Skip to main content Accessibility help
×
Hostname: page-component-77c89778f8-n9wrp Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-07-24T17:25:19.194Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

References

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  11 July 2009

Jim Rossi
Affiliation:
Florida State University
Get access
Type
Chapter
Information
Publisher: Cambridge University Press
Print publication year: 2005

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

References

Adams, Henry Carter. 1887 (January). “Relation of the State to Industrial Action.” Publications of the American Economics Association. 1: 55Google Scholar
Ahdieh, Robert B. 2004. “Law's Signal: A Cueing Theory of Law in Market Transition.” Southern California Law Review. 77: 215Google Scholar
Alexander, Barbara & The National Consumer Law Center. 1996. Consumer Protection Proposals for Retail Electric Competition: Model Legislation and RegulationsBoston: National Consumer Law CenterGoogle Scholar
Alexander, Gregory S. 1996. “Ten Years of Takings.” Journal of Legal Education. 46: 586Google Scholar
Alston, Lee J., Eggertsson, Thráinn & North, Douglas C., eds. Empirical Studies in Institutional ChangeCambridge: Cambridge University PressCrossRef
Areeda, Phillip E. & Hovenkamp, Herbert. 2000. IA Antitrust Law, Second edition. Boston: Little, BrownGoogle Scholar
Arteburn, Norman F. 1927. “The Origin and First Test of Public Callings.” University of Pennsylvania Law Review. 75: 411CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Austin, Regina. 1983. “The Insurance Classification Controversy.” University of Pennsylvania Law Review. 131: 517CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Averch, Harvey & Johnson, Leland L. 1962. “Behavior of the Firm Under Regulatory Constraint.” American Economic Review. 52: 1052Google Scholar
Aviram, Amitai. 2003. “Regulation by Networks.” Brigham Young University Law Review. 2003: 1179Google Scholar
Ayres, Ian & Braithwaite, John. 1992. Responsive Regulation: Transcending the Deregulation Debate. New York: Oxford University PressGoogle Scholar
Ayres, Ian & Gertner, Robert. 1992. “Strategic Contractual Inefficiency and the Optimal Choice of Legal Rules.” Yale Law Journal. 101: 729CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Baer, William J. 1997. “FTC Perspectives on Competition Policy and Enforcement Initiatives in Electric Power.” Presented at the Conference on the New Rules of the Game for Electric Power: Antitrust and Anticompetitive Behavior, Bureau of Competition, Federal Trade Commission, Washington, D.C., December 4. Available at http://www.ftc.gov/speeches/other/elec1204.htm
Baker, Scott and Krawiec, Kimberly. 2004. “The Penalty Default Canon.” George Washington Law Review. 72: 663Google Scholar
Baron, David & Ferejohn, John. 1989. “Bargaining in Legislatures.” American Political Science Review. 83: 1181CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Baumol, William J. & Merrill, Thomas W. 1996. “Deregulatory Takings, Breach of the Regulatory Contract, and the Telecommunications Act of 1996.” New York University Law Review. 72: 1037Google Scholar
Becker, Gary. 1983. “A Theory of Competition Among Pressure Groups for Political Influence.” Quarterly Journal of Economics. 98: 371CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Beer, Samuel H. 1977. “Political Overload and Federalism.” Polity. 10: 5CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Berg, Jessica Wilen. 2003. “Understanding Waiver.” Houston Law Review. 40: 281Google Scholar
Bernheim, B. Douglas & Whinston, Michael D.. 1998. “Incomplete Contracts and Strategic Ambiguity.” American Economic Review. 88: 902Google Scholar
Bernstein, David E. 2003. “Lochner's Legacy's Legacy.” Texas Law Review. 82: 1Google Scholar
Bernstein, Lisa. 1992. “Opting Out of the Legal System: Extra Legal Contractual Relations in the Diamond Industry.” Journal of Legal Studies. 21: 115CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bernstein, Lisa. 2001. “Private Commercial Law in the Cotton Industry: Creating Cooperation Through Rules, Norms and Institutions.” Michigan Law Review. 99: 1724CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bolze, Ray S., Pierce, John C. & Walsh, Linda L., 2000. “Antitrust Law Regulation: A New Focus for a Competitive Energy Industry.” Energy Law Journal. 21: 79Google Scholar
Borenstein, Severin. 2002. “The Trouble with Electricity Markets: Understanding California's Restructuring Disaster.” Journal of Economic Perspectives. 16(1): 191CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Borenstein, Severin & Bushnell, James D.. 2000. “Electricity Restructuring: Deregulation or Reregulation?Regulation 23(2): 46Google Scholar
Boudin, Michael. 1986. “Antitrust Doctrine and the Sway of Metaphor.” Georgetown Law Journal. 75: 395Google Scholar
Bouknight, J. A. & Raskin, David B.. 1987. “Planning for Wholesale Customer Loads in a Competitive Environment: The Obligation to Provide Wholesale Service under the Federal Power Act.” Energy Law Journal. 8: 237Google Scholar
Boyes, William J. 1976. “An Empirical Examination of the Averch-Johnson Effect.” Economic Inquiry. 14: 25CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bradley, Robert L., Jr. 2003. “The Origins and Development of Electric Power Regulation.” In Grossman, Peter Z. & Cole, Daniel H., eds. The End of a Natural Monopoly: Deregulation and Competition in the Electric Power IndustryAmsterdam: Elsevier Science (JAI Imprint)Google Scholar
Brennan, Timothy J. & Boyd, James. 1997. “Stranded Costs, Takings, and the Law and Economics of Implicit Contracts.” Journal of Regulatory Economics. 11: 41CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Breyer, Stephen. 1982. Regulation and its Reform. Cambridge, Mass.: Harvard University PressGoogle Scholar
Brown, Stephen J. & Sibley, David S.. 1986. The Theory of Public Utility Pricing. New York: Cambridge University PressCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Burdick, Charles K. 1911. “The Origin of the Peculiar Duties of Public Service Companies.” Columbia Law Review. 11: 514CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Buzbee, William W. 2003. “Recognizing the Regulatory Commons: A Theory of Regulatory Gaps.” Iowa Law Review. 89: 1Google Scholar
Cain, Bruce, Ferejohn, John & Fiorina, Morris. 1987. The Personal Vote: Constituency Service and Electoral Independence. Cambridge, Mass.: Harvard University PressCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Calabresi, Guido & Douglas, A. Melamed. 1972. “Property Rules, Liability Rules, and Inalienability: One View of the Cathedral.” Harvard Law Review. 85: 1089CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Candeub, Adam. 2004. “Network Interconnection and Takings.” Syracuse Law Review. 54: 369Google Scholar
Carron, Andrew S. & Paul, W. MacAvoy. 1981. The Decline of Service in Regulated IndustriesWashington, D.C.: American Enterprise InstituteGoogle Scholar
Casson, Mark. 1997. Information and Organization: A New Perspective on the Theory of the FirmNew York: Clarendon PressGoogle Scholar
Chen, Jim. 1999. “The Second Coming of Smyth v. Ames.” Texas Law Review. 77: 1535Google Scholar
Chen, Jim. 2000. “Standing in the Shadows of Giants: The Role of Intergenerational Equity in Telecommunications Reform.” University of Colorado Law Review. 71: 921Google Scholar
Chen, Jim. 2003a. “The Vertical Dimension of Cooperative Competition Policy.” Antitrust Bulletin. 48: 1005CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Chen, Jim. 2003b. “Subsidized Rural Telephony and the Public Interest: A Case Study in Cooperative Federalism and Its Pitfalls.” Journal on Telecommunications & High Technology Law. 2: 307Google Scholar
Chen, Jim. 2003c. “A Vision Softly Creeping: Congressional Acquiesence and the Dormant Commerce Clause.” Minnesota Law Review. 88: 1764Google Scholar
Chen, Jim. 2004. “The Nature of the Public Utility: Infrastructure, the Market, and the Law.” Northwestern University Law Review. 98: 1617Google Scholar
Cirace, John. 1982. “An Economic Analysis of the ‘State-Municipal Action’ Antitrust Cases.” Texas Law Review. 61: 481Google Scholar
Coase, Ronald H. 1937. “The Nature of the Firm.” Economica. 4: 386CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Coase, Ronald H. 1960. “The Problem of Social Costs.” Journal of Law and Economics. 3: 1CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Coenen, Dan T. 1989. “Untangling the Market-Participant Exception to the Dormant Commerce Clause.” Michigan Law Review. 88: 395CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Cohen, George M. 1994. “The Fault Lines in Contract Damages.” Virginia Law Review. 80: 1225CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Cole, Daniel H. 2003. “The Regulatory Contract.” in Grossman, Peter Z. & Daniel, H. Cole, eds. The End of a Natural Monopoly: Deregulation and Competition in the Electric Power IndustryAmsterdam: Elsevier Science (JAI Imprint)Google Scholar
Colton, Roger. 1991. “A Cost-Based Response to Low-Income Energy Problems.” Public Utilities Fortnightly. March 1: 31Google Scholar
Colton, Roger. 1997. The ‘Obligation to Serve’ and a Competitive Electric Industry. Report of DOE Office of Economic, Electricity and Natural Gas Analysis, May
Costello, Kenneth W. & Robert, J. Graniere. 1997. Deregulation-Restructuring: Evidence from Individual IndustriesColumbus, Ohio: National Regulatory Research InstituteCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Costello, Kenneth W. & , J. Rodney Lemon. 1996. Unbundling the Retail Natural Gas Market: Current Activities and Guidance for Serving Residential and Small Consumers. Columbus, Ohio: National Regulatory Research InstituteCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Courville, Leon. 1974. “Regulation and Efficiency in the Electric Utility Industry.” Bell Journal of Economic and Management Science. 5: 53CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Cramton, Roger C. 1986. “Demystifying Legal Scholarship.” Georgetown Law Journal. 75: 1Google Scholar
Cudahy, Richard D. 2002a. “Electric Deregulation after California: Down But Not Out.” Administrative Law Review. 54: 333Google Scholar
Cudahy, Richard D. 2002b. “Full Circle in the Formerly Regulated Industries?Loyola University of Chicago Law Journal. 33: 767Google Scholar
Davis, Mary J. 2002. “Unmasking the Presumption in Favor of Preemption.” Southern California Law Review. 53: 967Google Scholar
Figueiredo, John M. & Figueiredo, Rui J. P. Jr. 2002. “The Allocation of Resources by Interest Groups: Lobbying, Litigation and Administrative Regulation.” Business and Politics. 4(2): 161CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Dechert, W. Davis. 1984. “Has the Averch-Johnson Effect Been Theoretically Justified?Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control. 8: 1CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Deisinger, Chris. 2000. “The Backlash Against Merchant Plants and the Need for a New Regulatory Model.” Electricity Journal. 13: 51CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Demsetz, Harold. 1968. “Why Regulate Utilities?Journal of Law & Economics. 11: 55CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Denning, Brannon P. 1999. “Justice Thomas, the Import-Export Clause, and Camps Newfound/Owatonna v. Harrison.” University of Colorado Law Review. 70: 155Google Scholar
Denning, Brannon P. 2003. “Why the Privileges and Immunities Clause of Article IV Cannot Replace the Dormant Commerce Clause Doctrine.” Minnesota Law Review. 84: 284Google Scholar
Derthick, Martha & Paul, J. Quirk. 1985. The Politics of Deregulation. Washington, D.C.: BrookingsGoogle Scholar
Dibadj, Reza. 2004. “Saving Antitrust.” University of Colorado Law Review. 75: 745Google Scholar
Diver, Colin. 1983. “The Optimal Precision of Administrative Rules.” Yale Law Journal. 93: 65CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Dorf, Michael H. & Charles, F. Sabel. 1998. “A Constitution of Democratic Experimentalism.” Columbia Law Review. 98: 267CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Easterbrook, Frank H. 1984. “The Limits of Antitrust.” Texas Law Review. 63: 1Google Scholar
Easterbrook, Frank H. 1988. “The Role of Original Intent in Statutory Construction.” Harvard Journal of Law and Public Policy. 11: 59Google Scholar
Eaton, Jade Alice. 1994. “Recent United States Department of Justice Actions in the Electric Utility Industry.” Connecticut Journal of International Law. 9: 857Google Scholar
Economides, Nicholas. 2003. “The Tragic Inefficiency of the M-ECPR.” in Shampine, Allan L., ed. Down to the Wire: Studies in the Diffusion and Regulation of Telecommunications TechnologiesHauppauge, N.Y.: Nova Science PublishersGoogle Scholar
Eggertsson, Thráinn. 1996. “A Note on the Economics of Institutions.” in Alston, Lee J., Eggertsson, Thráinn & Douglas, C. North, eds. Empirical Studies in Institutional ChangeCambridge: Cambridge University PressCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Elhauge, Einer. 2002. “Preference-Eliciting Statutory Default Rules.” Columbia Law Review. 102: 2163Google Scholar
Ellickson, Robert. 1994. Order Without Law: How Neighbors Settle Disputes. Cambridge, Mass.: Harvard University PressGoogle Scholar
Ely, John Hart. 1980. Democracy and Distrust: A Theory of Judicial ReviewCambridge, Mass.: Harvard University PressGoogle Scholar
Ely, Richard T. 1887. “The Nature and Significance of the Corporation.” Harper's Magazine. 75: 71Google Scholar
Engel, Kristen H. 1999. “The Dormant Commerce Clause Threat to Market-Based Regulation: The Case of Electricity Deregulation.” Ecology Law Quarterly. 26: 243Google Scholar
