Skip to main content Accessibility help
×
Hostname: page-component-84b7d79bbc-g7rbq Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-07-26T18:57:10.797Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

References

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  02 September 2009

Donald A. Walker
Affiliation:
Indiana University of Pennsylvania
Get access
Type
Chapter
Information
Walrasian Economics , pp. 317 - 333
Publisher: Cambridge University Press
Print publication year: 2006

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

References

Allais, Maurice (1968), “Vilfredo Pareto, Contributions to Economics,” in International Encyclopedia of the Social Sciences, New York: Macmillan Co. and the Free Press, 2, 399–411Google Scholar
Amoroso, Luigi (1909), “La teoria dell'equilibrio economico secondo il Prof. Vilfredo Pareto,” Giornale degli Economisti, series 2, 39, October, 353–67Google Scholar
Amoroso, Luigi (1921), Lezioni di economia mathematica, Bologna: N. ZanichelliGoogle Scholar
Antonelli, Etienne (1914), Principes d'économie pure, Paris: Librairie des sciences politiques et socialesGoogle Scholar
Antonelli, Etienne (1939), L'Economie pure du capitalisme, Paris: Guillaumin et CieGoogle Scholar
Antonucci, Antonio (ed.) (1938), Alcune lettere di Vilfredo Pareto pubblicate e commentate da A. Antonucci, Rome: Prof. P. Maglione-Editore; Socc. di Loescher & C.; reprinted in Busino 1973 without Antonucci's commentsGoogle Scholar
Arena, Richard and Ragni, Ludovic (1994), “Libre concurrence et méthodologie walrasienne: une tentative de mise en relation,” Economies et Sociétés, Série Œconomia, Histoire de la Pensée économique, P. E. no. 20–21, 10–11, 161–82Google Scholar
Arrow, Kenneth (1959), “Towards a Theory of Price Adjustment,” in Abramovitz, Moses. (eds.), The Allocation of Economic Resources: Essays in Honor of Bernard Francis Haley, Stanford: Stanford University Press, 41–51Google Scholar
Arrow, Kenneth (1968), “Economic Equilibrium,” in Sills, David L. (ed.), International Encyclopedia of the Social Sciences, 4, no place: Macmillan Company and the Free Press, 376–86Google Scholar
Arrow, Kenneth J. and Debreu, Gérard (1954), “Existence of an Equilibrium for a Competitive Economy,” Econometrica, 22, July, 265–90CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Arrow, Kenneth J. and Debreu, Gérard (eds.) (2001), Landmark Papers in General Equilibrium Theory, Social Choice and Welfare, in Foundations of Twentieth Century Economics, 3, Cheltenham, U.K. and Northampton, MA. : Elgar Publishing LimitedGoogle Scholar
Arrow, Kenneth J. and Hahn, F. H. (1971), General Competitive Analysis, San Francisco: Holden-Day; Edinburgh: Oliver and BoydGoogle Scholar
Arrow, Kenneth J. and Hurwicz, Leonid (1958), “On the Stability of Competitive Equilibrium I,” Econometrica, 26, 522–52CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Aupetit, Albert (1901), Essai sur la théorie générale de la monnaie, Paris: Guillaumin et CieGoogle Scholar
Aupetit, Albert (1914), Principes d'économie pure, Paris: Guillaumin et CieGoogle Scholar
Barone, Enrico (1895), “Sopra un recente libro del Wicksteed,” unpublished lost mss.; translated into French by Léon Walras as “Sur un livre récent de Wicksteed,” in 239, 1895, 2, 644–48; translated into English by Donald A. Walker, in Jaffé 1983, 182–86
Barone, Enrico (1896), “Studi sulla distribuzione,” Giornale degli Economisti, series 2, 12, February, 107–152Google Scholar
Barone, Enrico (1908), “Il Ministro della produzione nello stato collettivista,” Giornale degli Economisti, series 2, 37, September, 267–93; October, 391–414Google Scholar
Baumol, William J. and Goldfeld, Stephen M. (eds.) (1968), Precursors in Mathematical Economics, LSE Series of reprints of scarce works on political economy, no. 19, London: London School of EconomicsGoogle Scholar
Belloc, Bernard and Michel Moreaux (1987), “Allais, Maurice,” in Eatwell et al. 1987, 1, 78–80
Bidard, Christian and Franke, Reiner (1987), “On Walras' Model of General Equilibrium: A Simpler Way to Demonstrate Existence,” Zeitschrift für Nationalökonomie, 47 (3), 315–19CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bini, Piero and Bruni, Luigino (1998), “Intervista a Gérard Debreu,” Storia del pensiero economico, 35, 3–29Google Scholar
Blaug, Mark (ed.) (1992a), Leon Walras (1834–1910), an Elgar Reference Collection, in Pioneers in Economics, 25, Aldershot, UK and Brookfield, VT: Edward Elgar PublishingGoogle Scholar
Blaug, Mark (1992b), The Methodology of Economics or How Economists Explain, 2nd ed., Cambridge: Cambridge University PressCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Blaug, Mark (1997), “Competition as an End-State and Competition as a Process,” in Eaton, B. Curtis and Harris, Richard G. (eds.), Trade, Technology and Economics: Essays in Honour of Richard G. Lipsey, Cheltenham, UK and Brookfield, VT: Edward Elgar Publishing, 241–62; and in Not Only an Economist, Recent Essays, Cheltenham, UK: Edward Elgar Publishing, 66–86; and in Walker 2000a, 1, 272–93Google Scholar
Bliss, Christopher (1987), “Hicks, John Richard (born 1904),” in Eatwell et al., 2, 641–46
