76.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Orbell, J., and Wilson, L. A. (1978), ‘Institutional solutions to the N-prisoners’ dilemma’, American Political Science Review 72: 411–21.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Orbell, J. M., Dawes, R. M. and Kragt, A. J. C. (1978), ‘Explaining discussion induced cooperation’, Journal of Personality and Social Psychology 54: 811–19.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Orbell, J. M., Dawes, R. M. and Kragt, A. J. C. (1983), ‘The minimal contributing set as a solution to public goods problems’, American Political Science Review 77: 112–22.Google Scholar
Ostrom, E., and J. M. Walker (1991), ‘Cooperation without external enforcement’, in: Palfrey, T. P. (ed.), Laboratory Research in Political Economy, Ann Arbor: University of Michigan Press 287–322.Google Scholar
Pantaleoni, M. (1898), Pure Economics, Clifton, NJ: Kelley.Google Scholar
Pareto, V. (1911), Le mythe vertuiste et la littérature immorale, Paris: Rivière.Google Scholar
Pareto, V. (1913), ‘Il massimo di utilità per una colletività’, Giornale degli Economisti 3: 337–41. [Reprinted as a long footnote in A Treatise on General Sociology.]Google Scholar
Pareto, V. (1916), A Treatise on General Sociology, New York: Dover.Google Scholar
Parsons, T. (1951), The Social System, Glencoe, IL: Free Press.Google Scholar
Piaget, J. (1932), La Naissance du Sentiment Moral chez l'Enfant, Geneva: Payot.Google Scholar
Polanyi, K. (1944), The Great Transformation: The Political Origin of Our Time, Boston: Beacon Press.Google Scholar
Prasnikar, V., and Roth, A. E. (1992), ‘Considerations of fairness and strategy: experimental data from sequential games’, Quarterly Journal of Economics 107 (3): 865–88.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Proudhon, P. J. (1853), Manuel du spéculateur à la bourse, Paris: Garnier Frères.Google Scholar
Pruitt, D. G. (1968), ‘Reciprocity and credit building in a laboratory dyad’, Journal of Personality and Social Psychology 8: 143–7.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Pryor, F. (1977), The Origins of the Economy, New York: Academic Press.Google Scholar
Putnam, R. O. (1993), Making Democracy Work: Civic Traditions in Modern Italy, Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Rabin, M. (1993), ‘Incorporating fairness into game theory and economics’, American Economic Review 83 (5): 1281–302.Google Scholar
Rabin, M. (1998), ‘Psychology and economics’, Journal of Economic Literature 36: 11–46.Google Scholar
Radner, R. (1980), ‘Collusive behavior in noncooperative epsilon-equilibria of oligopolies with long but finite lives’, Journal of Economic Theory 22 (2): 136–54.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Rose-Ackerman, S. (1996), ‘Altruism, nonprofits, and economic theory’, Journal of Economic Literature 34: 701–28.Google Scholar
Rosenhan, D. L. (1969), ‘Some origins of concern for others’, in: Mussen, P., J. Langer and M. Covington (eds.), Trends and Issues in Developmental Psychology, New York: Holt, Rinehart and Winston, 134–53.Google Scholar
Rosenhan, D. L. (1970), ‘The natural socialization of altruistic autonomy’, in: Macaulay, J. and Berkowitz, L. (eds.), Altruism and Helping Behavior, New York: Academic Press, 251–68.Google Scholar
Rosenhan, D. L., and White, G. M. (1967), ‘Observation and rehearsal as determinants of prosocial behavior’, Journal of Personality and Social Psychology 5: 424–31.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Rotemberg, J. (1994), ‘Human relations in the workplace’, Journal of Political Economy 102 (4): 684–717.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Roth, A. E. (1995), ‘Bargaining experiments’, in: Kagel, J. H. and Roth, A. E. (eds.), Handbook of Experimental Economics, Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press, 253–348.Google Scholar
Sacco, P. L., and S. Zamagni (1996), ‘An evolutionary dynamic approach to altruism’, in: Farina, F., Hahn, F., and Vannucci, S. (eds.), Ethics, Rationality, and Economic Behaviour, Oxford: Clarendon Press, 265–300.Google Scholar
Sacco, P. L., and Zamagni, S. (eds.) (2002), Complessità Relazionale e Comportamento Economico, Bologna: Il Mulino.Google Scholar
Sahlins, M. (1968), Tribesmen, Englewood Cliffs, NJ: Prentice-Hall.Google Scholar
Sahlins, M. (1977), The Use and Abuse of Biology.An Anthropological Critique of Sociobiology. London: Tavistock.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Sawyer, J. (1966), ‘The altruism scale: a measure of cooperative, individualistic, and competitive interpersonal orientation’, American Journal of Sociology 71: 407–16.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Schneider, F., and Pommerehne, W. (1981), ‘On the rationality of free-riding: an experiment’, Quarterly Journal of Economics 96: 689–704.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Schwartz, B. (1967), ‘The social psychology of the gift’, American Journal of Sociology 73: 1–11.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Schwartz, R. (1970), ‘Personal philanthropic contributions’, Journal of Political Economy 78 (6): 1264–91.Google Scholar
Scott, R. H. (1972), ‘Avarice, altruism, and second party preferences’, Quarterly Journal of Economics 86 (1): 1–18.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Segal, U., and Sobel, J. (1999), Tit for Tat: Foundations of Preferences for Reciprocity in Strategic Settings, Discussion Paper 99–10, University of California, San Diego.Google Scholar
Selten, R., and Ockenfels, A. (1998), ‘An experimental solidarity game’, Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization 34 (4): 517–39.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Service, E. R. (1966), The Hunters, Englewood Cliffs, NJ: Prentice-Hall.Google Scholar
Sethi, R., and Somanathan, E. (2001), ‘Preference evolution and reciprocity’, Journal of Economic Theory 97: 273–97.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Sethi, R., and Somanathan, E. (2003), ‘Understanding reciprocity’, Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization 50 (1): 1–27.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Silber, J. (ed.) (1999), Handbook on Income Inequality Measurement, Boston: Kluwer Academic.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Simon, H. A. (1990), ‘A mechanism for social selection and successful altruism’, Science 250: 1665–8.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Simon, H. A. (1991), ‘Organization and markets’, Journal of Economic Perspectives 5: 27–44.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Smale, S. (1980), ‘The prisoner's dilemma and dynamic systems associated to non-cooperative games’, Econometrica 48: 1617–34.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Smith, A. (1759 [1966]), The Theory of Moral Sentiments, New York: Kelly.Google Scholar