Epstein, Richard A. 1984. “Toward a Revitalization of the Contract Clause.” University of Chicago Law Review. 51: 703CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Epstein, Richard A. 1985. Takings: Private Property and the Power of Eminent Domain. Cambridge, Mass.: Harvard University PressGoogle Scholar
Epstein, Richard A. 1995. “The Permit Power Meets the Constitution.” Iowa Law Review 81: 407Google Scholar
Epstein, Richard A. 1997a. “A Clear View from The Cathedral: The Dominance of Property Rules.” Yale Law Journal. 106: 2091, 2128CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Epstein, Richard A. 1997b. “Takings, Exclusivity and Speech: The Legacy of Prune Yard v. Robins.” University of Chicago Law Review. 64: 21CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Eskridge, William N. Jr. & Philip, P. Frickey. 1992. “Quasi-Constitutional Law: Clear Statement Rules as Constitutional Lawmaking.” Vanderbilt Law Review. 45: 593Google Scholar
Eule, Julian N. 1982. “Laying the Dormant Commerce Clause to Rest.” Yale Law Journal. 91: 425CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Farber, Daniel A. 1991. Legislative Deals and Statutory Bequests. Minnesota Law Review. 75: 667Google Scholar
Farber, Daniel A. & Philip, Frickey. 1991. Law and Public Choice: A Critical IntroductionChicago: University of Chicago PressCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ferrey, Steven. 1997. “Renewable Subsidies in the Age of Deregulation: State-Imposed Preferences May Have Come to the Wrong Place at the Wrong Time.” Fortnightly. December: 22Google Scholar
Fisch, Jill E. 1997. “Retroactivity and Legal Change: An Equilibrium Approach.” Harvard Law Review. 110: 1055CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Fox-Penner, Peter. 1997. Electric Utility Restructuring: A Guide to the Competitive Era. Vienna, Virginia: Public Utility ReportsGoogle Scholar
Frankfurter, Felix & Landis, James. 1925. “The Compact Clause of the Constitution – A Study in Interstate Adjustments.” Yale Law Journal. 34: 685CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Freeman, Jody. 1997. “Collaborative Governance in the Administrative State.” UCLA Law Review. 45: 1Google Scholar
Freeman, Jody. 2000. “The Contracting State.” Florida State University Law Review. 28: 155Google Scholar
Friendly, Henry J. 1964. “In Praise of Erie – And of the New Federal Common Law.” New York University Law Review. 39: 383Google Scholar
Furubotn, Eirik G. & Rudolf, Richter. 1998. Institutions and Economic Theory: The Contribution of the New Institutional Economics. Ann Arbor: University of Michig an PressGoogle Scholar
Garbaum, Stephen A. 1994. “The Nature of Preemption.” Cornell Law Review. 79: 767Google Scholar
Garland, Merrick B. 1987. “Antitrust and State Action: Economic Efficiency and the Political Process.” Yale Law Journal. 96: 486CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Gey, Steven G. 1989–90. “The Political Economy of the Dormant Commerce Clause.” NYU Review of Law & Social Change. 17: 1Google Scholar
Gifford, Daniel J. 1995. “Federalism, Efficiency, the Commerce Clause, and the Sherman Act: Why We Should Follow a Consistent Free Market Policy.” Emory Law Journal. 44: 1227Google Scholar
Gillette, Clayton. 1991. “In Partial Praise of Dillon's Rule, or, Can Public Choice Theory Justify Local Government Law?Chicago-Kent Law Review. 67: 959Google Scholar
Gilliam, Thomas J. Jr. 1997. “Contracting with the United States in its Role as Regulator: Striking a Bargain with an Equitable Sovereign or Capricious Siren.” Mississippi College Law Review. 18: 247Google Scholar
Glazer, Craig A. & , M. Bryan Little. 1999. “The Rolesof Antitrust Law and Regulatory Oversight in the Restructured Electricity Industry.” Electricity Journal. 12: 21CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Goldberg, Victor. 1976. “Regulation and Administered Contracts.” Bell Journal of Economics. 7: 444CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Goldsmith, Richard. 1989. “Utility Rates and ‘Takings’.” Energy Law Journal. 10: 241Google Scholar
Gómez-Ibáñez, José A. 2003. Regulating Infrastructure: Monopoly Contracts and DiscretionCambridge, Mass.: Harvard University PressGoogle Scholar
Goodin, Robert E. 1982. Political Theory and Public Policy. Chicago: University of Chicago PressGoogle Scholar
Goodman, James. 2003. BlackoutNew York: North Point PressGoogle Scholar
Gormley, William T. Jr. 1983. The Politics of Public Utility Regulation. Pittsburgh: University of Pitts burgh PressGoogle Scholar
Grossman, Peter Z. 2003. “Is Anything Naturally aMonopoly?” in Grossman, Peter Z. & Daniel, H. Cole, eds. The End of a Natural Monopoly: Deregulation and Competition in the Electric Power Industry. Amsterdam: Elsevier Science (JAIImprint)Google Scholar
Grossman, Peter Z. & Daniel, H. Cole. 2003. The End of a Natural Monopoly: Deregulation and Competition in the Electric Power Industry. Amsterdam: Elsevier Science (JAIImprint)Google Scholar
Haar, Charles M. & Daniel, W. Fessler. 1986. The Wrong Side of the Tracks: A Revolutionary Rediscovery of the Common Law Tradition of Fairness in the Struggle Against Inequality. New York: Simon & SchusterGoogle Scholar
Hadfield, Gillian. 1999. “Of Sovereignty and Contract: Damages for Breach of Contract by the Government.” Southern California Interdisciplinary Law Journal. 8: 467Google Scholar
Hale, G. E. & Hale, Rosemary. 1962. “Competition or Control VI: Application of Antitrust Laws to Regulated Industries.” University of Pennsylvania Law Review. 111: 46CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hall, Gus & Pierce, Richard., 1997. “Retail Gas Reform: Learning from the Georgia Model.” Public Utilities Fortnightly. April 15: 22Google Scholar
Hart, Oliver & Moore, John. 1999. “Foundations of Incomplete Contracts.” Review of Economic Studies. 66: 115CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hart, Oliver D. 1988. “Incomplete Contracts and the Theory of the Firm.” Journal of Law, Economics and Organization. 4: 119Google Scholar
Hart, Oliver D. 1995. Firms, Contracts, and Financial Structure. Oxford: Oxford University PressCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hills, Roderick M. Jr. 1999. “Dissecting the State:The Use of Federal Law to Free State and Local Officials from State Legislatures'Control.” Michigan Law Review. 97: 1201CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hills, Roderick M., Jr. 2003. “Against Preemption:How Federalism Can Improve the National Lawmaking Process.” Working paper available at http://papers.ssrn.com/sol3/papers.cfm?abstract_id=412000
Hirsh, Richard F. 1999. Power Loss: The Origins of Deregulation and Restructuring in the American Electric Utility IndustryCambridge, Mass.: MIT PressGoogle Scholar
Hirst, Eric & Baxter, Lester. 1995. “How Stranded Will Electric Utilities Be?Public Utilities Fortnightly Feb. 15: 30–32Google Scholar
Hoke, S. Candice. 1991. “Preemption Pathologies and Civic Republican Values.” Boston University Law Review. 71: 685Google Scholar
Holmes, Oliver Wendell. 1920. Collected Legal Papers. New York: Harcourt, Brace &CoGoogle Scholar
Horwich, Allan. 2000. “The Neglected Relationship of Materiality and Recklessness in Actions under Rule 10b-5.” Business Lawyer. 55: 1023Google Scholar
Hovenkamp, Herbert. 1991. Enterpriseand American Law, 1836–1937. Cambridge, Mass.: Harvard University PressGoogle Scholar
Hovenkamp, Herbert. 1999a. Federal Antitrust Policy: The Law of Competition and Its PracticeSt. Paul, Minnesota: West GroupGoogle Scholar
Hovenkamp, Herbert. 1999b. “The Takings Clause and Improvident Regulatory Bargains.” Yale Law Journal. 108: 801CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Humphrey, Andrew G. 1985. “Antitrust Jurisdiction and Remedies in an Electric Utility Price Squeeze.” University of Chicago Law Review. 52: 1090
Inman, Robert P. & Daniel, L. Rubinfeld. 1997. “Making Sense of the Antitrust State-Action Doctrine: Balancing Political Participation and Economic Efficiency in Regulatory Federalism.” Texas Law Review. 75: 1203Google Scholar
Isser, Steve & Steven, A. Mitnick. 1998. “Enron's Battle with PECO.” Public Utilities Fortnightly Mar. 1: 38Google Scholar
Jaffe, Louis L. 1964. “Primary Jurisdiction.” Harvard Law Review. 77: 1037CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Joskow, Paul. 1977. “Commercial Impossibility, the Uranium Market, and the Westinghouse Case.” Journal of Legal Studies. 6: 119CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Joskow, Paul J. 2001. “California's Electricity Crisis.” Oxford Journal of Economic Policy. 17: 365CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Joskow, Paul & Roger G. Noll. 1981. “Regulation in Theory and Practice: An Overview.” in Fromm, Gary, ed. Studies in Public Utility RegulationCambridge, Massachusetts: MIT PressGoogle Scholar
Joskow, Paul & Schmalensee, Richard. 1983. Markets for Power: An Analysis of Electrical Utility Deregulation. Cambridge, Massachusetts: MIT PressGoogle Scholar
Kalt, Joseph P. & Mark, A. Zupan. 1984. “Capture and Ideology in the Economic Theory of Politics.” American Economic Review. 74: 279Google Scholar
Kaplow, Louis. 1985. “Extension of Monopoly Power Through Leverage.” Columbia Law Review. 85: 515CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kaplow, Louis. 1986. “An Economic Analysis of Legal Transitions.” Harvard Law Review. 99: 509CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kearney, Joseph D. & Thomas, W. Merrill. 1998. The Great Transformation of Regulated Industries Law. Columbia Law Review. 98: 1323CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kelly, Kevin. 1997. “New Rules for the New Economy.” Wired Sept.: 140, 142–43Google Scholar
Kingdon, John W. 1995. Agendas, Alternatives, and Public PoliciesBoston: Addison WesleyGoogle Scholar
Kolasky, William J. 1999. “Network Effects: AContrarian View.” George Mason Law Review. 7: 577Google Scholar
Komesar, Neil K. 2001. Law'sLimits: The Rule of Law and the Supply and Demand of Rights. Cambridge: Cambridge University PressGoogle Scholar
Kutler, Stanley. 1971. Privilege and Creative Destruction: The Charles River Bridge Case. Baltimore: John Hopkins University PressGoogle Scholar
Kuttner, Robert. 1999. Everythingfor Sale: The Virtues and Limits of Markets. Chicago: University of Chicago PressGoogle Scholar
Laffont, Jean-Jacques & Tirole, Jean. 1990. “Adverse Selection and Renegotiation in Procurement.” Review of Economic Studies. 57: 597–626CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Laffont, Jean-Jacques & Tirole, Jean. 1993. A Theory of Incentives in Procurement and Regulation. Cambridge, Mass.: MIT PressGoogle Scholar
Laffont, Jean-Jacques & Tirole, Jean. 2000. Competition in Telecommunications. Cambridge, Mass.: MIT PressGoogle Scholar
Laswell, Harold. 1971. APre-View of the Policy Sciences. New York: American ElsevierGoogle Scholar
Lemley, Mark & McGowan, David. 1998. “Legal Implications of Network Economic Effects.” California Law Review. 86: 479CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lesser, Jonathon A. & Ainspan, Malcolm D.. 1994. “Retail Wheeling: Deja Vu All Over Again?The Electricity Journal. Apr.: 34CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Levinson, Daryl. 2000. “Making Government Pay:Markets, Politics, and the Allocation of Constitutional Costs.” University of Chicago Law Review. 67: 345CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lewis, Tracy & Poitevin, Michael. 1997. “Disclosure of Information in Regulatory Proceedings.” Journal of Law, Economics &Organization. 13: 50CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Levy, Brian & Pablo, T. Spiller. 1996. Regulations, Institutions and Commitment: Comparative Studies of Telecommunications. Cambridge: Cambridge University PressCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lichtman, Douglas, Baker, Scott & Krause, Kate. 2000. “Strategic Disclosure in the Patent System.” Vanderbilt Law Review. 53: 2175Google Scholar
Lopatka, John E. 1984. “The Electric Utility Price Squeezeas an Antitrust Cause of Action.” UCLA Law Review. 31: 563Google Scholar
MacAvoy, Paul W., Daniel, F. Spulber & Stangle, Bruce. 1989. “Is Competitive Entry Free? Bypass and Partial Deregulation in Natural Gas Markets.” Yale Journal on Regulation. 6: 209Google Scholar
Macey, Jonathan R. 1986. “Promoting Public-Regarding Legislation Through Statutory Interpretation: An Interest Group Model.” Columbia Law Review. 86: 223CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Macey, Jonathan R. 1998. “Public Choice and the Law.” in Newman, Peter, ed. The New Palgrave Dictionary of Economics and the LawLondon: United Kingdom: Macmillan Reference LimitedCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Macleod, W. Bentley. 1996. “Decision, Contract, and Emotion: Some Economics for a Complex and Confusing World.” Canadian Journal of Economics. 29: 788CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Macneil, Ian R. 1978. “Contracts: Adjustment of Long-term Economic Relations Under Classical, Neo-Classical, and Relational Contract Law.” Northwestern University Law Review. 72: 854Google Scholar
Mahoney, Paul G. & Sanchirico, Chris William. 2003. “Norms, Repeated Games and the Role of Law.” California Law Review. 91: 1281CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Malloy, Michael. 1998. “When You Wish Upon a Winstar: Contract Analysis and the Future of Regulatory Action.” Saint Louis University Law Journal. 42: 409Google Scholar
Markell, David L. 2000. “The Role of Deterrence-Based Enforcement in a ‘Reinvented’ State/Federal Relationship: The Divide Between Theory and Reality.” Harvard Environmental Law Review. 24:1
Martimort, David, Phillip De Donder & Etienne Billette de Villemeur. 2003. “An Incomplete Contract Perspective on Public Good Provision.”Toulouse Institut d'Economie Industrielle Working Paper, available at http://www.idei.fr/doc/wp/2003/public_good_provision.pdf
