Skip to main content Accessibility help
×
Hostname: page-component-848d4c4894-4hhp2 Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-06-06T06:27:48.940Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

11 - The Institutional Curse of Natural Resources in the Arab World1

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  05 July 2016

Ibrahim Elbadawi
Affiliation:
Dubai Economic Council and Economic Research Forum (ERF), Egypt
Hoda Selim
Affiliation:
Economic Research Forum (ERF), Egypt
Get access

Summary

Abstract

This paper argues that the resource curse in the Arab world is primarily an “institutional curse,” even though it has several macroeconomic manifestations. An empirical investigation, using an augmented growth model, confirms the conditional resource curse hypothesis. The results suggest that on their own, political institutions do not always have an effect on growth but, when interacted with natural resources, they reduce the negative effect of natural resources on growth but do not offset it. The analysis also shows that the curse has operated in different ways within the Arab World. In the GCC, large rents per capita have been channeled to national citizens in the form of well-remunerated public sector jobs and other generous social welfare schemes which have served to increase government legitimacy and foster regime stability. In contrast, the populous group comprising poorer rentier states have experienced conflict, violence and social unrest. Moreover, in a context of low rent per capita, excessive consumption resulted in massive deficiencies in infrastructure investments and an underdeveloped financial sector. Finally, the volatility of their limited resources has been accompanied by more dire economic consequences: excessive borrowing and Dutch Disease.

Type
Chapter
Information
Publisher: Cambridge University Press
Print publication year: 2016