Bompaire, François (1931), Du principe de liberté économique dans l'œuvre de Cournot et dans celle de l'école de Lausanne (Walras, Pareto), Paris: Recueil SireyGoogle Scholar
Bousquet, Georges-Henri (1927), Essai sur l'évolution de la pensée économique, Paris: M. GiardGoogle Scholar
Bousquet, Georges-Henri (1928a), Cours d'économie pure, Paris: Librairie des sciences politiques et socialesGoogle Scholar
Bousquet, Georges-Henri (1928b), Vilfredo Pareto. Sa vie et son œuvre, Paris: PayotGoogle Scholar
Bousquet, Georges-Henri (1960), Pareto (1848–1923). Le savant et l'homme, Lausanne: PayotGoogle Scholar
Bousquet, Georges-Henri (1964), “Introduction” to Pareto 1896/1897, new edition, Geneva: Librarie Droz, IX–XVIIGoogle Scholar
Bousquet, Georges-Henri (1971), “Quelques remarques sur Pareto et certains défauts de son œuvre,” Revue Européenne des Sciences Sociales et Cahiers Vilfredo Pareto, 9 (25), 11–27Google Scholar
Bouvier, Emile (1901), “L'économie politique mathématique, quelques mots à propos du traité de M. Léon Walras,” Revue Critique de Législation et de Jurisprudence, 30 (12), December, 623–29Google Scholar
Boven, Pierre (1923), “Vilfredo Pareto II. L'œuvre et les théories,” Journal de Genève, 94th year, no. 229, August 22, 1–2Google Scholar
Bowley, Arthur L. (1924), The Mathematical Groundwork of Economics: An Introductory Treatise, Oxford: The Clarendon PressGoogle Scholar
Brems, Hans (1986), Pioneering Economic Theory, 1630–1980. A Mathematical Restatement, Baltimore and London: The Johns Hopkins University PressGoogle Scholar
Brems, Hans (1987), “Zeuthen, Frederik Ludvig Bang (1888–1959),” in Eatwell et al. 1987, 4, pp. 944–45CrossRef
Bridel, Pascal (1990), “Equilibre, statique comparée et analyse dynamique chez Vilfredo Pareto: remarques sur la contribution de Siro Lombardini,” Revue européenne des sciences sociales, 27 (88), 183–191Google Scholar
Bridel, Pascal (1997), Money and General Equilibrium Theory; From Walras to Pareto (1870–1923), Cheltenham, UK and Lyme, CT: Edward Elgar Publishing LimitedGoogle Scholar
Bridel, Pascal (1998), Review of “Walras's market models. By Donald A. Walker. Cambridge; New York and Melbourne: Cambridge University Press, 1996,” Journal of Economic Literature, 36 (1), 231–33Google Scholar
Bridel, Pascal and Huck, Elisabeth (2002), “Yet another look at Walras's theory of tâtonnement,” European Journal of the History of Economic Thought, 9, Winter, 513–40CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bruni, Luigino (2002), Vilfredo Pareto and the birth of modern microeconomics, Cheltenham, U.K. and Northampton, MA: Elgar Publishing LimitedCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Buckle, Henry Thomas (1872), The miscellaneous and posthumous works of Henry Thomas Buckle, edited by Taylor, Helen, London: Longmans, Green and CoGoogle Scholar
Burgenmeier, B. (1994), “The Misperception of Walras,” American Economic Review, 84 (1), March, 342–52Google Scholar
Busetto, Francesca (1995), “Why the Non-Tâtonnement Line of Reasearch Died Out,” Economic Notes, 24 (1), 89–113Google Scholar
Busino, Giovanni (ed.) (1973), Vilfredo Pareto: Epistolario, 1890–1923, 2 vols., Rome: Accademia Nazionale dei LinceiGoogle Scholar
Busino, Giovanni (1987), “Pareto, Vilfredo,” in Eatwell et. al. 1987, 3, 799–804
Cassel, Karl Gustav (1899), “Grundriss einer elementaren Preislehre,” Zeitschrift für die gesamte Staatswissenschaf, 55 (3), 395–458Google Scholar
Cassel, Karl Gustav (1900), “Grundsätze für die Bildung der Personentarife auf den Eisenbahnen,” Archiv für Eisenbahnwesen, 23, 116–46; translated as “The Principles of Railway Rates for Passengers,” International Economic Papers, 6, 1956Google Scholar
Cassel, Karl Gustav (1903), The Nature and Necessity of Interest, London and New York: MacmillanGoogle Scholar
Cassel, Karl Gustav (1918), Theoretische Sozialökonomie, Leipzig: C. F. Winter; 4th ed., revised, Leipzig: A. Deichertsche Verlasbuchhandlung Dr. Werner Scholl, 1927Google Scholar
Cassel, Karl Gustav (1921), The World's Monetary Problems, Two memoranda presented to the International Financial Conference of the League of Nations in Brussels in 1920 and to the Financial Committee of the League of Nations in September 1921, London: ConstableGoogle Scholar
Cassel, Karl Gustav (1923), The Theory of Social Economy, translated by Joseph McCabe from the enlarged German 2nd ed., London: T. F. UnwinGoogle Scholar
Cassel, Karl Gustav (1928), “The Rate of Interest, the Bank Rate, and the Stabilization of Prices,” Quarterly Journal of Economics, 42 (August), 511–29CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Cassel, Karl Gustav (1932), The Theory of Social Economy, translated by Samuel L. Barron from the 5th German edition, London: E. Benn; reprint, New York: Augustus M. Kelley, 1967Google Scholar
Cassel, Karl Gustav (1935), On Quantitative Thinking in Economics, Oxford: Clarendon PressGoogle Scholar
Cassel, Karl Gustav (1937), “Keynes' General Theory,” International Labour Review, 36, 437–45Google Scholar
Clarke, Desmond M. (1991), “Descartes's Use of ‘Demonstration’ and ‘Deduction,’” in Moyal, Georges J. D., (ed.), (1991), René Descartes: Critical Assessments, 4 vols., London: RoutledgeGoogle Scholar