Martin, Robert B. III. 2003. “Sherman Shorts Outs:The Dimming of Antitrust Enforcement in the California Electricity Crisis.” Hastings Law Journal. 55: 271Google Scholar
Mashaw, Jerry. 1997. Greed, Chaos& Governance: Using Public Choice to Improve Public Law. New Haven, Conn.: Yale University PressGoogle Scholar
Maskin, Eric & Tirole, Jean. 1999. “Unforeseen Contingencies and Incomplete Contracts.” Review of Economic Studies. 66: 83CrossRefGoogle Scholar
McArthur, John Burritt. 1997. “Anti-Trust in the New[De]Regulated Natural Gas Industry.” Energy Law Journal. 18: 1Google Scholar
McGreal, Paul E. 1995. “Some Rice with Your Chevron?: Presumption and Deference in Regulatory Preemption.” Case Western Reserve Law Review. 45: 823Google Scholar
McGreal, Paul E. 1998. “The Flawed Economics of the Dormant Commerce Clause.” William & Mary Law Review. 39: 1191Google Scholar
McNollgast, . 1992. “Positive Canons: The Role of Legislative Bargains in Statutory Interpretation.” Georgetown Law Journal. 80: 705Google Scholar
McUsic, Molly S. 1996. “The Ghost of Lochner: Modern Takings Doctrine and Its Impact on Economic Legislation.” Boston University Law Review. 76: 605Google Scholar
Merrill, Thomas W. 1999. “Supplier of Last Resort: Who, What, Why?Public Utilities Fortnightly. July 15: 18Google Scholar
Merrill, Thomas W. & Henry, E. Smith. 2002. “The Property/Contract Interface.” Columbia Law Review. 101: 773CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Michaels, Robert J. 1996. “Stranded Investments, Stranded Intellectuals.” Regulation. 47: 51Google Scholar
Michelman, Frank. 1968. “Property, Utility, and Fairness: Comments on the Ethical Foundations of ‘Just Compensation’ Law.” Harvard Law Review. 80: 1165CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Michelman, Frank. 1988. “Takings 1987.” Columbia Law Review. 88: 1600CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Mishkin, Paul J. 1957. “The Variousness of ‘Federal Law’: Competence and Discretion in the Choice of National and State Rules for Decision.” University of Pennsylvania Law Review. 105: 797CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Mitnick, Barry M. 1980. The Political Economy of Regulation: Creating, Designing, and Removing Regulatory Forms. New York: Columbia University PressGoogle Scholar
Movsesian, Mark. 1998. “Are Statutes Really ‘Legislative Bargains?’ The Failure of the Contract Analogy in Statutory Interpretation.” North Carolina Law Review. 76: 1145Google Scholar
Mueller, Milton J. Jr. 1997. Universal Service: Competition, Interconnection, and Monopoly in the Making of the American Telephone SystemWashington, D.C.: American Enterprise InstituteGoogle Scholar
Nagle, John Copeland. 1995. “Waiving Sovereign Immunity inan Age of Clear Statement Rules.” Wisconsin Law Review. 1995: 771Google Scholar
Nelson, Caleb. 2000. “Preemption.” Virginia Law Review. 86: 225CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Noam, Eli. 1997. “Will Universal Service and Common Carriage Survive the Telecommunications Act of 1996?Columbia Law Review. 97: 955CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Noll, Roger. 1971. Reforming Regulation: Studies in the Regulation of Economic Activity. Washington, D.C.: BrookingsGoogle Scholar
Norlander, Gerald A. 1998. “Retail Choice: A Race tothe Bottom.” Public Utilities Fortnightly. Jan.1: 8 (letter to the editor)
North, Douglass C. 1996. “Epilogue: Economic Performance Through Time.” in Alston, Lee J., Eggertsson, Thráinn & Douglas, C. North, eds. Empirical Studies in Institutional Change. Cambridge: Cambridge University PressCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Norton, Floyd & Spivak, Mark. 1985. “The Wholesale Service Obligation of Electric Utilities.” Energy Law Journal. 6: 179Google Scholar
Note. 1923. “The Sherman Act as Applied to Railroads Regulated Under the Interstate Commerce Act.” Harvard Law Review. 36: 456CrossRef
Note. 1953. “Recent Cases: Antitrust –Primary Jurisdiction Applied in Action Against Members of Regulated Industries.” University of Pennsylvania Law Review. 101: 678
Pace, Joe D. 1987. “Wheeling and the Obligation to Serve.” Energy Law Journal. 8: 265Google Scholar
Page, William H. 1981. “Antitrust, Federalism and the Regulatory Process.” Boston University Law Review. 61: 1099Google Scholar
Page, William H. 1987. “Interest Groups, Antitrust, and State Regulation: Parker v. Brown in the Economic Theory of Legislation.” Duke Law Journal. 1987: 618CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Page, William H. & John, E. Lopatka. 1993. “State Regulation in the Shadow of Antitrust: FTC v. Ticor Title Insurance Co.” Supreme Court Economic Review. 3: 189CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Pechman, Carl. 1993. Regulating Power: The Economics of Electricity in the Information Age. Dordrecht: Kluwer Academic PressCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Peltzman, Sam. 1976. “Toward a More General Theory of Regulation.” Journal of Law and Economics. 19: 211CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Peltzman, Sam. 1989. “The Economic Theory of Regulationafter a Decade of Deregulation.” Brookings Papers on Economic Activity: Microeconomics. 1989: 1CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Percival, Robert V. 1995. “Environmental Federalism:Historical Roots and Contemporary Models.” Maryland Law Review. 54: 1141Google Scholar
Persson, Torsten, Roland, Gerard & Tabellini, Guido. 1997. “Separation of Powers and Political Accountability.” Quarterly Journal of Economics. 112: 1163CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Peterson, Andrea. 1989. “The Takings Clause: InSearch of Underlying Principles. Part I – A Critique of Current Takings Clause Doctrine.” California Law Review. 77: 1299CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Peterson, H. Craig. 1975. “An Empirical Test of Regulatory Effects.” Bell Journal of Economics and Management Science. 6: 111CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Phillips, Charles F. 1993. The Regulation of Public Utilities. Fairfax, Virginia: Public Utility ReportsGoogle Scholar
Picker, Randal C. 2002. “Understanding Statutory Bundles: Does the Sherman Act Come with the 1996 Telecommunications Act?”University of Chicago John M. Olin Program in Law & Economics, Working Paper No. 177, 2002. Available at http://www.law.uchicago.edu/Picker/Papers/Manhattan200.pdf
Pierce, Richard J. Jr. 1984. “Regulatory Treatment of Mistakes in Retrospect: Cancelled Plants and Excess Capacity.” University of Pennsylvania Law Review. 132: 497CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Pierce, Richard J. Jr. 1988. “Reconstituting the Natural Gas Industry from Wellhead to Burnertip.” Energy Law Journal. 9: 1Google Scholar
Pierce, Richard J. Jr. 1989. “Public Utility Regulatory Takings: Should the Judiciary Attempt to Police the Political Institutions?Georgetown Law Journal. 77: 2031Google Scholar
Pierce, Richard J. Jr. 1991. “The Unintended Effects of Judicial Review of Agency Rules: How Federal Courts Have Contributed to the Electricity Crisis of the 1990s.” Administrative Law Review. 43: 7Google Scholar
Pierce, Richard J. Jr. 1994. “The State of the Transition to Competitive Markets in Natural Gas and Electricity.” Energy Law Journal. 15: 323Google Scholar
Piraino, Thomas A. Jr. 1997. “A Proposed Antitrust Analysisof Telecommunications Joint Ventures.” Wisconsin Law Review. 1997: 639Google Scholar
Pitofsky, Robert. 1997. “Competition Policy in Communications Industries: New Antitrust Approaches.” Remarks presented at Glasser Legal Works Seminar on Competitive Policy in Communications Industries: New Antitrust Approach es, Federal Trade Commission, Washington, D.C., March 10. Available at http://www.ftc.gov/speeches/pitofsky/newcomm.htm
Platt, Harold. 1991. The Electric City: Energy and the Growth of the Chicago Area 880–1930Chicago: University of Chicago PressGoogle Scholar
Pleatt, George R. 1998. “Should Metering Stay at the Stand-Alone Disco?Public Utilities Fortnightly. Feb. 1Google Scholar
Poirier, Marc R. 2002. “The Virtue of Vagueness in Takings Doctrine.” Cardozo Law Review. 24: 93Google Scholar
Posner, Eric. 1995. “Contract Law in the Welfare State: A Defense of the Unconscionability Doctrine, Usury Laws, and Related Limits on the Freedom to Contract.” Journal of Legal Studies. 24: 283CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Posner, Eric. 2003. “Economic Analysis of Contract Law after Three Decades: Success or Failure?Yale Law Journal. 112: 829CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Posner, Richard A. 1974. “Theories of Economic Regulation.” Bell Journal of Economics and Management Science. 5: 335CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Posner, Richard A. 1979. “The Chicago School of Antitrust Analysis.” University of Pennsylvania Law Review. 127: 925CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Posner, Richard & Rosenfield, Andrew. 1977. “Impossibility and Related Doctrines in Contract Law: An Economic Analysis.” Journal of Legal Studies. 6: 83CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Priest, George. 1992. “The Origins of Utility Regulation and the ‘Theories of Regulation’ Debate.” Journal of Law &Economics. 36: 289CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Quirk, Paul J. 1981. Industry Influence in Federal Regulatory Agencies. Princeton, N.J.: Princeton University PressCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Robinson, Gustavus H. 1928. “The Public Utility Concept in American Law.” Harvard Law Review. 41: 277CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Rockefeller John, D. IV. 1991. “A Call for Action:The Pepper Commission's Blueprint for Health Care Reform.” Journal of the American Medical Association. 265: 2507Google Scholar
Rodden, Jonathan & Rose-Ackerman, Susan. 1997. “Does Federalism Preserve Markets?Virginia Law Review. 83: 1521CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Rose-Ackerman, Susan. 1980. “Risk Taking and Reelection: Does Federalism Promote Innovation?Journal of Legal Studies. 9: 593CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Rose-Ackerman, Susan. 1988. “Against AdHocery: A Comment on Michelman.” Columbia Law Review. 88: 1697CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Rose-Ackerman, Susan. 1992. “Regulatory Takings: Policy Analysis and Democratic Principles.” in Merucro, Nicholas, ed. Taking Property and Just Compensation: Law and Economic Perspectives of the Takings IssueDordrecht: Kluwer Academic PressCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Rose-Ackerman, Susan & Rossi, Jim. 2000. “Disentangling Deregulatory Takings.” Virginia Law Review. 86: 1435CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Rossi, Jim. 1994. “Redeeming Judicial Review: The Hard Look Doctrine and Federal Regulatory Efforts to Restructure the Electric Utility Industry.” Wisconsin Law Review. 1994: 763Google Scholar
Rossi, Jim. 1997. “Participation Run Amok: The Costsof Mass Participation for Deliberative Agency Decisionmaking.” Northwestern University Law Review. 92: 173Google Scholar
Rossi, Jim. 1998a. “The Common Law ‘Duty to Serve’ and Protection of Consumers in an Age of Competitive Retail Public Utility Restructuring.” Vanderbilt Law Review 51: 1233Google Scholar
Rossi, Jim. 1998b. “The Irony of Deregulatory Takings.” Texas Law Review. 77: 297Google Scholar
Rossi, Jim. 2002. “The Electric Power Deregulation Fiasco: Looking to Regulatory Federalism to Promote a Balance Between Markets and the Provision of Public Goods.” Michigan Law Review. 100: 1768CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Rossi, Jim. 2003. “Lowering the Filed Tariff Shield:Judicial Enforcement for a Deregulatory Era.” Vanderbilt Law Review. 56: 1591Google Scholar
Rossi, Jim. 2004. “Debilitating Doctrine: How the Filed Rate Policy Wreaks Havoc – And What Courts Can Do About It.” Public Utilities Fortnightly, November: 16Google Scholar
Rossi, Jim. Forthcoming 2005. “Dual Constitutions and Constitutional Duels.” William & Mary Law Review.
Rouse, Michael A. 1990. “A Re-Evaluation of the “Filed Rate” Doctrine in Light of Revised Regulatory Policy and Carriers'Practices: INF, Ltd. v. Spectro Alloys Corp.” Creighton Law Review. 23: 669Google Scholar
Rubin, Edward L. & Feeley, Malcolm. 1994. “Federalism: Some Notes on a National Neurosis.” UCLA Law Review. 41: 903Google Scholar
Rubin, Paul H., Curran, Christopher & Curran, John. 2001. “Litigation versus Legislation: Forum Shopping by Rent-Seekers.” Public Choice. 107: 295CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ruhl, J. B. & Salzman, James. 2003. “Regulatory Accretion in the Administrative State. Georgetown Law Journal. 91: 75Google Scholar
Santa, Donald F. Jr. 2000. “Who Needs What, and Why?Reporting and Disclosure Obligations in Emerging Competitive Electricity Markets.” Energy Law Journal. 21: 1Google Scholar
Savage, Leonard J. 1972. The Foundations of StatisticsNew York: Dover PublicationsGoogle Scholar
Schelling, Thomas. 1980. Strategy of Conflict, Second edition. Cambridge, Mass.: Harvard University PressGoogle Scholar
Schwartz, Jeffrey D. 1999. “The Use of Antitrust State Action Doctrine in the Deregulated Electric Utility Industry.” American University Law Review. 48: 1449Google Scholar
Schwartz, Joshua I. 1997. “Assembling Winstar: Triumpth of the Ideal of Congruence in Government Contracts Law?Public Contract Law Journal. 26: 481Google Scholar
Seidenfeld, Mark. 2004. “Pyrrhic Political Penalties: Why the Public Would Lose Under the ‘Penalty Default Canon.’George Washington Law Review. 72: 724Google Scholar