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

References

Abdelal, R., Khan, A. and Khanna, T.. (2008). Where Oil-Rich Nations are Placing their Bets. Harvard Business Review 86(9): 119128.Google Scholar
Abdih, Y., Lopez-Murphy, P. and Sahay, R.. (2010). The Cyclicality of Fiscal Policy in the Middle East and Central Asia: Is the Current Crisis Different? IMF Working Paper 10/68. Washington DC.Google Scholar
Ali, O. and Elbadawi, I.. This volume. The Political Economy of Public Sector Employment in Resource Dependent Countries.Google Scholar
Al-Abri, A. This volume. Labor Market Heterogeneity and Optimal Exchange Rate Regimes in Resource-rich Arab Countries.Google Scholar
Al-Sheik, H. and Erbas, S.N.. This volume. The Oil Curse and Labor Markets: The Case of Saudi Arabia.Google Scholar
Andersen, L. (1987). The State in the Middle East and North Africa. Comparative Politics 20(1):118.Google Scholar
Arezki, R. and Brückner, M.. (2011). Oil Rents, Corruption, and State Stability: Evidence from Panel Data Regressions. European Economic Review 55(7): 955963.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Auty, R. M. (1993). Sustaining Development in Mineral Economies: The Resource Curse Thesis. London: Routledge.Google Scholar
Baseday, M. and Lay, J.. (2009). Resource Curse or Rentier Peace? The Ambiguous Effects of Oil Wealth and Oil Dependence on Violent Conflict. Journal of Peace Research 46(6): 757776.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Beblawi, H. G. L., eds. (1987). The Rentier State: Nation, State and the Integration of the Arab World. London: Croom Helm.Google Scholar
Beck, T. (2011). Finance and Oil: Is There a Resource Curse in Financial Development?” In Beyond the Curse: Policies to Harness the Power of Natural Resources. Arezki, R., Gylfason, T. and Sy, A., eds., Washington, DC: International Monetary Fund.Google Scholar
Bellin, E. (2004). The Robustness of Authoritarianism in the Middle East: Exceptionalism in Comparative Perspective. Comparative Politics 36(2): 139159.Google Scholar
Collier, P. This volume. Savings and Investment Decisions from Natural Resource Revenues: Implications for Arab Development.Google Scholar
Collier, P. (2010). The Political Economy of Natural Resources. Social Research 77(4): 11051132.Google Scholar
Collier, P., van der Ploeg, F., Spence, M. and Venables, A.. (2010). Managing Resource Revenues in Developing Economies.IMF Staff Papers 57(1): 84118.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Collier, P. and Hoeffler, A.. (2009). Testing the Neocon Agenda: Democracy in Resource-rich Societies. European Economic Review 53(3): 293308.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Collier, P. and Hoeffler, A.. (2004). Greed and Grievance in Civil War. Oxford Economic Papers 56(4): 563595.Google Scholar
Collier, P. and Goderis, B.. (2007). Commodity Prices, Growth, and the Natural Resource Curse: Reconciling a Conundrum. Economics Series Working Papers WPS/2007-15, University of Oxford, Department of Economics.Google Scholar
Corden, W. (1984). Booming Sector and Dutch Disease Economics: Survey and Consolidation. Oxford Economic Papers 36: 359380.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Daniel, P. S. G., Mattina, T., and Segura-Ubiergo, A.. (2013). Extracting Resource Revenue: Finance and Development. Washington, D.C.: IMF.Google Scholar
De Gregorio, J. and Guidotti, P.. (1995). Financial Development and Economic Growth. World Development 23(3, March): 433448.Google Scholar
Diop, N. and de Melo, J.. This volume. Dutch Disease in the Services Sector: Evidence from Oil Exporters in the Arab region.Google Scholar
Diop, N., Marotta, D. and de Melo, J.. (2012). Natural Resource Abundance, Growth, and Diversification in the Middle East and North Africa: The Effects of Natural Resources and the Role of Policies. Washington, D.C. World Bank.Google Scholar
Elbadawi, I. and Selim, H.. This volume. Overview of Context, Issues and Summary.Google Scholar
Elbadawi, I. and Soto, R.. This volume. Resource Rents, Political Institutions and Economic Growth.Google Scholar
Elbadawi, I., Makdisi, S. and Milante, G.. (2011). Explaining the Arab Democracy Deficit: the Role of Oil and Conflicts. In Democracy in the Arab World: Explaining the Deficit. Elbadawi, I. and Makdisi, S., eds., New York and Canada: Routledge and International Development Centre.Google Scholar
Freedom House. (2013). Freedom in the World data. Available at: www.freedomhouse.org/report-types/freedom-world. Accessed August 2014.Google Scholar
Galal, A. and Selim, H.. (2013). The Elusive Quest for Economic Development in the Arab Countries. Middle East Development Journal 5(1): 129.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Gelb, A., Tordo, S., and Hallan, H.. (2014). Sovereign Wealth Funds and Domestic Investment in Resource-rich Countries: Love Me, or Love Me Not? World Bank Economic Premise Note Series 133. World Bank: Washington, D.C.Google Scholar
Gylfason, T. (2004). Natural Resources, Education, and Economic Development. European Economic Review 45(4–6): 847859.Google Scholar
Gylfason, T. and Zoega, G.. (2006). Natural Resources and Economic Growth: The Role of Investment. The World Economy 29(8): 10911115.Google Scholar
Haber, S. and Menaldo, V.. (2011). Do Natural Resources Fuel Authoritarianism? A Reappraisal of the Resource Curse. American Political Science Review 105(1): 126.Google Scholar
Haouas, I. and Soto, R.. This volume. Has the UAE Escaped the Oil Curse?Google Scholar
Hausmann, R. and Rigobon, R.. (2003). An Alternative Interpretation of the ‘Resource Curse’: Theory and Policy Implications. NBER Working Paper 9424, Cambridge, Mass.Google Scholar
Herb, M. (2005). No Representation without Taxation? Rents, Development, and Democracy. Comparative Politics 37(3): 297316.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hertog, S. (2012). Redesigning the Distributional Bargain in the GCC. Paper presented at the BRISMES Annual Conference 2012 on “Revolution and Revolt: Understanding the Forms and Causes of Change”. London. 26–28 March.Google Scholar
Hodson, N. (2011). Distributional Structures in the Arab Gulf: Public Employment, Subsidies, and Potential Reform. Sciences Po Kuwait program publication.Google Scholar