Clower, Robert W. (1965), “The Keynesian Counter-Revolution: A Theoretical Appraisal,” in Hahn, F. H. and Brechling, F. P. R., (eds.), The Theory of Interest Rates, London: Macmillan, 103–25Google Scholar
Collins Robert Unabridged French-English, English-French Dictionary (2002), 6th ed., Glasgow: HarperCollins Publishers
Cournot, Antoine-Auguste (1838), Recherches sur les principes mathématiques de la théorie des richesses, Paris: HachetteGoogle Scholar
Cournot, Antoine-Auguste (1863), Principes de la théorie des richesses, Paris: HachetteGoogle Scholar
Creedy, John (1999), “The Rise and Fall of Walras's Demand and Supply Curves,” Manchester School, 67 (2), March, 192–202CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Currie, Martin and Steedman, Ian (1990), Wrestling with Time: Problems in Economic Theory, Manchester: Manchester University PressGoogle Scholar
D'Agata, Antonio (2001), “Yet Another Proof of the Existence of a Competitive Equilibrium,” Revista de Analisis Economico, 16 (2), December, 155–58Google Scholar
Davis, John B., Hands, D. Wade, and Mäki, Uskali (1998), The Handbook of Economic Methodology, Cheltenham, UK and Northampton, MA: Edward Elgar Publishing LimitedCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Debreu, Gérard (1952), “A Social Equilibrium Existence Theorem,” Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences, 38, 886–93CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Debreu, Gérard (1959), Theory of Value; An Axiomatic Analysis of Economic Equilibrium, New York: John Wiley and SonsGoogle Scholar
Debreu, Gérard (ed.) (1996), General Equilibrium Theory, 2 vols., an Elgar Reference Collection, in The International Library of Critical Writings in Economics, general editor Mark Blaug, Cheltenham, UK and Brookfield, VT: Edward Elgar Publishing LimitedGoogle Scholar
Debs, Alexandre (2004), “‘To Be’ or ‘Ought To Be’: The Questions of Empirical Content and Normative Bias in Léon Walras's Methodology,” Journal of the History of Economic Thought, 26, December, 479–92CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Vroey, Michel (1987), “La possibilité d'une économie décentralisée,” Revue Economique, 38 (4), 773–805Google Scholar
Vroey, Michel (1999), “Transforming Walras into a Marshallian Economist: A Critical Review of Donald Walker's Walras's Market Models,” Journal of the History of Economic Thought, 21 (4), December, 413–35CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Diemer, Arnaud (2002), “Economie Pure, Economie Appliquée, Economie Sociale, Un point de vue critique sur l'œuvre de Léon Walras?,” IIIe Colloque de l'Association Internationale Walras, Lyon, September 20, in Les Cahiers du CERAS, hors série no. 3, May, 2004, 235–53, with the title “Economie Pure et Economie Appliquée. Retour sur les origines de l'œuvre de Léon Walras.”
Diemer, Arnaud and Jérôme Lallement (2004), “De Auguste à Léon Walras: retour sur les origines du marché et de la concurrence walrassiennes,” preliminary version, IVeColloque de l'Association Internationale Walras, Nice, September 23–24
Divisia, François (1928), Economique rationelle, Paris: G. DoinGoogle Scholar
Dockès, Pierre (1994), “≪La société n'est pas un pique-nique≫: le socialisme appliqué de Léon Walras,” Economies et Sociétés, Série Œconomia, Histoire de la Pensée économique, P. E. no. 20–21, 10–11, 270–325Google Scholar
Dockès, Pierre (1996), La société n'est pas un pique-nique: Léon Walras et l'économie sociale, Paris: EconomicaGoogle Scholar
Dockès, Pierre (1999), “Ce qui est, ce qui devrait être, ce qui sera: Walras's economics as he saw it,” Revue Européenne des Sciences Sociales, 37 (116), 13–36Google Scholar
Dockès, Pierre, Frobert, Ludovic, Klotz, Gérard, Potier, Jean-Pierre, and Tiran, André, (eds.), (2000), Les traditions économiques françaises 1848–1939, Paris: CNRS ÉDITIONSGoogle Scholar
Dockès, Pierre and Potier, Jean-Pierre (2001), La Vie et l'œuvre économique de Léon Walras, Paris: Economica; an extract from 249.V, IX–ⅬXXVIIIGoogle Scholar
Dorfman, Robert, Samuelson, Paul A., and Solow, Robert M. (1958), Linear Programming and Economic Analysis, New York, Toronto, London: McGraw-Hill Book CompanyGoogle Scholar
Eatwell, John, Milgate, Murray, and Newman, Peter (eds.), The New Palgrave: A Dictionary of Economics, 4 vols., London: Macmillan Press; New York: Stockton Press; Tokyo: Maruzen Company
Edgeworth, Francis Y. (1881), Mathematical Psychics: An Essay on the Application of Mathematics to the Moral Sciences, London: C. Kegan Paul; reprint, New York: Augustus M. Kelley, 1961Google Scholar
Edgeworth, Francis Y. (1889), “The Mathematical Theory of Political Economy. Eléments d'économie politique pure. By Léon Walras,” Nature, 40, September, 434–36Google Scholar
Einaudi, Manon Michels (1935), “Pareto as I Knew Him,” Atlantic Monthly, 156, September, 336–46Google Scholar
Fisher, Irving (1892), “Mathematical Investigations in the Theory of Value and Prices,” in Transactions of the Connecticut Academy, 9, July, 3–126; reprint, New York: Augustus M. Kelley, 1965