Shepsle, Kenneth A. 1992. “Congress is a ‘They,’ Not an ‘It’: Legislative Intent as an Oxymoron.” International Review of Law &Economics. 12: 239CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Sidak, J. Gregory & Spulber, Daniel. 1997. Deregulatory Takings and the Regulatory Contract: The Transformation of Network Industries in the United States. New York: Cambridge University PressCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Sillin, John O. 2003. “Why We Fell into the Heart of Darkness.” Public Utilities Fortnightly September 15: 30Google Scholar
Silverstein, Eileen. 1991. “Against Preemption in Labor Law.” Connecticut Law Review. 24: 1Google Scholar
Simon, Herbert. 1961. Administrative Behavior, Second edition. New York: MacmillanGoogle Scholar
Simons, Kenneth W. 2002. “Reflections on Assumption of the Risk.” UCLA Law Review. 50: 481Google Scholar
Simpson, James B. & Sarah, D. Strum. 1991. “How a Good Samaritan? Federal Income Tax Exemption for Charitable Hospitals Reconsidered.” University of Puget Sound Law Review. 14: 633Google Scholar
Singer, Joseph. 1996. “No Right to Exclude: Public Accommodations and Private Property.” Northwestern University Law Review. 90: 1283Google Scholar
Smith, Vernon. 1993. “Can Electric Power – A ‘Natural Monopoly’ – Be Deregulated?” in Landsberg, Hans H., ed. Making National Energy PolicyWashington, D.C.: Resources for the FutureGoogle Scholar
Sosnov, Leonard N. 2000. “Separation of Powers Shell Game: The Federal Witness Immunity Act.” Temple Law Review. 73: 171Google Scholar
Spann, Robert M. 1974. “Rate of Return Regulation and Efficiency in Production: An Empirical Test of the Averch-Johnson Thesis.” Bell Journal of Economic and Management Science. 5: 38CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Speidel, Richard. 1981. “Court-Imposed Price Adjustments Under Long-Term Supply Contracts.” Northwestern University Law Review. 76: 369, 381–94Google Scholar
Spence, David B. & Murray, Paula. 1999. “The Law, Economics, and Politics of Federal Preemption Analysis: A Quantitative Analysis.” California Law Review. 87: 1125CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Spitzer, Matthew. 1988. “Antitrust, Federalism, and the Rational Choice Political Economy: A Critique of Capture Theory.” Southern California Law Review. 61: 1293Google Scholar
Spulber, Daniel F. & Christopher, S. Yoo. 2003. Access to Networks: Constitutional and Economic Connections. Cornell Law Review. 88: 885Google Scholar
Stearns, Maxell L. 2003. “A Beautiful Mend: A Game Theoretical Analysis of the Dormant Commerce Clause Doctrine.” William & Mary Law Review. 45: 1Google Scholar
Stewart, Richard B. 1990. “Madison'sNightmare.” University of Chicago Law Review. 57: 335CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Stigler, George. 1971. “The Theory of Economic Regulation.” Bell Journal of Economic and Management Science. 2: 3CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Stigler, George & Friedland, Claire. 1962. “What Can Regulators Regulate? The Case of Electricity.” Journal of Law &Economics. 5: 1CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Sugden, Robert. 1995. “A Theory of Focal Points.” Economic Journal. 105: 533CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Sullivan, Lawrence A. 1992. “Section 2 of the Sherman Act and Vertical Strategies by Dominant Firms.” Southwestern University Law Review. 21: 1227Google Scholar
Sunstein, Cass. 1989. “Interpreting Statutes in the Regulatory State.” Harvard Law Review. 103: 405CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Sunstein, Cass. 1995. “Incompletely The orized Agreements.” Harvard Law Review. 108: 1733CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Symposium, . 2003. “Is There an Ideal Way to Deal with the Non-Ideal World of Legal Change?Journal of Contemporary Legal Issues. 13: 1Google Scholar
Talley, Eric. 2001. “Disclosure Norms.” University of Pennsylvania Law Review. 149: 1955CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Tirole, Jean. 2002. The Theory of Industrial Organization. Cambridge, Mass.: MIT PressGoogle Scholar
Tomain, Joseph P. & Shapiro, Sidney. 1997. “Analyzing Government Regulation.” Administrative Law Review. 39: 377Google Scholar
U.S. Energy Information Administration. 1997. Electricity Prices in a Competitive Environment: Marginal Cost Pricing of Generation Services and Financial Status of Electric Utilities – A Preliminary Analysis Through 2015. Washington, D.C.: U.S. Department of Energy
Alstine, Michael P. 2002. “The Costs of Legal Change.” UCLA Law Review. 49: 789Google Scholar
Doren, Peter & Taylor, Jerry. 2004. “Rethinking Restructuring.” Public Utilities Fortnightly. February: 12Google Scholar
Mehren, Robert B. 1954. “The Antitrust Laws and Regulated Industries: The Doctrine of Primary Jurisdiction.” Harvard Law Review. 67: 929CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Watts, Duncan J. 2003. Six Degreesof Separation: The Science of a Connected Age. New York: W.W. Norton& CoGoogle Scholar
Weaver, Jacqueline. 2004. “Can Energy Markets BeTrusted?Houston Business and Tax Law Journal. 4: 1Google Scholar
Weiser, Philip J. 1999. “Chevron, Cooperative Federalism, and Tele communications Reform.” Vanderbilt Law Review. 52: 1Google Scholar
Weiser, Philip J. 2001a. “Federal Common Law, Cooperative Federalism, and the Enforcement of the Telcom Act.” New York University Law Review. 76: 1692Google Scholar
Weiser, Philip J. 2001b. “Towards a Constitutional Architecture for Cooperative Federalism.” North Carolina Law Review. 79: 663Google Scholar
Weiser, Philip J. 2003. “Goldwasser, The Telecom Act, and Reflections on Antitrust Remedies.” Administrative Law Review. 55: 1Google Scholar
White, Matthew W. 1996. “Power Struggles: Explaining Deregulatory Reforms in Electricity Markets.” Brookings Papers: Microeconomics. 1996: 201CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Wiley, John Shepard Jr. 1986. “A Capture Theory of Antitrust Federalism.” Harvard Law Review. 99: 713CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Williamson, Oliver. 1975. Marketsand Hierarchies: Analysis and Antitrust ImplicationsNew York: Free PressGoogle Scholar
Williamson, Oliver. 1976. “Franchise Bidding for Natural Monopolies – In General and with Respect to CATV.”Bell Journal of Economics. 7: 73CrossRef
Williamson, Oliver. 1979. “Transaction Cost Economics: The Governance of Contractual Relations.” Journal of Law & Economics. 22: 233CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Williamson, Oliver. 1996a. The Mechanisms of GovernanceNew York: Oxford University PressGoogle Scholar
Williamson, Oliver. 1996b. “Response: Deregulatory Takings and the Breach of the Regulatory Contract: Some Precautions.” New York University Law Review. 71: 1007Google Scholar
Wright, Ronald. 1996. “When Do We Want Incomplete Agreements: A Comment on Sunstein's Holmes Devise Lecture.” Wake Forest Law Review. 31: 459Google Scholar
Wyman, Bruce. 1903. “The Law of the Public Callings as aSolution of the Trust Problem.” Harvard Law Review. 17: 156, 161CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Young, Ernest A. 1999. “Preemption at Sea.” George Washington Law Review. 67: 273Google Scholar
Yoo, John C. 1998. “Sounds of Sovereignty: Defining Federalism in the 1990s.” Indiana Law Review. 32: 27Google Scholar
Zajac, Edward E. 1995. The Political Economy of Fairness. Cambridge, Massachusetts: MIT Press.Google Scholar
Adams, Henry Carter. 1887 (January). “Relation of the State to Industrial Action.” Publications of the American Economics Association. 1: 55Google Scholar
Ahdieh, Robert B. 2004. “Law's Signal: A Cueing Theory of Law in Market Transition.” Southern California Law Review. 77: 215Google Scholar
Alexander, Barbara & The National Consumer Law Center. 1996. Consumer Protection Proposals for Retail Electric Competition: Model Legislation and RegulationsBoston: National Consumer Law CenterGoogle Scholar
Alexander, Gregory S. 1996. “Ten Years of Takings.” Journal of Legal Education. 46: 586Google Scholar
Alston, Lee J., Eggertsson, Thráinn & North, Douglas C., eds. Empirical Studies in Institutional ChangeCambridge: Cambridge University PressCrossRef
Areeda, Phillip E. & Hovenkamp, Herbert. 2000. IA Antitrust Law, Second edition. Boston: Little, BrownGoogle Scholar
Arteburn, Norman F. 1927. “The Origin and First Test of Public Callings.” University of Pennsylvania Law Review. 75: 411CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Austin, Regina. 1983. “The Insurance Classification Controversy.” University of Pennsylvania Law Review. 131: 517CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Averch, Harvey & Johnson, Leland L. 1962. “Behavior of the Firm Under Regulatory Constraint.” American Economic Review. 52: 1052Google Scholar
Aviram, Amitai. 2003. “Regulation by Networks.” Brigham Young University Law Review. 2003: 1179Google Scholar
Ayres, Ian & Braithwaite, John. 1992. Responsive Regulation: Transcending the Deregulation Debate. New York: Oxford University PressGoogle Scholar
Ayres, Ian & Gertner, Robert. 1992. “Strategic Contractual Inefficiency and the Optimal Choice of Legal Rules.” Yale Law Journal. 101: 729CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Baer, William J. 1997. “FTC Perspectives on Competition Policy and Enforcement Initiatives in Electric Power.” Presented at the Conference on the New Rules of the Game for Electric Power: Antitrust and Anticompetitive Behavior, Bureau of Competition, Federal Trade Commission, Washington, D.C., December 4. Available at http://www.ftc.gov/speeches/other/elec1204.htm
Baker, Scott and Krawiec, Kimberly. 2004. “The Penalty Default Canon.” George Washington Law Review. 72: 663Google Scholar
Baron, David & Ferejohn, John. 1989. “Bargaining in Legislatures.” American Political Science Review. 83: 1181CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Baumol, William J. & Merrill, Thomas W. 1996. “Deregulatory Takings, Breach of the Regulatory Contract, and the Telecommunications Act of 1996.” New York University Law Review. 72: 1037Google Scholar
Becker, Gary. 1983. “A Theory of Competition Among Pressure Groups for Political Influence.” Quarterly Journal of Economics. 98: 371CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Beer, Samuel H. 1977. “Political Overload and Federalism.” Polity. 10: 5CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Berg, Jessica Wilen. 2003. “Understanding Waiver.” Houston Law Review. 40: 281Google Scholar
Bernheim, B. Douglas & Whinston, Michael D.. 1998. “Incomplete Contracts and Strategic Ambiguity.” American Economic Review. 88: 902Google Scholar
Bernstein, David E. 2003. “Lochner's Legacy's Legacy.” Texas Law Review. 82: 1Google Scholar
Bernstein, Lisa. 1992. “Opting Out of the Legal System: Extra Legal Contractual Relations in the Diamond Industry.” Journal of Legal Studies. 21: 115CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bernstein, Lisa. 2001. “Private Commercial Law in the Cotton Industry: Creating Cooperation Through Rules, Norms and Institutions.” Michigan Law Review. 99: 1724CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bolze, Ray S., Pierce, John C. & Walsh, Linda L., 2000. “Antitrust Law Regulation: A New Focus for a Competitive Energy Industry.” Energy Law Journal. 21: 79Google Scholar
Borenstein, Severin. 2002. “The Trouble with Electricity Markets: Understanding California's Restructuring Disaster.” Journal of Economic Perspectives. 16(1): 191CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Borenstein, Severin & Bushnell, James D.. 2000. “Electricity Restructuring: Deregulation or Reregulation?Regulation 23(2): 46Google Scholar
Boudin, Michael. 1986. “Antitrust Doctrine and the Sway of Metaphor.” Georgetown Law Journal. 75: 395Google Scholar
Bouknight, J. A. & Raskin, David B.. 1987. “Planning for Wholesale Customer Loads in a Competitive Environment: The Obligation to Provide Wholesale Service under the Federal Power Act.” Energy Law Journal. 8: 237Google Scholar
Boyes, William J. 1976. “An Empirical Examination of the Averch-Johnson Effect.” Economic Inquiry. 14: 25CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bradley, Robert L., Jr. 2003. “The Origins and Development of Electric Power Regulation.” In Grossman, Peter Z. & Cole, Daniel H., eds. The End of a Natural Monopoly: Deregulation and Competition in the Electric Power IndustryAmsterdam: Elsevier Science (JAI Imprint)Google Scholar
Brennan, Timothy J. & Boyd, James. 1997. “Stranded Costs, Takings, and the Law and Economics of Implicit Contracts.” Journal of Regulatory Economics. 11: 41CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Breyer, Stephen. 1982. Regulation and its Reform. Cambridge, Mass.: Harvard University PressGoogle Scholar
Brown, Stephen J. & Sibley, David S.. 1986. The Theory of Public Utility Pricing. New York: Cambridge University PressCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Burdick, Charles K. 1911. “The Origin of the Peculiar Duties of Public Service Companies.” Columbia Law Review. 11: 514CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Buzbee, William W. 2003. “Recognizing the Regulatory Commons: A Theory of Regulatory Gaps.” Iowa Law Review. 89: 1Google Scholar
Cain, Bruce, Ferejohn, John & Fiorina, Morris. 1987. The Personal Vote: Constituency Service and Electoral Independence. Cambridge, Mass.: Harvard University PressCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Calabresi, Guido & Douglas, A. Melamed. 1972. “Property Rules, Liability Rules, and Inalienability: One View of the Cathedral.” Harvard Law Review. 85: 1089CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Candeub, Adam. 2004. “Network Interconnection and Takings.” Syracuse Law Review. 54: 369Google Scholar
Carron, Andrew S. & Paul, W. MacAvoy. 1981. The Decline of Service in Regulated IndustriesWashington, D.C.: American Enterprise InstituteGoogle Scholar
Casson, Mark. 1997. Information and Organization: A New Perspective on the Theory of the FirmNew York: Clarendon PressGoogle Scholar
Chen, Jim. 1999. “The Second Coming of Smyth v. Ames.” Texas Law Review. 77: 1535Google Scholar