Inglehart, R. (1997). Modernization and Post-modernization: Cultural, Economic, and Political Change in 43 Societies. Princeton: Princeton University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
International Monetary Fund. (2013a). Saudi Arabia: Selected Issues. IMF Country Report 13/230. Washington, D.C.Google Scholar
International Monetary Fund. (2013b). Sudan: 2013 Article IV Consultation. IMF Country Report 13/317. Washington, D.C.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
International Monetary Fund. (2013c) . Economic Prospects and Policy Challenges for the GCC Countries. Document prepared by the staff of the IMF for the Annual Meeting of Ministers of Finance and Central Bank Governors. Riyadh. October 5.Google Scholar
International Monetary Fund. (2013d). Labor Market Reforms to Boost Employment and Productivity in the GCC. Document prepared by the staff of the IMF for the Annual Meeting of Ministers of Finance and Central Bank Governors. Riyadh. October 5.Google Scholar
Jensen, N. and Wantchekon, L.. (2004). Resource Wealth and Political Regimes in Africa. Comparative Political Studies 37(7): 816841.Google Scholar
Kenny, C. and Karver, J.. (2012). Publish What You Buy: The Case for Routine Publication of Government Contracts. CGD Policy Paper 011. Washington DC: Center for Global DevelopmentGoogle Scholar
Kohler, P. (2013). GCC Sovereign Wealth Funds: Leveraging Local Economic Development? United Nations Development Policy and Analysis Division, Department of Economic and Social Affairs, World Economic Situation and Prospects Policy Briefing. May.Google Scholar
Leite, C. and Weidmann, J. J. (1999). Does Mother Nature Corrupt? Natural Resources, Corruption and Economic Growth. IMF Working Paper 99/85. Washington. D.C.Google Scholar
Loayza, N. and Ranciere, R.. (2005). Financial Development, Financial Fragility, and Growth. IMF Working paper 05/170. Washington. D.C.Google Scholar
Mankiw, G., Romer, D. and Weil, D.. (1992). A Contribution to the Empirics of Economic Growth. Quarterly Journal of Economics 107(2): 407437.Google Scholar
Manzano, O. and Rigobon, R.. (2001). Resource Curse or Debt Overhang?NBER Working Papers 8390. Cambridge, Mass.Google Scholar
Melhum, H., Moene, K. and Torvik, R.. (2006). Institutions and the Resource Curse. Economic Journal, 116(January): 120.Google Scholar
Van der Ploeg, F. and Poelhekke, S.. (2009). Volatility and the Natural Resource Curse. Oxford Economic Papers 61(4): 727760.Google Scholar
Robinson, J., Torvik, R. and Verdier, T.. (2006). Political Foundations of the Resource Curse. Journal of Development Economics 79(2): 447468.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Robinson, J. And Torvik, R.. (2005). White Elephants. Journal of Public Economics 89(2–3): 197210.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Rodrik, D. (2009). Industrial Policy: Don’t Ask Why, Ask How. Middle East Development Journal 1(1): 129.Google Scholar
Rodrik, D. 2008. The Real Exchange Rate and Economic Growth. Brookings Papers on Economic Activity 39(2): 365439.Google Scholar
Ross, M., Kaiser, K. and Mazaheri, N.. (2011). The “Resource Curse” in MENA? Political Transitions, Resource Wealth, Economic Shocks, and Conflict Risk. World Bank Policy Research Working Paper 5742. Washington, D.C.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ross, M., Kaiser, K. and Mazaheri, N.. (2004). Does Taxation Lead to Representation? British Journal of Political Science 32(4): 229249.Google Scholar
Ross, M., Kaiser, K. and Mazaheri, N.. (2001). Does Oil Hinder Democracy? World Politics 53(3), 325361.Google Scholar
Sachs, J. and Warner, A.. (1995). Natural Resource Abundance and Economic Growth. NBER Working Paper 5398. Cambridge, Mass.Google Scholar
Salti, N. (2008). Oil Greasing the Wheels: When Do Natural Resources Become a Blessing? ERF Working Paper 439. Cairo.Google Scholar
Schmidt-Hebbel, K. This volume. Fiscal Institutions in Resource-rich Economies: Lessons from Chile and Norway.Google Scholar
Smith, B. (2004). Oil Wealth and Regime Survival in the Developing World, 1960–1999. American Journal of Political Science 48(2): 232246.Google Scholar
Solow, R. (1956). A Contribution to the Theory of Economic Growth. The Quarterly Journal of Economics 70(1): 6594.Google Scholar
Suliman, K. This volume. Understanding and Avoiding the Oil Curse in Sudan.Google Scholar
Tilly, C. ed. (1975). The Formation of National States in Western Europe. Princeton: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Tornell, A. and Lane, P. R.. (1999). The Voracity Effect. American Economic Review 89(1): 2246.Google Scholar
Villafuerte, M. and Lopez-Murphy, P.. (2010). Fiscal Policy in Oil Producing Countries During the Recent Oil Price Cycle. IMF Working Paper 10/18. Washington, D.C.Google Scholar

Save book to Kindle

To save this book to your Kindle, first ensure coreplatform@cambridge.org is added to your Approved Personal Document E-mail List under your Personal Document Settings on the Manage Your Content and Devices page of your Amazon account. Then enter the ‘name’ part of your Kindle email address below. Find out more about saving to your Kindle.

Note you can select to save to either the @free.kindle.com or @kindle.com variations. ‘@free.kindle.com’ emails are free but can only be saved to your device when it is connected to wi-fi. ‘@kindle.com’ emails can be delivered even when you are not connected to wi-fi, but note that service fees apply.

Find out more about the Kindle Personal Document Service.

Available formats
×

Save book to Dropbox

To save content items to your account, please confirm that you agree to abide by our usage policies. If this is the first time you use this feature, you will be asked to authorise Cambridge Core to connect with your account. Find out more about saving content to Dropbox.

Available formats
×

Save book to Google Drive

To save content items to your account, please confirm that you agree to abide by our usage policies. If this is the first time you use this feature, you will be asked to authorise Cambridge Core to connect with your account. Find out more about saving content to Google Drive.

Available formats
×