Fisher, Irving (1896), Appreciation and Interest, publications of the American Economic Association, 3rd series, 11 (4), August, New York: Macmillan Company
Fisher, Irving (1892), Mathematical Investigations in the Theory of Value and Prices, in Transactions of the Connecticut Academy, 9, July, 3–126; reprint, New York: Augustus M. Kelley, 1965
Fontaine, Phillippe (1998), “Menger, Jevons, and Walras Un-homogenized, De-homogenized, and Homogenized: A Comment on Peart,” American Journal of Economics and Sociology, 57 (3), July, 333–40CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Gewirtz, Alan (1941), “Experience and the Non-Mathematical in the Cartesian Method,” Journal of the History of Ideas, 2 (2), April, 183–210CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Giddings, Franklin H. (1896), The Principles of Sociology, New York: Macmillan CompanyGoogle Scholar
Gijsel, Peter de (1989), “On the Role of General Equilibrium Theory in Walras's Theory of a Just Society,” in Walker, Donald A. (ed.), Classical and Neoclassical Economic Thought: Selected Papers from the History of Economics Society Conference 1987, Perspectives on the History of Economic Thought, 1, Aldershot, UK: Edward Elgar for the History of Economics Society, 133–44Google Scholar
Gustafsson, Bo (1987), “Cassel, Gustav,” in Eatwell et al. 1987, 1, 375–77
Hahn, Frank (1981), review: “M. Beenstock, A Neoclassical Analysis of Macroeconomic Policy, Cambridge Universtiy Press, 1980,” Economic Journal, 91 (364), December, 1036–39CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hands, D. Wade (1998), “Positivism,” in Davis et al. 1998, 374–78
Hauenschild, Nils and Stahlecker, Peter (2002), “A Simple Proof for the Existence of Walrasian Equilibrium under Monotone Preferences,” Economics Bulletin, 4 (4), 1–8Google Scholar
Hayek, Friedrich August (1934), “Carl Menger,” Economica, n.s., 1, November, 393–420CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Herland, Michel (1996), “Three French Socialist Economists: Leroux, Proudhon, Walras,” Journal of the History of Economic Thought, 18 (1), Spring, 133–53CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Herschel, John F. W. (1831 [1830]), A Preliminary Discourse on the Study of Natural Philosophy, London: Longman, Rees, Orme, Browne and GreeneGoogle Scholar
Hicks, J. R. (1934), “Léon Walras,” Econometrica, 2, October, 338–48CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hicks, J. R. (1939), Value and Capital; 2nd ed., 1946, Oxford: Clarendon PressGoogle Scholar
Hicks, J. R. (1965), Capital and Growth, New York and Oxford: Oxford University PressGoogle Scholar
Hildenbrand, W. and Kirman, A. P. (1988), Equilibrium analysis: Variations on Themes by Edgeworth and Walras, in Advanced Textbooks in Economics, 28, Amsterdam, New York, Oxford, Tokyo: North-HollandGoogle Scholar
Hilton, H. C. (1995), “Léon Walras on Money and Banking,” History of Economics Review, 24, Summer, 72–78CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hollander, Samuel and Peart, Sandra (1999), “John Stuart Mill's Method in Principle and Practice: A Review of the Evidence,” Journal of the History of Economic Thought, 21 (4), December, 369–97CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hotelling, Harold (1929), “Stability in Competition,” Economic Journal, 39, March, 41–57CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Howitt, P. W. (1973), “Walras and Monetary Theory,” Western Economic Journal, 11 (4), December, 487–99Google Scholar
Huck, Elizabeth (2001), “La neutralité du tâtonnement au regard de la répartition des richesses dans la théorie de la production de Léon Walras. Le cas du tâtonnement sans bons des trois premières éditions des Eléments d'économie politique pure,” Revue économique, 52 (3), May, 729–38Google Scholar
Hume, David (1777), Enquiries concerning Human Understanding and concerning the Principles of Morals, 3rd edition; reprint, edited by L. A. Selby Bigge, Oxford: Clarendon Press, 1975CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hutchison, T. W. (1953), A Review of Economic Doctrines 1870–1929, London: Oxford University PressGoogle Scholar
Iimura, Takuya (2003), “A Discrete Fixed Point Theorem and Its Applications,” Journal of Mathematical Economics, 39 (7), September, 725–42CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ingrao, Bruna and Israel, Giorgio (1990), The Invisible Hand: Economic Equilibrium in the History of Science, translated by Ian McGilvray, Cambridge, MA: MIT PressGoogle Scholar
Jaffé, William (1935), “Unpublished Papers and Letters of Léon Walras,” Journal of Political Economy, 43, April, 187–207. All articles of Jaffé's that are listed in these references are reprinted in Jaffé 1983, except Jaffé 1978 and 1984CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Jaffé, William (1967), “Walras's Theory of Tâtonnement: A Critique of Recent Interpretations,” Journal of Political Economy, 75, February, 1–19CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Jaffé, William (1969), “A. N. Isnard, Progenitor of the Walrasian General Equilibrium Model,” History of Political Economy, 1, Spring, 19–43CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Jaffé, William (1971), “Reflections on the Importance of Léon Walras,” in Schaarste en Welvaart, P. Hennipman Festschrift, edited by Arnold Heertje et al., Amsterdam: Stenfert Kroese, 87–107