Chen, Jim. 2000. “Standing in the Shadows of Giants: The Role of Intergenerational Equity in Telecommunications Reform.” University of Colorado Law Review. 71: 921Google Scholar
Chen, Jim. 2003a. “The Vertical Dimension of Cooperative Competition Policy.” Antitrust Bulletin. 48: 1005CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Chen, Jim. 2003b. “Subsidized Rural Telephony and the Public Interest: A Case Study in Cooperative Federalism and Its Pitfalls.” Journal on Telecommunications & High Technology Law. 2: 307Google Scholar
Chen, Jim. 2003c. “A Vision Softly Creeping: Congressional Acquiesence and the Dormant Commerce Clause.” Minnesota Law Review. 88: 1764Google Scholar
Chen, Jim. 2004. “The Nature of the Public Utility: Infrastructure, the Market, and the Law.” Northwestern University Law Review. 98: 1617Google Scholar
Cirace, John. 1982. “An Economic Analysis of the ‘State-Municipal Action’ Antitrust Cases.” Texas Law Review. 61: 481Google Scholar
Coase, Ronald H. 1937. “The Nature of the Firm.” Economica. 4: 386CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Coase, Ronald H. 1960. “The Problem of Social Costs.” Journal of Law and Economics. 3: 1CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Coenen, Dan T. 1989. “Untangling the Market-Participant Exception to the Dormant Commerce Clause.” Michigan Law Review. 88: 395CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Cohen, George M. 1994. “The Fault Lines in Contract Damages.” Virginia Law Review. 80: 1225CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Cole, Daniel H. 2003. “The Regulatory Contract.” in Grossman, Peter Z. & Daniel, H. Cole, eds. The End of a Natural Monopoly: Deregulation and Competition in the Electric Power IndustryAmsterdam: Elsevier Science (JAI Imprint)Google Scholar
Colton, Roger. 1991. “A Cost-Based Response to Low-Income Energy Problems.” Public Utilities Fortnightly. March 1: 31Google Scholar
Colton, Roger. 1997. The ‘Obligation to Serve’ and a Competitive Electric Industry. Report of DOE Office of Economic, Electricity and Natural Gas Analysis, May
Costello, Kenneth W. & Robert, J. Graniere. 1997. Deregulation-Restructuring: Evidence from Individual IndustriesColumbus, Ohio: National Regulatory Research InstituteCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Costello, Kenneth W. & , J. Rodney Lemon. 1996. Unbundling the Retail Natural Gas Market: Current Activities and Guidance for Serving Residential and Small Consumers. Columbus, Ohio: National Regulatory Research InstituteCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Courville, Leon. 1974. “Regulation and Efficiency in the Electric Utility Industry.” Bell Journal of Economic and Management Science. 5: 53CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Cramton, Roger C. 1986. “Demystifying Legal Scholarship.” Georgetown Law Journal. 75: 1Google Scholar
Cudahy, Richard D. 2002a. “Electric Deregulation after California: Down But Not Out.” Administrative Law Review. 54: 333Google Scholar
Cudahy, Richard D. 2002b. “Full Circle in the Formerly Regulated Industries?Loyola University of Chicago Law Journal. 33: 767Google Scholar
Davis, Mary J. 2002. “Unmasking the Presumption in Favor of Preemption.” Southern California Law Review. 53: 967Google Scholar
Figueiredo, John M. & Figueiredo, Rui J. P. Jr. 2002. “The Allocation of Resources by Interest Groups: Lobbying, Litigation and Administrative Regulation.” Business and Politics. 4(2): 161CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Dechert, W. Davis. 1984. “Has the Averch-Johnson Effect Been Theoretically Justified?Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control. 8: 1CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Deisinger, Chris. 2000. “The Backlash Against Merchant Plants and the Need for a New Regulatory Model.” Electricity Journal. 13: 51CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Demsetz, Harold. 1968. “Why Regulate Utilities?Journal of Law & Economics. 11: 55CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Denning, Brannon P. 1999. “Justice Thomas, the Import-Export Clause, and Camps Newfound/Owatonna v. Harrison.” University of Colorado Law Review. 70: 155Google Scholar
Denning, Brannon P. 2003. “Why the Privileges and Immunities Clause of Article IV Cannot Replace the Dormant Commerce Clause Doctrine.” Minnesota Law Review. 84: 284Google Scholar
Derthick, Martha & Paul, J. Quirk. 1985. The Politics of Deregulation. Washington, D.C.: BrookingsGoogle Scholar
Dibadj, Reza. 2004. “Saving Antitrust.” University of Colorado Law Review. 75: 745Google Scholar
Diver, Colin. 1983. “The Optimal Precision of Administrative Rules.” Yale Law Journal. 93: 65CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Dorf, Michael H. & Charles, F. Sabel. 1998. “A Constitution of Democratic Experimentalism.” Columbia Law Review. 98: 267CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Easterbrook, Frank H. 1984. “The Limits of Antitrust.” Texas Law Review. 63: 1Google Scholar
Easterbrook, Frank H. 1988. “The Role of Original Intent in Statutory Construction.” Harvard Journal of Law and Public Policy. 11: 59Google Scholar
Eaton, Jade Alice. 1994. “Recent United States Department of Justice Actions in the Electric Utility Industry.” Connecticut Journal of International Law. 9: 857Google Scholar
Economides, Nicholas. 2003. “The Tragic Inefficiency of the M-ECPR.” in Shampine, Allan L., ed. Down to the Wire: Studies in the Diffusion and Regulation of Telecommunications TechnologiesHauppauge, N.Y.: Nova Science PublishersGoogle Scholar
Eggertsson, Thráinn. 1996. “A Note on the Economics of Institutions.” in Alston, Lee J., Eggertsson, Thráinn & Douglas, C. North, eds. Empirical Studies in Institutional ChangeCambridge: Cambridge University PressCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Elhauge, Einer. 2002. “Preference-Eliciting Statutory Default Rules.” Columbia Law Review. 102: 2163Google Scholar
Ellickson, Robert. 1994. Order Without Law: How Neighbors Settle Disputes. Cambridge, Mass.: Harvard University PressGoogle Scholar
Ely, John Hart. 1980. Democracy and Distrust: A Theory of Judicial ReviewCambridge, Mass.: Harvard University PressGoogle Scholar
Ely, Richard T. 1887. “The Nature and Significance of the Corporation.” Harper's Magazine. 75: 71Google Scholar
Engel, Kristen H. 1999. “The Dormant Commerce Clause Threat to Market-Based Regulation: The Case of Electricity Deregulation.” Ecology Law Quarterly. 26: 243Google Scholar
Epstein, Richard A. 1984. “Toward a Revitalization of the Contract Clause.” University of Chicago Law Review. 51: 703CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Epstein, Richard A. 1985. Takings: Private Property and the Power of Eminent Domain. Cambridge, Mass.: Harvard University PressGoogle Scholar
Epstein, Richard A. 1995. “The Permit Power Meets the Constitution.” Iowa Law Review 81: 407Google Scholar
Epstein, Richard A. 1997a. “A Clear View from The Cathedral: The Dominance of Property Rules.” Yale Law Journal. 106: 2091, 2128CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Epstein, Richard A. 1997b. “Takings, Exclusivity and Speech: The Legacy of Prune Yard v. Robins.” University of Chicago Law Review. 64: 21CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Eskridge, William N. Jr. & Philip, P. Frickey. 1992. “Quasi-Constitutional Law: Clear Statement Rules as Constitutional Lawmaking.” Vanderbilt Law Review. 45: 593Google Scholar
Eule, Julian N. 1982. “Laying the Dormant Commerce Clause to Rest.” Yale Law Journal. 91: 425CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Farber, Daniel A. 1991. Legislative Deals and Statutory Bequests. Minnesota Law Review. 75: 667Google Scholar
Farber, Daniel A. & Philip, Frickey. 1991. Law and Public Choice: A Critical IntroductionChicago: University of Chicago PressCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ferrey, Steven. 1997. “Renewable Subsidies in the Age of Deregulation: State-Imposed Preferences May Have Come to the Wrong Place at the Wrong Time.” Fortnightly. December: 22Google Scholar
Fisch, Jill E. 1997. “Retroactivity and Legal Change: An Equilibrium Approach.” Harvard Law Review. 110: 1055CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Fox-Penner, Peter. 1997. Electric Utility Restructuring: A Guide to the Competitive Era. Vienna, Virginia: Public Utility ReportsGoogle Scholar
Frankfurter, Felix & Landis, James. 1925. “The Compact Clause of the Constitution – A Study in Interstate Adjustments.” Yale Law Journal. 34: 685CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Freeman, Jody. 1997. “Collaborative Governance in the Administrative State.” UCLA Law Review. 45: 1Google Scholar
Freeman, Jody. 2000. “The Contracting State.” Florida State University Law Review. 28: 155Google Scholar
Friendly, Henry J. 1964. “In Praise of Erie – And of the New Federal Common Law.” New York University Law Review. 39: 383Google Scholar
Furubotn, Eirik G. & Rudolf, Richter. 1998. Institutions and Economic Theory: The Contribution of the New Institutional Economics. Ann Arbor: University of Michig an PressGoogle Scholar
Garbaum, Stephen A. 1994. “The Nature of Preemption.” Cornell Law Review. 79: 767Google Scholar
Garland, Merrick B. 1987. “Antitrust and State Action: Economic Efficiency and the Political Process.” Yale Law Journal. 96: 486CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Gey, Steven G. 1989–90. “The Political Economy of the Dormant Commerce Clause.” NYU Review of Law & Social Change. 17: 1Google Scholar
Gifford, Daniel J. 1995. “Federalism, Efficiency, the Commerce Clause, and the Sherman Act: Why We Should Follow a Consistent Free Market Policy.” Emory Law Journal. 44: 1227Google Scholar
Gillette, Clayton. 1991. “In Partial Praise of Dillon's Rule, or, Can Public Choice Theory Justify Local Government Law?Chicago-Kent Law Review. 67: 959Google Scholar
Gilliam, Thomas J. Jr. 1997. “Contracting with the United States in its Role as Regulator: Striking a Bargain with an Equitable Sovereign or Capricious Siren.” Mississippi College Law Review. 18: 247Google Scholar
Glazer, Craig A. & , M. Bryan Little. 1999. “The Rolesof Antitrust Law and Regulatory Oversight in the Restructured Electricity Industry.” Electricity Journal. 12: 21CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Goldberg, Victor. 1976. “Regulation and Administered Contracts.” Bell Journal of Economics. 7: 444CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Goldsmith, Richard. 1989. “Utility Rates and ‘Takings’.” Energy Law Journal. 10: 241Google Scholar
Gómez-Ibáñez, José A. 2003. Regulating Infrastructure: Monopoly Contracts and DiscretionCambridge, Mass.: Harvard University PressGoogle Scholar
Goodin, Robert E. 1982. Political Theory and Public Policy. Chicago: University of Chicago PressGoogle Scholar
Goodman, James. 2003. BlackoutNew York: North Point PressGoogle Scholar
Gormley, William T. Jr. 1983. The Politics of Public Utility Regulation. Pittsburgh: University of Pitts burgh PressGoogle Scholar
Grossman, Peter Z. 2003. “Is Anything Naturally aMonopoly?” in Grossman, Peter Z. & Daniel, H. Cole, eds. The End of a Natural Monopoly: Deregulation and Competition in the Electric Power Industry. Amsterdam: Elsevier Science (JAIImprint)Google Scholar
Grossman, Peter Z. & Daniel, H. Cole. 2003. The End of a Natural Monopoly: Deregulation and Competition in the Electric Power Industry. Amsterdam: Elsevier Science (JAIImprint)Google Scholar
Haar, Charles M. & Daniel, W. Fessler. 1986. The Wrong Side of the Tracks: A Revolutionary Rediscovery of the Common Law Tradition of Fairness in the Struggle Against Inequality. New York: Simon & SchusterGoogle Scholar
Hadfield, Gillian. 1999. “Of Sovereignty and Contract: Damages for Breach of Contract by the Government.” Southern California Interdisciplinary Law Journal. 8: 467Google Scholar
Hale, G. E. & Hale, Rosemary. 1962. “Competition or Control VI: Application of Antitrust Laws to Regulated Industries.” University of Pennsylvania Law Review. 111: 46CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hall, Gus & Pierce, Richard., 1997. “Retail Gas Reform: Learning from the Georgia Model.” Public Utilities Fortnightly. April 15: 22Google Scholar
Hart, Oliver & Moore, John. 1999. “Foundations of Incomplete Contracts.” Review of Economic Studies. 66: 115CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hart, Oliver D. 1988. “Incomplete Contracts and the Theory of the Firm.” Journal of Law, Economics and Organization. 4: 119Google Scholar
Hart, Oliver D. 1995. Firms, Contracts, and Financial Structure. Oxford: Oxford University PressCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hills, Roderick M. Jr. 1999. “Dissecting the State:The Use of Federal Law to Free State and Local Officials from State Legislatures'Control.” Michigan Law Review. 97: 1201CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hills, Roderick M., Jr. 2003. “Against Preemption:How Federalism Can Improve the National Lawmaking Process.” Working paper available at http://papers.ssrn.com/sol3/papers.cfm?abstract_id=412000
Hirsh, Richard F. 1999. Power Loss: The Origins of Deregulation and Restructuring in the American Electric Utility IndustryCambridge, Mass.: MIT PressGoogle Scholar
Hirst, Eric & Baxter, Lester. 1995. “How Stranded Will Electric Utilities Be?Public Utilities Fortnightly Feb. 15: 30–32Google Scholar
Hoke, S. Candice. 1991. “Preemption Pathologies and Civic Republican Values.” Boston University Law Review. 71: 685Google Scholar
Holmes, Oliver Wendell. 1920. Collected Legal Papers. New York: Harcourt, Brace &CoGoogle Scholar
Horwich, Allan. 2000. “The Neglected Relationship of Materiality and Recklessness in Actions under Rule 10b-5.” Business Lawyer. 55: 1023Google Scholar