Smith, A. (1776 [1937]), An Inquiry into the Nature and Cause of the Wealth of Nations, New York: Random House.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Sobel, J. (2005), ‘Interdependent preferences and reciprocity’, Journal of Economic Literature 43: 392–436.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Solow, J. L. (1993), ‘Is it really the thought that counts? Toward a rational theory of Christmas’, Rationality and Society 5: 506–17.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Solow, R. M. (1979), ‘Another possible source of wage stickiness’, Journal of Macroeconomics 1 (1): 79–82.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Stark, O. (1995), Altruism and Beyond: An Economic Analysis of Transfers and Exchanges within Families and Groups, Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Stark, W. (ed.) (1952–4), Jeremy Bentham's Economic Writings (3 vols.), New York: Franklin.Google Scholar
Stein, E. (1964), On the Problem of Empathy (trans. W. Stein), The Hague: Martinus Nijhoff.Google Scholar
Stotland, E. (1969), ‘Exploratory investigations of empathy’, in: Berkowitz, L. (ed.), Advances in Experimental Social Psychology, New York: Academic Press, 271–314.Google Scholar
Sugden, R. (1984), ‘Reciprocity: the supply of public goods through voluntary contribution’, Economic Journal 94: 772–87.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Sugden, R. (1993), ‘Thinking as a team: towards an explanation of nonselfish behavior’, Social Philosophy and Policy 10: 69–89.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Sugden, R. (2000), ‘Team preferences’, Economics and Philosophy 16: 175–205.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Sugden, R. (2002), ‘Beyond sympathy and empathy: Adam Smith's concept of fellow feeling’, Economics and Philosophy 18: 63–88.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Swaney, J. A. (1990), ‘Common property, reciprocity, and community’, Journal of Economic Issues24: 451–62.Google Scholar
Thurnwald, R. G. (1916), ‘Bánaro society: social organization and kinship system of a tribe in the interior of New Guinea’, Memoirs of the American Anthropological Association 3 (4): 251–391.Google Scholar
Thurnwald, R. G. (1921), Die Gemeinde der Bánaro, Stuttgart: Ferdinand Enke.Google Scholar
Thurnwald, R. G. (1932a), Die Menschliche Gesellschaft, 5 vols., Berlin and Leipzig: Walter de Gruyter.Google Scholar
Thurnwald, R. G. (1932b), Economics in Primitive Communities, London: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Titmuss, R. M. (1971), The Gift Relationship, London: Allen and Unwin.Google Scholar
Tognoli, J. (1975), ‘Reciprocation of generosity and knowledge of game termination in the decomposed prisoner's dilemma game’, European Journal of Social Psychology 5: 297–313.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Tönnies, F. (1972), Gemeinschaft und Gesellschaft, Darmstadt: Wissenschaftliche Buchgesellschaft.Google Scholar
Tournier, P. (1963), The Meaning of Gifts, Richmond, VA: John Knox Press.Google Scholar
Trivers, R. L. (1971), ‘The evolution of reciprocal altruism’, Quarterly Review of Biology 46 (1): 35–58.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Uhlaner, C. J. (1989), ‘Relational goods and participation: incorporating sociability into a theory of rational action’, Public Choice 62: 253–85.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kragt, A. J. C., Orbell, J. M. and Dawes, R. M. (1983), ‘The minimal contributing set as a solution to public goods problems’, American Political Science Review 77: 112–22.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Vickrey, W. S. (1962), ‘One economist's view of philanthropy’, in: Dickinson, F. (ed.), Philanthropy and Public Policy, New York: National Bureau of Economic Research.Google Scholar
Furstenberg, G. M., and Mueller, D. C. (1971), ‘The Pareto optimal approach to income redistribution: a fiscal application’, American Economic Review 61 (3): 628–37.Google Scholar
Waller, W., and Hill, R. (1951), The Family: A Dynamic Interpretation, New York: Dryden Press.Google Scholar
Walras, L. (1865 [1969]), Les associations populaires de consommation, de production et de crédit, Rome: Bizzarri.Google Scholar
Warr, P. G. (1982), ‘Pareto optimal redistribution and private charity’, Journal of Public Economics 19: 131–8.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Weisbrod, B. A. (1988), The Nonprofit Economy, Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.Google Scholar
Westermarck, E. (1908), The Origin and Development of the Moral Ideas, vol. II, London: Macmillan.Google Scholar
Wicksteed, P. H. (1888), The Alphabet of Economic Science, London: R. H. Hutton.Google Scholar
Wicksteed, P. H. (1933), The Common Sense of Political Economy, London: Robbins Edn.Google Scholar
Wilke, H., and Lanzetta, J. (1970), ‘The obligation to help: the effects of prior help on subsequent helping behavior’, Journal of Experimental Social Psychology 6: 466–93.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Winter, S. J. (1969), ‘A simple remark on the second optimality theorem of welfare economics’, Journal of Economic Theory 1: 99–103.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Wintrobe, R. (1981), ‘It pays to do good, but not to do more good than it pays’, Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization 2: 201–13.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Wispe, L. (1968), ‘Sympathy and empathy’, in: Sills, D. L. (ed.), Encyclopedia of the Social Sciences, vol. XV, New York: Macmillan, 441–7.Google Scholar
Wolff, K. H. (ed.) (1950), The Sociology of Georg Simmel, trans. Wolff, K. H., Glencoe, IL: Free Press.Google Scholar
Wright, B. (1942), ‘Altruism in children and the perceived conduct of others’, Journal of Abnormal and Social Psychology 37: 218–33.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Zak, P. J., and Knack, S. (2001), ‘Trust and growth’, Economic Journal 111: 295–321.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Zamagni, S. (ed.) (1995), The Economics of Altruism, Cheltenham: Edward Elgar.Google Scholar
Zeckhauser, R. (1971), ‘Optimal mechanisms for income transfer’, American Economic Review 61 (3): 324–34.Google Scholar