Jaffé, William (1976), “Menger, Jevons and Walras De-homogenized,” Economic Inquiry, 14, December, 511–24CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Jaffé, William (1977), “The Normative Bias of the Walrasian Model: Walras versus Gossen,” Quarterly Journal of Economics, 91, August, 371–87CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Jaffé, William (1978), Review of “Walras' Economics: A Pure Theory of Capital and Money, by Michio Morishima,” Economic Journal, 88, September, 574–617CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Jaffé, William (1980), “Walras's Economics as Others See It,” Journal of Economic Literature, 18, June, 528–49Google Scholar
Jaffé, William (1981), “Another Look at Léon Walras's Theory of Tâtonnement,” History of Political Economy, 13, Summer, 313–36CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Jaffé, William (1983), William Jaffé's Essays on Walras, edited by Walker, Donald A., Cambridge, New York, Melbourne: Cambridge University PressGoogle Scholar
Jaffé, William (1984), “The Antecedents and Early Life of Léon Walras,” edited by Donald A. Walker, History of Political Economy, 16 (1), Spring, 1–57CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Jolink, Albert (1993), “‘Procrustean Beds and All That’: The Irrelevance of Walras for a Mirowski Thesis,” History of Political Economy, 25, Supplement, 159–74Google Scholar
Keynes, John Maynard (1925/1930), “F. P. Ramsey 1903–1930,” in Essays and Sketches in Biography, New York: Median Books, 1956. 114–24Google Scholar
Keynes, John Maynard (1936), “William Stanley Jevons 1835–1882,” in Essays and Sketches in Biography, New York: Median Books, 1956, 125–60Google Scholar
Keynes, John Maynard (1936), The General Theory of Employment, Interest and Money, New York: Harcourt, Brace and CompanyGoogle Scholar
Kirman, Alan P. (1987), “Pareto as an Economist,” in Eatwell et al. 1987, 3, 804–9CrossRef
Kirman, Alan P. (1999), “The Future of Economic Theory,” in Kirman, Alan P. and Gérard-Varet, L.-A. (eds.), Economics Beyond the Millenium, Oxford: Oxford University Press, 8–22CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Klotz, Gérard (1994), “Achylle Nicolas Isnard, précurseur de Léon Walras?,” Economies et Sociétés, Série Œconomia, Histoire de la Pensée économique, P.E. nos. 20–21, 28 (10–11), 29–52Google Scholar
Koopmans, Tjalling (1964), “Economic Growth at a Maximal Rate,” Quarterly Journal of Economics, 78, August, 355–94CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Koppl, Roger (1992), “Price Theory as Physics: The Cartesian Influence in Walras,” Methodus, 4 (2), December, 17–28; and in Walker 2001, 1, 199–210Google Scholar
Koppl, Roger (1995), “The Walras Paradox,” Eastern Economic Journal, 21 (1), 43–55; and in Walker 2001a, 2, 268–80Google Scholar
Kowalik, Tadeusz (1987), “Lange, Oskar Ryszard (1904–1965),” in Eatwell et al. 1987, 3, 123–29CrossRef
Kuenne, Robert E. (1961), “The Walrasian Theory of Money: An Interpretation and a Reconstruction,” Metroeconomica, 13, August, 94–105CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kurz, Heinz and Neri Salvadori (2000), “Walras and Ricardo,” in Dockès et al. 2000, 967–85
Kurz, Heinz and Salvadori, Neri (2004), “Von Neumann, the Classical Economists and Arrow-Debreu: Some Notes,” Acta Œconomica, 54 (1), 39–62CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Volpe, Giulio (1936), Studi Sulla Teoria Dell' Equilibrio Economico Dinamico Generale, Naples: Jovene; translated by Helen Ampt as Studies on the Theory of General Dynamic Economic Equilibrium, Basingstoke and London: Macmillan, 1993Google Scholar
Lange, Oskar R. (1936), “On the Economic Theory of Socialism, Part I,” Review of Economic Studies, 4 (1), October, 53–71CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lange, Oskar R. (1937), “On the Economic Theory of Socialism, Part II,” Review of Economic Studies, 4 (2), February, 123–42CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lange, Oskar R. (1944), Price Flexibility and Employment, Bloomington: Principia PressGoogle Scholar
Laurent, Hermann (1902), Petit traité d'économie politique mathématique, rédigé conformément aux préceptes de l' école de Lausanne, Paris: C. SchmidGoogle Scholar
Lendjel, Emeric (1997), “Le ≪biais empiriste≫ dans l'interprétation de Walker du tâtonnement walrassien,” Economies et Sociétés, Œconomia, Histoire de la pensée économique, Série P.E., no. 26, 31 (10), 47–84Google Scholar
Lendjel, Emeric (1999), “Tâtonnement walrassien et marchandage parétien: Une approche comparative,” Revue européenne des sciences sociales, 37 (116), 295–314Google Scholar
Lengwiler, Yvan (1998), “Endogenous Endowments and Equilibrium Starvation in a Walrasian Economy,” Journal of Mathematical Economics, 30 (1), August, 37–58CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lexis, William (1881), “Zur mathematisch-ökonomischen Literatur,” Jahrbücher für Nationalökonomie und Statistik, new series, 3, 427–34Google Scholar