Hovenkamp, Herbert. 1991. Enterpriseand American Law, 1836–1937. Cambridge, Mass.: Harvard University PressGoogle Scholar
Hovenkamp, Herbert. 1999a. Federal Antitrust Policy: The Law of Competition and Its PracticeSt. Paul, Minnesota: West GroupGoogle Scholar
Hovenkamp, Herbert. 1999b. “The Takings Clause and Improvident Regulatory Bargains.” Yale Law Journal. 108: 801CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Humphrey, Andrew G. 1985. “Antitrust Jurisdiction and Remedies in an Electric Utility Price Squeeze.” University of Chicago Law Review. 52: 1090
Inman, Robert P. & Daniel, L. Rubinfeld. 1997. “Making Sense of the Antitrust State-Action Doctrine: Balancing Political Participation and Economic Efficiency in Regulatory Federalism.” Texas Law Review. 75: 1203Google Scholar
Isser, Steve & Steven, A. Mitnick. 1998. “Enron's Battle with PECO.” Public Utilities Fortnightly Mar. 1: 38Google Scholar
Jaffe, Louis L. 1964. “Primary Jurisdiction.” Harvard Law Review. 77: 1037CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Joskow, Paul. 1977. “Commercial Impossibility, the Uranium Market, and the Westinghouse Case.” Journal of Legal Studies. 6: 119CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Joskow, Paul J. 2001. “California's Electricity Crisis.” Oxford Journal of Economic Policy. 17: 365CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Joskow, Paul & Roger G. Noll. 1981. “Regulation in Theory and Practice: An Overview.” in Fromm, Gary, ed. Studies in Public Utility RegulationCambridge, Massachusetts: MIT PressGoogle Scholar
Joskow, Paul & Schmalensee, Richard. 1983. Markets for Power: An Analysis of Electrical Utility Deregulation. Cambridge, Massachusetts: MIT PressGoogle Scholar
Kalt, Joseph P. & Mark, A. Zupan. 1984. “Capture and Ideology in the Economic Theory of Politics.” American Economic Review. 74: 279Google Scholar
Kaplow, Louis. 1985. “Extension of Monopoly Power Through Leverage.” Columbia Law Review. 85: 515CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kaplow, Louis. 1986. “An Economic Analysis of Legal Transitions.” Harvard Law Review. 99: 509CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kearney, Joseph D. & Thomas, W. Merrill. 1998. The Great Transformation of Regulated Industries Law. Columbia Law Review. 98: 1323CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kelly, Kevin. 1997. “New Rules for the New Economy.” Wired Sept.: 140, 142–43Google Scholar
Kingdon, John W. 1995. Agendas, Alternatives, and Public PoliciesBoston: Addison WesleyGoogle Scholar
Kolasky, William J. 1999. “Network Effects: AContrarian View.” George Mason Law Review. 7: 577Google Scholar
Komesar, Neil K. 2001. Law'sLimits: The Rule of Law and the Supply and Demand of Rights. Cambridge: Cambridge University PressGoogle Scholar
Kutler, Stanley. 1971. Privilege and Creative Destruction: The Charles River Bridge Case. Baltimore: John Hopkins University PressGoogle Scholar
Kuttner, Robert. 1999. Everythingfor Sale: The Virtues and Limits of Markets. Chicago: University of Chicago PressGoogle Scholar
Laffont, Jean-Jacques & Tirole, Jean. 1990. “Adverse Selection and Renegotiation in Procurement.” Review of Economic Studies. 57: 597–626CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Laffont, Jean-Jacques & Tirole, Jean. 1993. A Theory of Incentives in Procurement and Regulation. Cambridge, Mass.: MIT PressGoogle Scholar
Laffont, Jean-Jacques & Tirole, Jean. 2000. Competition in Telecommunications. Cambridge, Mass.: MIT PressGoogle Scholar
Laswell, Harold. 1971. APre-View of the Policy Sciences. New York: American ElsevierGoogle Scholar
Lemley, Mark & McGowan, David. 1998. “Legal Implications of Network Economic Effects.” California Law Review. 86: 479CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lesser, Jonathon A. & Ainspan, Malcolm D.. 1994. “Retail Wheeling: Deja Vu All Over Again?The Electricity Journal. Apr.: 34CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Levinson, Daryl. 2000. “Making Government Pay:Markets, Politics, and the Allocation of Constitutional Costs.” University of Chicago Law Review. 67: 345CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lewis, Tracy & Poitevin, Michael. 1997. “Disclosure of Information in Regulatory Proceedings.” Journal of Law, Economics &Organization. 13: 50CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Levy, Brian & Pablo, T. Spiller. 1996. Regulations, Institutions and Commitment: Comparative Studies of Telecommunications. Cambridge: Cambridge University PressCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lichtman, Douglas, Baker, Scott & Krause, Kate. 2000. “Strategic Disclosure in the Patent System.” Vanderbilt Law Review. 53: 2175Google Scholar
Lopatka, John E. 1984. “The Electric Utility Price Squeezeas an Antitrust Cause of Action.” UCLA Law Review. 31: 563Google Scholar
MacAvoy, Paul W., Daniel, F. Spulber & Stangle, Bruce. 1989. “Is Competitive Entry Free? Bypass and Partial Deregulation in Natural Gas Markets.” Yale Journal on Regulation. 6: 209Google Scholar
Macey, Jonathan R. 1986. “Promoting Public-Regarding Legislation Through Statutory Interpretation: An Interest Group Model.” Columbia Law Review. 86: 223CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Macey, Jonathan R. 1998. “Public Choice and the Law.” in Newman, Peter, ed. The New Palgrave Dictionary of Economics and the LawLondon: United Kingdom: Macmillan Reference LimitedCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Macleod, W. Bentley. 1996. “Decision, Contract, and Emotion: Some Economics for a Complex and Confusing World.” Canadian Journal of Economics. 29: 788CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Macneil, Ian R. 1978. “Contracts: Adjustment of Long-term Economic Relations Under Classical, Neo-Classical, and Relational Contract Law.” Northwestern University Law Review. 72: 854Google Scholar
Mahoney, Paul G. & Sanchirico, Chris William. 2003. “Norms, Repeated Games and the Role of Law.” California Law Review. 91: 1281CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Malloy, Michael. 1998. “When You Wish Upon a Winstar: Contract Analysis and the Future of Regulatory Action.” Saint Louis University Law Journal. 42: 409Google Scholar
Markell, David L. 2000. “The Role of Deterrence-Based Enforcement in a ‘Reinvented’ State/Federal Relationship: The Divide Between Theory and Reality.” Harvard Environmental Law Review. 24:1
Martimort, David, Phillip De Donder & Etienne Billette de Villemeur. 2003. “An Incomplete Contract Perspective on Public Good Provision.”Toulouse Institut d'Economie Industrielle Working Paper, available at http://www.idei.fr/doc/wp/2003/public_good_provision.pdf
Martin, Robert B. III. 2003. “Sherman Shorts Outs:The Dimming of Antitrust Enforcement in the California Electricity Crisis.” Hastings Law Journal. 55: 271Google Scholar
Mashaw, Jerry. 1997. Greed, Chaos& Governance: Using Public Choice to Improve Public Law. New Haven, Conn.: Yale University PressGoogle Scholar
Maskin, Eric & Tirole, Jean. 1999. “Unforeseen Contingencies and Incomplete Contracts.” Review of Economic Studies. 66: 83CrossRefGoogle Scholar
McArthur, John Burritt. 1997. “Anti-Trust in the New[De]Regulated Natural Gas Industry.” Energy Law Journal. 18: 1Google Scholar
McGreal, Paul E. 1995. “Some Rice with Your Chevron?: Presumption and Deference in Regulatory Preemption.” Case Western Reserve Law Review. 45: 823Google Scholar
McGreal, Paul E. 1998. “The Flawed Economics of the Dormant Commerce Clause.” William & Mary Law Review. 39: 1191Google Scholar
McNollgast, . 1992. “Positive Canons: The Role of Legislative Bargains in Statutory Interpretation.” Georgetown Law Journal. 80: 705Google Scholar
McUsic, Molly S. 1996. “The Ghost of Lochner: Modern Takings Doctrine and Its Impact on Economic Legislation.” Boston University Law Review. 76: 605Google Scholar
Merrill, Thomas W. 1999. “Supplier of Last Resort: Who, What, Why?Public Utilities Fortnightly. July 15: 18Google Scholar
Merrill, Thomas W. & Henry, E. Smith. 2002. “The Property/Contract Interface.” Columbia Law Review. 101: 773CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Michaels, Robert J. 1996. “Stranded Investments, Stranded Intellectuals.” Regulation. 47: 51Google Scholar
Michelman, Frank. 1968. “Property, Utility, and Fairness: Comments on the Ethical Foundations of ‘Just Compensation’ Law.” Harvard Law Review. 80: 1165CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Michelman, Frank. 1988. “Takings 1987.” Columbia Law Review. 88: 1600CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Mishkin, Paul J. 1957. “The Variousness of ‘Federal Law’: Competence and Discretion in the Choice of National and State Rules for Decision.” University of Pennsylvania Law Review. 105: 797CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Mitnick, Barry M. 1980. The Political Economy of Regulation: Creating, Designing, and Removing Regulatory Forms. New York: Columbia University PressGoogle Scholar
Movsesian, Mark. 1998. “Are Statutes Really ‘Legislative Bargains?’ The Failure of the Contract Analogy in Statutory Interpretation.” North Carolina Law Review. 76: 1145Google Scholar
Mueller, Milton J. Jr. 1997. Universal Service: Competition, Interconnection, and Monopoly in the Making of the American Telephone SystemWashington, D.C.: American Enterprise InstituteGoogle Scholar
Nagle, John Copeland. 1995. “Waiving Sovereign Immunity inan Age of Clear Statement Rules.” Wisconsin Law Review. 1995: 771Google Scholar
Nelson, Caleb. 2000. “Preemption.” Virginia Law Review. 86: 225CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Noam, Eli. 1997. “Will Universal Service and Common Carriage Survive the Telecommunications Act of 1996?Columbia Law Review. 97: 955CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Noll, Roger. 1971. Reforming Regulation: Studies in the Regulation of Economic Activity. Washington, D.C.: BrookingsGoogle Scholar
Norlander, Gerald A. 1998. “Retail Choice: A Race tothe Bottom.” Public Utilities Fortnightly. Jan.1: 8 (letter to the editor)
North, Douglass C. 1996. “Epilogue: Economic Performance Through Time.” in Alston, Lee J., Eggertsson, Thráinn & Douglas, C. North, eds. Empirical Studies in Institutional Change. Cambridge: Cambridge University PressCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Norton, Floyd & Spivak, Mark. 1985. “The Wholesale Service Obligation of Electric Utilities.” Energy Law Journal. 6: 179Google Scholar
Note. 1923. “The Sherman Act as Applied to Railroads Regulated Under the Interstate Commerce Act.” Harvard Law Review. 36: 456CrossRef
Note. 1953. “Recent Cases: Antitrust –Primary Jurisdiction Applied in Action Against Members of Regulated Industries.” University of Pennsylvania Law Review. 101: 678
Pace, Joe D. 1987. “Wheeling and the Obligation to Serve.” Energy Law Journal. 8: 265Google Scholar
Page, William H. 1981. “Antitrust, Federalism and the Regulatory Process.” Boston University Law Review. 61: 1099Google Scholar
Page, William H. 1987. “Interest Groups, Antitrust, and State Regulation: Parker v. Brown in the Economic Theory of Legislation.” Duke Law Journal. 1987: 618CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Page, William H. & John, E. Lopatka. 1993. “State Regulation in the Shadow of Antitrust: FTC v. Ticor Title Insurance Co.” Supreme Court Economic Review. 3: 189CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Pechman, Carl. 1993. Regulating Power: The Economics of Electricity in the Information Age. Dordrecht: Kluwer Academic PressCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Peltzman, Sam. 1976. “Toward a More General Theory of Regulation.” Journal of Law and Economics. 19: 211CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Peltzman, Sam. 1989. “The Economic Theory of Regulationafter a Decade of Deregulation.” Brookings Papers on Economic Activity: Microeconomics. 1989: 1CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Percival, Robert V. 1995. “Environmental Federalism:Historical Roots and Contemporary Models.” Maryland Law Review. 54: 1141Google Scholar
Persson, Torsten, Roland, Gerard & Tabellini, Guido. 1997. “Separation of Powers and Political Accountability.” Quarterly Journal of Economics. 112: 1163CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Peterson, Andrea. 1989. “The Takings Clause: InSearch of Underlying Principles. Part I – A Critique of Current Takings Clause Doctrine.” California Law Review. 77: 1299CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Peterson, H. Craig. 1975. “An Empirical Test of Regulatory Effects.” Bell Journal of Economics and Management Science. 6: 111CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Phillips, Charles F. 1993. The Regulation of Public Utilities. Fairfax, Virginia: Public Utility ReportsGoogle Scholar
Picker, Randal C. 2002. “Understanding Statutory Bundles: Does the Sherman Act Come with the 1996 Telecommunications Act?”University of Chicago John M. Olin Program in Law & Economics, Working Paper No. 177, 2002. Available at http://www.law.uchicago.edu/Picker/Papers/Manhattan200.pdf
Pierce, Richard J. Jr. 1984. “Regulatory Treatment of Mistakes in Retrospect: Cancelled Plants and Excess Capacity.” University of Pennsylvania Law Review. 132: 497CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Pierce, Richard J. Jr. 1988. “Reconstituting the Natural Gas Industry from Wellhead to Burnertip.” Energy Law Journal. 9: 1Google Scholar
Pierce, Richard J. Jr. 1989. “Public Utility Regulatory Takings: Should the Judiciary Attempt to Police the Political Institutions?Georgetown Law Journal. 77: 2031Google Scholar
Pierce, Richard J. Jr. 1991. “The Unintended Effects of Judicial Review of Agency Rules: How Federal Courts Have Contributed to the Electricity Crisis of the 1990s.” Administrative Law Review. 43: 7Google Scholar