Save book to Kindle

To save this book to your Kindle, first ensure coreplatform@cambridge.org is added to your Approved Personal Document E-mail List under your Personal Document Settings on the Manage Your Content and Devices page of your Amazon account. Then enter the ‘name’ part of your Kindle email address below. Find out more about saving to your Kindle.

Note you can select to save to either the @free.kindle.com or @kindle.com variations. ‘@free.kindle.com’ emails are free but can only be saved to your device when it is connected to wi-fi. ‘@kindle.com’ emails can be delivered even when you are not connected to wi-fi, but note that service fees apply.

Find out more about the Kindle Personal Document Service.

  • Bibliography
  • Serge-Christophe Kolm, Ecole des Hautes Etudes en Sciences Sociales, Paris
  • Book: Reciprocity
  • Online publication: 22 September 2009
  • Chapter DOI: https://doi.org/10.1017/CBO9780511492334.026
Available formats
×

Save book to Dropbox

To save content items to your account, please confirm that you agree to abide by our usage policies. If this is the first time you use this feature, you will be asked to authorise Cambridge Core to connect with your account. Find out more about saving content to Dropbox.

  • Bibliography
  • Serge-Christophe Kolm, Ecole des Hautes Etudes en Sciences Sociales, Paris
  • Book: Reciprocity
  • Online publication: 22 September 2009
  • Chapter DOI: https://doi.org/10.1017/CBO9780511492334.026
Available formats
×

Save book to Google Drive

To save content items to your account, please confirm that you agree to abide by our usage policies. If this is the first time you use this feature, you will be asked to authorise Cambridge Core to connect with your account. Find out more about saving content to Google Drive.

  • Bibliography
  • Serge-Christophe Kolm, Ecole des Hautes Etudes en Sciences Sociales, Paris
  • Book: Reciprocity
  • Online publication: 22 September 2009
  • Chapter DOI: https://doi.org/10.1017/CBO9780511492334.026
Available formats
×