Locke, John (1954), Essays on the Law of Nature, edited by Leyden, W., Oxford: Oxford University PressGoogle Scholar
Mantel, R. (1974), “On the Characterisation of Aggregate Excess Demand,” Journal of Economic Theory, 7, 348–53CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Marchionatti, Roberto and Gambino, Enrico (1997), “Pareto and Political Economy as a Science: Methodological Revolution and Analytical Advances in Economic Theory in the 1890s,” Journal of Political Economy, 105 (6), December, 1322–48CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Marchionatti, Roberto and Mornati, Fiorenzo (2003), “Pareto et l'économie Mathématique au Début des Années 1890. Quelques Réflexions à Propos des ≪Considerazioni sui Principii Fondamentali Dell'economia Politica Pura≫,” in Histoire et Théorie des Sciences Sociales. Mélanges en l'honneur de Giovanni Busino, Geneva: Droz, 3, 51–84Google Scholar
Marget, Arthur W. (1931), “Léon Walras and the ‘Cash-Balance Approach’ to the Problem of the Value of Money,” Journal of Political Economy, 39 (5), October, 569–600CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Marget, Arthur W. (1935), “The Monetary Aspects of the Walrasian System,” Journal of Political Economy, 43, April, 145–86CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Marinitsch, O. (1892), La Bourse, théorique et pratique, Paris: Paul OllendorffGoogle Scholar
Marx, Karl (1858), “Introduction” to Contribution to the Critique of Political Economy, reprinted in David Horowitz, Marx and Modern Economics, New York: Monthly Review Press, 1968Google Scholar
Marx, Karl (1867), Capital, 1, Harmondsworth: Penguins Books, 1976Google Scholar
McKenzie, Lionel W. (1954), “On Equilibrium in Graham's Model of World Trade and Other Competitive Systems,” Econometrica, 22, April, 147–61CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ménard, Claude (1990), “The Lausanne Tradition: Walras and Pareto,” and “Commentary” by Donald A. Walker, in Hennings, Klaus and Samuels, Warren J. (eds), Neoclassical Economic Theory: 1870 to 1930, Dordrecht: Kluwer Academici Publishers, 95–136, 137–50CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Menger, Karl (1973), “Austrian Marginalism and Mathematical Economics,” in Carl Menger and the Austrian school of economics, edited by Hicks, John R. and Weber, W., Oxford: Oxford University Press, 38–60Google Scholar
Mill, John Stuart (1836), “On the definition of Political Economy; and on the Method of Philosophical Investigation Proper to It,” London and Westminster Review, October; in Essays on Some Unsettled Questions of Political Economy, London: John W. Parker, 1844, 120–64; and in Collected Works of John Stuart Mill, 22, Toronto: University of Toronto Press, 1967, 309–39
Mill, John Stuart (1981–1991), Collected Works of John Stuart Mill, 33 vols., Toronto: Toronto University PressGoogle Scholar
Mirowski, Philip (1989), More heat than light. Economics as social physics: Physics as nature's economics, Cambridge: Cambridge University PressCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Moore, Henry Ludwell (1929), Synthetic Economics, New York: MacmillanGoogle Scholar
Moret, Jacques (1915), L'Emploi des mathématiques en économie poltitque, Paris: M. Giard et E. BrièreGoogle Scholar
Morishima, Michio (1977), Walras' Economics; A Pure Theory of Capital and Money, Cambridge: Cambridge University PressGoogle Scholar
Morishima, Michio (1996), “Morishima on Ricardo: Two Replies,” Cambridge Journal of Economics, 20 (1), January, 91–109; in Walker 2001, 1, 278–96CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Mosak, Jacob L. (1987), “Schultz, Henry (1893–1938),” in Eatwell et al. 1987, 4, 261–62CrossRef
Mouchot, Claude (2000), “De quelques problèmes relatifs à l'entrepreneur walrassien,” Les Cahiers du CERAS, Actes du Colloque de l'Association Internationale Walras, hors série no1, juin, 49–57
Murray, Roberto A. (1920), Leçons d'économie politique suivant la doctrine de l'école de Lausanne, Paris: Payot et CieGoogle Scholar
Myrdal, Gunnar (1945), “Gustav Cassel in Memoriam,” Ekonomisk revy, 2, 3–13Google Scholar
Nash, John F. (1950), “The Bargaining Problem,” Econometrica, 18, 155–62CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Nash, John F. (1951), “Non-cooperative Games,” Annals of Mathematics, 54, 286–95CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Negishi, Takashi (1989), History of Economic Theory, Amsterdam: North-HollandGoogle Scholar
Neisser, Hans Philipp (1932), “Lohnhöhe und Beschäftigungsgrad im Marktgleichgewicht,” Weltwirtschaftliches Archiv, 36 (2), October, 415–55Google Scholar
Neumann, John von (1937), “Über ein Ökonomisches Gleichungssystem und eine Verallgemeinerung des Brouwerschen Fixpunktsatzes,” Ergebnisse eines Mathematischen Kolloquiums, Heft 8, 1935–1936 [sic]; edited by Karl Menger, Leipzig and Wien: Franz Deuticke, 1938, 73–83; translated by George Morgenstern as “A Model of General Economic Equilibrium,” Review of Economic Studies, 13, 1945–1946, 1–9