Pierce, Richard J. Jr. 1994. “The State of the Transition to Competitive Markets in Natural Gas and Electricity.” Energy Law Journal. 15: 323Google Scholar
Piraino, Thomas A. Jr. 1997. “A Proposed Antitrust Analysisof Telecommunications Joint Ventures.” Wisconsin Law Review. 1997: 639Google Scholar
Pitofsky, Robert. 1997. “Competition Policy in Communications Industries: New Antitrust Approaches.” Remarks presented at Glasser Legal Works Seminar on Competitive Policy in Communications Industries: New Antitrust Approach es, Federal Trade Commission, Washington, D.C., March 10. Available at http://www.ftc.gov/speeches/pitofsky/newcomm.htm
Platt, Harold. 1991. The Electric City: Energy and the Growth of the Chicago Area 880–1930Chicago: University of Chicago PressGoogle Scholar
Pleatt, George R. 1998. “Should Metering Stay at the Stand-Alone Disco?Public Utilities Fortnightly. Feb. 1Google Scholar
Poirier, Marc R. 2002. “The Virtue of Vagueness in Takings Doctrine.” Cardozo Law Review. 24: 93Google Scholar
Posner, Eric. 1995. “Contract Law in the Welfare State: A Defense of the Unconscionability Doctrine, Usury Laws, and Related Limits on the Freedom to Contract.” Journal of Legal Studies. 24: 283CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Posner, Eric. 2003. “Economic Analysis of Contract Law after Three Decades: Success or Failure?Yale Law Journal. 112: 829CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Posner, Richard A. 1974. “Theories of Economic Regulation.” Bell Journal of Economics and Management Science. 5: 335CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Posner, Richard A. 1979. “The Chicago School of Antitrust Analysis.” University of Pennsylvania Law Review. 127: 925CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Posner, Richard & Rosenfield, Andrew. 1977. “Impossibility and Related Doctrines in Contract Law: An Economic Analysis.” Journal of Legal Studies. 6: 83CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Priest, George. 1992. “The Origins of Utility Regulation and the ‘Theories of Regulation’ Debate.” Journal of Law &Economics. 36: 289CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Quirk, Paul J. 1981. Industry Influence in Federal Regulatory Agencies. Princeton, N.J.: Princeton University PressCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Robinson, Gustavus H. 1928. “The Public Utility Concept in American Law.” Harvard Law Review. 41: 277CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Rockefeller John, D. IV. 1991. “A Call for Action:The Pepper Commission's Blueprint for Health Care Reform.” Journal of the American Medical Association. 265: 2507Google Scholar
Rodden, Jonathan & Rose-Ackerman, Susan. 1997. “Does Federalism Preserve Markets?Virginia Law Review. 83: 1521CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Rose-Ackerman, Susan. 1980. “Risk Taking and Reelection: Does Federalism Promote Innovation?Journal of Legal Studies. 9: 593CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Rose-Ackerman, Susan. 1988. “Against AdHocery: A Comment on Michelman.” Columbia Law Review. 88: 1697CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Rose-Ackerman, Susan. 1992. “Regulatory Takings: Policy Analysis and Democratic Principles.” in Merucro, Nicholas, ed. Taking Property and Just Compensation: Law and Economic Perspectives of the Takings IssueDordrecht: Kluwer Academic PressCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Rose-Ackerman, Susan & Rossi, Jim. 2000. “Disentangling Deregulatory Takings.” Virginia Law Review. 86: 1435CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Rossi, Jim. 1994. “Redeeming Judicial Review: The Hard Look Doctrine and Federal Regulatory Efforts to Restructure the Electric Utility Industry.” Wisconsin Law Review. 1994: 763Google Scholar
Rossi, Jim. 1997. “Participation Run Amok: The Costsof Mass Participation for Deliberative Agency Decisionmaking.” Northwestern University Law Review. 92: 173Google Scholar
Rossi, Jim. 1998a. “The Common Law ‘Duty to Serve’ and Protection of Consumers in an Age of Competitive Retail Public Utility Restructuring.” Vanderbilt Law Review 51: 1233Google Scholar
Rossi, Jim. 1998b. “The Irony of Deregulatory Takings.” Texas Law Review. 77: 297Google Scholar
Rossi, Jim. 2002. “The Electric Power Deregulation Fiasco: Looking to Regulatory Federalism to Promote a Balance Between Markets and the Provision of Public Goods.” Michigan Law Review. 100: 1768CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Rossi, Jim. 2003. “Lowering the Filed Tariff Shield:Judicial Enforcement for a Deregulatory Era.” Vanderbilt Law Review. 56: 1591Google Scholar
Rossi, Jim. 2004. “Debilitating Doctrine: How the Filed Rate Policy Wreaks Havoc – And What Courts Can Do About It.” Public Utilities Fortnightly, November: 16Google Scholar
Rossi, Jim. Forthcoming 2005. “Dual Constitutions and Constitutional Duels.” William & Mary Law Review.
Rouse, Michael A. 1990. “A Re-Evaluation of the “Filed Rate” Doctrine in Light of Revised Regulatory Policy and Carriers'Practices: INF, Ltd. v. Spectro Alloys Corp.” Creighton Law Review. 23: 669Google Scholar
Rubin, Edward L. & Feeley, Malcolm. 1994. “Federalism: Some Notes on a National Neurosis.” UCLA Law Review. 41: 903Google Scholar
Rubin, Paul H., Curran, Christopher & Curran, John. 2001. “Litigation versus Legislation: Forum Shopping by Rent-Seekers.” Public Choice. 107: 295CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ruhl, J. B. & Salzman, James. 2003. “Regulatory Accretion in the Administrative State. Georgetown Law Journal. 91: 75Google Scholar
Santa, Donald F. Jr. 2000. “Who Needs What, and Why?Reporting and Disclosure Obligations in Emerging Competitive Electricity Markets.” Energy Law Journal. 21: 1Google Scholar
Savage, Leonard J. 1972. The Foundations of StatisticsNew York: Dover PublicationsGoogle Scholar
Schelling, Thomas. 1980. Strategy of Conflict, Second edition. Cambridge, Mass.: Harvard University PressGoogle Scholar
Schwartz, Jeffrey D. 1999. “The Use of Antitrust State Action Doctrine in the Deregulated Electric Utility Industry.” American University Law Review. 48: 1449Google Scholar
Schwartz, Joshua I. 1997. “Assembling Winstar: Triumpth of the Ideal of Congruence in Government Contracts Law?Public Contract Law Journal. 26: 481Google Scholar
Seidenfeld, Mark. 2004. “Pyrrhic Political Penalties: Why the Public Would Lose Under the ‘Penalty Default Canon.’George Washington Law Review. 72: 724Google Scholar
Shepsle, Kenneth A. 1992. “Congress is a ‘They,’ Not an ‘It’: Legislative Intent as an Oxymoron.” International Review of Law &Economics. 12: 239CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Sidak, J. Gregory & Spulber, Daniel. 1997. Deregulatory Takings and the Regulatory Contract: The Transformation of Network Industries in the United States. New York: Cambridge University PressCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Sillin, John O. 2003. “Why We Fell into the Heart of Darkness.” Public Utilities Fortnightly September 15: 30Google Scholar
Silverstein, Eileen. 1991. “Against Preemption in Labor Law.” Connecticut Law Review. 24: 1Google Scholar
Simon, Herbert. 1961. Administrative Behavior, Second edition. New York: MacmillanGoogle Scholar
Simons, Kenneth W. 2002. “Reflections on Assumption of the Risk.” UCLA Law Review. 50: 481Google Scholar
Simpson, James B. & Sarah, D. Strum. 1991. “How a Good Samaritan? Federal Income Tax Exemption for Charitable Hospitals Reconsidered.” University of Puget Sound Law Review. 14: 633Google Scholar
Singer, Joseph. 1996. “No Right to Exclude: Public Accommodations and Private Property.” Northwestern University Law Review. 90: 1283Google Scholar
Smith, Vernon. 1993. “Can Electric Power – A ‘Natural Monopoly’ – Be Deregulated?” in Landsberg, Hans H., ed. Making National Energy PolicyWashington, D.C.: Resources for the FutureGoogle Scholar
Sosnov, Leonard N. 2000. “Separation of Powers Shell Game: The Federal Witness Immunity Act.” Temple Law Review. 73: 171Google Scholar
Spann, Robert M. 1974. “Rate of Return Regulation and Efficiency in Production: An Empirical Test of the Averch-Johnson Thesis.” Bell Journal of Economic and Management Science. 5: 38CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Speidel, Richard. 1981. “Court-Imposed Price Adjustments Under Long-Term Supply Contracts.” Northwestern University Law Review. 76: 369, 381–94Google Scholar
Spence, David B. & Murray, Paula. 1999. “The Law, Economics, and Politics of Federal Preemption Analysis: A Quantitative Analysis.” California Law Review. 87: 1125CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Spitzer, Matthew. 1988. “Antitrust, Federalism, and the Rational Choice Political Economy: A Critique of Capture Theory.” Southern California Law Review. 61: 1293Google Scholar
Spulber, Daniel F. & Christopher, S. Yoo. 2003. Access to Networks: Constitutional and Economic Connections. Cornell Law Review. 88: 885Google Scholar
Stearns, Maxell L. 2003. “A Beautiful Mend: A Game Theoretical Analysis of the Dormant Commerce Clause Doctrine.” William & Mary Law Review. 45: 1Google Scholar
Stewart, Richard B. 1990. “Madison'sNightmare.” University of Chicago Law Review. 57: 335CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Stigler, George. 1971. “The Theory of Economic Regulation.” Bell Journal of Economic and Management Science. 2: 3CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Stigler, George & Friedland, Claire. 1962. “What Can Regulators Regulate? The Case of Electricity.” Journal of Law &Economics. 5: 1CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Sugden, Robert. 1995. “A Theory of Focal Points.” Economic Journal. 105: 533CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Sullivan, Lawrence A. 1992. “Section 2 of the Sherman Act and Vertical Strategies by Dominant Firms.” Southwestern University Law Review. 21: 1227Google Scholar
Sunstein, Cass. 1989. “Interpreting Statutes in the Regulatory State.” Harvard Law Review. 103: 405CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Sunstein, Cass. 1995. “Incompletely The orized Agreements.” Harvard Law Review. 108: 1733CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Symposium, . 2003. “Is There an Ideal Way to Deal with the Non-Ideal World of Legal Change?Journal of Contemporary Legal Issues. 13: 1Google Scholar
Talley, Eric. 2001. “Disclosure Norms.” University of Pennsylvania Law Review. 149: 1955CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Tirole, Jean. 2002. The Theory of Industrial Organization. Cambridge, Mass.: MIT PressGoogle Scholar
Tomain, Joseph P. & Shapiro, Sidney. 1997. “Analyzing Government Regulation.” Administrative Law Review. 39: 377Google Scholar
U.S. Energy Information Administration. 1997. Electricity Prices in a Competitive Environment: Marginal Cost Pricing of Generation Services and Financial Status of Electric Utilities – A Preliminary Analysis Through 2015. Washington, D.C.: U.S. Department of Energy
Alstine, Michael P. 2002. “The Costs of Legal Change.” UCLA Law Review. 49: 789Google Scholar
Doren, Peter & Taylor, Jerry. 2004. “Rethinking Restructuring.” Public Utilities Fortnightly. February: 12Google Scholar
Mehren, Robert B. 1954. “The Antitrust Laws and Regulated Industries: The Doctrine of Primary Jurisdiction.” Harvard Law Review. 67: 929CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Watts, Duncan J. 2003. Six Degreesof Separation: The Science of a Connected Age. New York: W.W. Norton& CoGoogle Scholar
Weaver, Jacqueline. 2004. “Can Energy Markets BeTrusted?Houston Business and Tax Law Journal. 4: 1Google Scholar
Weiser, Philip J. 1999. “Chevron, Cooperative Federalism, and Tele communications Reform.” Vanderbilt Law Review. 52: 1Google Scholar
Weiser, Philip J. 2001a. “Federal Common Law, Cooperative Federalism, and the Enforcement of the Telcom Act.” New York University Law Review. 76: 1692Google Scholar
Weiser, Philip J. 2001b. “Towards a Constitutional Architecture for Cooperative Federalism.” North Carolina Law Review. 79: 663Google Scholar
Weiser, Philip J. 2003. “Goldwasser, The Telecom Act, and Reflections on Antitrust Remedies.” Administrative Law Review. 55: 1Google Scholar
White, Matthew W. 1996. “Power Struggles: Explaining Deregulatory Reforms in Electricity Markets.” Brookings Papers: Microeconomics. 1996: 201CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Wiley, John Shepard Jr. 1986. “A Capture Theory of Antitrust Federalism.” Harvard Law Review. 99: 713CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Williamson, Oliver. 1975. Marketsand Hierarchies: Analysis and Antitrust ImplicationsNew York: Free PressGoogle Scholar
Williamson, Oliver. 1976. “Franchise Bidding for Natural Monopolies – In General and with Respect to CATV.”Bell Journal of Economics. 7: 73CrossRef
Williamson, Oliver. 1979. “Transaction Cost Economics: The Governance of Contractual Relations.” Journal of Law & Economics. 22: 233CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Williamson, Oliver. 1996a. The Mechanisms of GovernanceNew York: Oxford University PressGoogle Scholar
Williamson, Oliver. 1996b. “Response: Deregulatory Takings and the Breach of the Regulatory Contract: Some Precautions.” New York University Law Review. 71: 1007Google Scholar
Wright, Ronald. 1996. “When Do We Want Incomplete Agreements: A Comment on Sunstein's Holmes Devise Lecture.” Wake Forest Law Review. 31: 459Google Scholar
Wyman, Bruce. 1903. “The Law of the Public Callings as aSolution of the Trust Problem.” Harvard Law Review. 17: 156, 161CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Young, Ernest A. 1999. “Preemption at Sea.” George Washington Law Review. 67: 273Google Scholar
Yoo, John C. 1998. “Sounds of Sovereignty: Defining Federalism in the 1990s.” Indiana Law Review. 32: 27Google Scholar
Zajac, Edward E. 1995. The Political Economy of Fairness. Cambridge, Massachusetts: MIT Press.Google Scholar