Neumann, John and Morgenstern, Oskar (1944), Theory of Games and Economic Behavior, Princeton: Princeton University PressGoogle Scholar
Niiniluoto, Ilkka (1998), “Induction,” in Davis et al. 1998, 246–49
Osorio, Antonio (1913), Théorie mathématique de l'échange, Paris: M. Giard et E. BrièreGoogle Scholar
Pantaleoni, Maffeo (1889), Principii di economia pura, Florence: BarberaGoogle Scholar
Pareto, Vilfredo (1893a), “Lettre d'Italie,” Le Monde Economique, July 8, 35–36Google Scholar
Pareto, Vilfredo (1893b), “Considerazioni sui principii fondamentali dell'economia politica pura,” Giornale degli Economisti, series 2, 7, October, 279–321Google Scholar
Pareto, Vilfredo (1896/1897), Cours d'économie politique, 2 vols., Lausanne: F. Rouge; reprint, edited by Bousquet, G.-H. and Busino, G., Geneva: Librairie Droz, 1964Google Scholar
Pareto, Vilfredo (1897), “The New Theories of Economics,” Journal of Political Economy, 5 (4), 485–502CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Pareto, Vilfredo (1898a), “Protezionismo italiano,” Critica Sociale, Rivista Quindicinale de Socialismo, 7, February 16, 49–50Google Scholar
Pareto, Vilfredo (1898b), “De l'économie mathématique,” Zeitschrift für Sozialwissenschaft, 1, 320–21Google Scholar
Pareto, Vilfredo (1899), “Liberali e Socialisti,” Critica Sociale, Rivista quindicinale de Socialismo, 8, September 1, 215–16Google Scholar
Pareto, Vilfredo (1902–1903), Les systèmes socialistes, 2 vols., Paris: V. Giard & E. BrièreGoogle Scholar
Pareto, Vilfredo (1909), Manuel d'économie politique; translated by Alfred Bonnet from the Italian Manuale d'economia politica, Milan: Società Editrice Libraria, 1906; translation reviewed and corrected by the author, Paris: V. Giard & E. Brière. The Italian version translated by Ann S. Schwier as Manual of Political Economy, New York: Augustus M. Kelley, 1971
Pareto, Vilfredo (1911b), “Economie Mathématique,” in Encyclopédie des sciences mathématiques, 1, Paris: Teubner, Gauthier, VillarsGoogle Scholar
Pareto, Vilfredo (1912a), “Economia Dimessa,” La Libertà Economica, Rassegna settimanale, 10 (17–18), 285–90Google Scholar
Pareto, Vilfredo (1912b), Review of “La Teoria della Rendita. By Prof. Guido Sensini. (Rome: Loescher. 1912.),” Economic Journal, 22 (3), September, 467–69CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Pareto, Vilfredo (1916), Trattato di sociologia generale, 4 vols., Florence: Barbera; translated by Andrew Bongiorno and Arthur Livingston as The Mind and Society; A Treatise on General Sociology, New York: Dover Publications, 1963Google Scholar
Pareto, Vilfredo (1948), Corrispondenza di V. Pareto, edited by Sensini, Guido, Padua: Cedam (Casa editrice Dr. Antonio Milani)Google Scholar
Pareto, Vilfredo (1960), Lettere a Maffeo Pantaleoni, 1890–1923, edited by Sensini, Guido, 3 vols., Rome: Banca Nazionale del LavoroGoogle Scholar
Pareto, Vilfredo (1963–2001), Œuvres complètes de Vilfredo Pareto, 31 vols., prepared under the direction of Giovanni Busino, Geneva: DrozGoogle Scholar
Patinkin, Don (1956), Money, Interest, and Prices: An Integration of Monetary and Value Theory, Evanston, IL: Row, Peterson; 2nd ed., New York: Harper and Row, 1965Google Scholar
Patinkin, Don (1987), “Walras's Law,” in Eatwell et al. 1987, 3, 863–68CrossRef
Petri, Fabio (2004), General Equilibrium, Capital and Macroeconomics; A Key to Recent Controversies in Equilibrium Theory, Cheltenham, UK, and Northhampton, MA: Edward Elgar PublishingGoogle Scholar
Pietri-Tonelli, Alfonso (1924), “Le equazioni generali dell'equilibrio economico di Vilfredo Pareto,” Giornale degli Economisti, series 4, 65, 55–61Google Scholar
Pietri-Tonelli, Alfonso (1927), Traité d'économie rationnelle, 3rd ed, Paris: M. GiardGoogle Scholar
Pirou, Gaëtan (1925), Les doctrines economiques en France depuis 1870, Paris: A. ColinGoogle Scholar
Pirou, Gaëtan (1934), Les théories de l'équilibre économique: L. Walras et V. Pareto, Paris: Les Editions Domat-MontchrestienGoogle Scholar
Poinsoit, Louis (1803), Elements de statique; 8th edition, Paris: Bachelier, 1842Google Scholar
Pokorny, D. (1978), “Smith and Walras: Two theories of science,” Canadian Journal of Economics and Political Science, 11 (3), 387–403Google Scholar
Potier, Jean-Pierre (1994), “Classification des sciences et divisions de l'≪économie politique et sociale≫ dans l'œuvre de Léon Walras: une tentative de reconstruction,” Economies et Sociétés, Série Œconomia, Histoire de la Pensée économique, P.E. no. 20–21, 28 (10–11), 223–77Google Scholar
Potier, Jean-Pierre (1998), “Léon Walras and Applied Science: The Significance of the Free Competition Principle,” in Faccarello, Gilbert (ed.), Studies in the History of French Political Economy: From Bodin to Walras, London and New York: Routledge, 369–403CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Potier, Jean-Pierre and Walker, Donald (eds.) (2004), La correspondance entre Aline Walras et William Jaffé et autres documents, Paris: EconomicaGoogle Scholar
Rebeyrol, Antoine (1998), “The Development of Walras' Monetary Theory,” in Faccarello, Gilbert (ed.), Studies in the History of French Political Economy: From Bodin to Walras, London and New York: Routledge, 319–68CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Rebeyrol, Antoine (1999), La pensée économique de Walras, Paris: DunodGoogle Scholar