Save book to Kindle

To save this book to your Kindle, first ensure coreplatform@cambridge.org is added to your Approved Personal Document E-mail List under your Personal Document Settings on the Manage Your Content and Devices page of your Amazon account. Then enter the ‘name’ part of your Kindle email address below. Find out more about saving to your Kindle.

Note you can select to save to either the @free.kindle.com or @kindle.com variations. ‘@free.kindle.com’ emails are free but can only be saved to your device when it is connected to wi-fi. ‘@kindle.com’ emails can be delivered even when you are not connected to wi-fi, but note that service fees apply.

Find out more about the Kindle Personal Document Service.

  • References
  • Jim Rossi, Florida State University
  • Book: Regulatory Bargaining and Public Law
  • Online publication: 11 July 2009
  • Chapter DOI: https://doi.org/10.1017/CBO9780511511080.011
Available formats
×

Save book to Dropbox

To save content items to your account, please confirm that you agree to abide by our usage policies. If this is the first time you use this feature, you will be asked to authorise Cambridge Core to connect with your account. Find out more about saving content to Dropbox.

  • References
  • Jim Rossi, Florida State University
  • Book: Regulatory Bargaining and Public Law
  • Online publication: 11 July 2009
  • Chapter DOI: https://doi.org/10.1017/CBO9780511511080.011
Available formats
×

Save book to Google Drive

To save content items to your account, please confirm that you agree to abide by our usage policies. If this is the first time you use this feature, you will be asked to authorise Cambridge Core to connect with your account. Find out more about saving content to Google Drive.

  • References
  • Jim Rossi, Florida State University
  • Book: Regulatory Bargaining and Public Law
  • Online publication: 11 July 2009
  • Chapter DOI: https://doi.org/10.1017/CBO9780511511080.011
Available formats
×