Rebeyrol, Antoine (2002), “‘Yet Another Look’? A Comment,” European Journal of the History of Economic Thought, 9 (4), winter, 541–49CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Redman, Deborah (1997), The Rise of Political Economy as a Science; Methodology and the Classical Economists, Cambridge, MA, and London: MIT PressGoogle Scholar
Ricci, Umberto (1924), “Pareto e l'economia pura,” Giornale degli Economisti, series 4, 65, 27–44; translated as “Pareto and Pure Economics,” Review of Economic Studies, 1 (1–3), 1933–1934, 3–21Google Scholar
Rizvi, S. Abu Turab (2003), “Postwar Neoclassical Microeconomics,” in A Companion to the History of Economic Thought, edited by Samuels, Warren J., Biddle, Jeff E., and Davis, John B., Malden, MA, Oxford, UK, Melbourne, Berlin: Blackwell Publishing Ltd., 377–94Google Scholar
Robert, Paul. (eds.) (2002), “Expérimental,” Le nouveau petit Robert, Paris: Dictionnaires Le Robert, 1001Google Scholar
Samuelson, Paul A. (1941a), “The Stability of Equilibrium: Comparative Statics and Dynamics,” Econometrica, 9 (2), April, 97–120CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Samuelson, Paul A. (1941b), “The Stability of Equilibrium: Linear and Nonlinear Systems,” Econometrica, 9, April, 97–120CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Samuelson, Paul A. (1947), Foundations of Economic Analysis, Cambridge: Harvard University PressGoogle Scholar
Samuelson, Paul A. (1993), “Gustav Cassel's Scientific Innovations: Claims and Realities,” History of Political Economy, 25 (3), 515–27CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Samuelson, Paul A. (1998), “Samuelson, Paul Anthony, as an Interpreter of the Classical Economists,” in Kurz, Heinz D. and Salvadori, Neri, eds., The Elgar Companion to Classical Economics, 2, Cheltenham, U.K.: Edward Elgar Publishing Limited, 329–333CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Schlesinger, Karl (1914), Theorie der Geld-und Kreditwirtschaft, Munich/ Leipzig: Dunker und HumblotGoogle Scholar
Schlesinger, Karl (1933–1934), “Über die produktionsgleichungen der ökonomischen Wertlehre,” Ergebnisse eines mathematischen Kolloquiums, Heft 6, edited by Karl Menger, Leipzig and Wien: Franz Deuticke, 1935, 10–11; translated by William J. Baumol as “On the Production Equations of Economic Value Theory,” in Baumol and Goldfeld 1968, 278–80
Schultz, Henry (1929), “Marginal Productivity and the General Pricing Process,” Journal of Political Economy, 37, October, 505–51CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Schultz, Henry (1932), “Marginal Productivity and the Lausanne School,” Economica, 12, August, 285–96CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Schultz, Henry (1933), “Interrelations of Demand,” Journal of Political Economy, 41, August, 468–512CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Schultz, Henry (1935), “Interrelations of Demand, Price, and Income,” Journal of Political Economy, 43, August, 433–81CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Schultz, Henry (1938), The Theory and Measurement of Demand, Chicago: University of Chicago PressGoogle Scholar
Schumpeter, Joseph A. (1910), “Marie Esprit Léon Walras,” Zeitschrift für Volksvirtschaft, 19, 397–402; English translation in Schumpeter 1951, 74–79Google Scholar
Schumpeter, Joseph A. (1911/1926), The Theory of Economic Development; An Inquiry into Profits, Capital, Credit, Interest, and the Business Cycle; translated by Redvers Opie, New York: Oxford University Press, 1961Google Scholar
Schumpeter, Joseph A. (1925), “Schumpeter on Böhm-Bawerk,” in Spiegel, Henry W. (ed.), The Development of Economic Thought; Great Economists in Perspective, abridged edition, New York, Science Editions, John Wiley & Sons, 1964, 370–80Google Scholar
Schumpeter, Joseph A. (1949), “Vilfredo Pareto,” Quarterly Journal of Economics, 63, May, 345–59; and in Schumpeter 1951CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Schumpeter, Joseph A. (1951), Ten Great Economists from Marx to Keynes, New York: Oxford University PressGoogle Scholar
Schumpeter, Joseph A. (1954), History of Economic Analysis, New York: Oxford University PressGoogle Scholar
Schwartz, P. (1972), The New Political Economy of J. S. Mill, London: London School of EconomicsGoogle Scholar
Sensini, Guido (1929), “Vilfredo Pareto e la teoria della moneta,” Il Giornale Economico, September–October; reprinted in Guido Sensini, Studi di scienze sociali, 1, Rome: Casa Libraria Editrice Italiana, 1932
Sonnenschein, Hugo F. (1972), “Market Excess Demand Functions,” Econometrica, 40, 549–63CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Sonnenschein, Hugo F. (1973), “Utility Hypothesis and Market Demand Theory,” Western Economic Journal, 11, 404–10Google Scholar
Slutsky, Eugen (1915), “Sulla teoria del bilancio del consomatore,” Giornale degli Economisti e Rivista di Statistica, 51, July, 1–26Google Scholar
Stackelberg, Heinrich (1933), “Zwei Kritische Bemerkungen zur Preistheorie Gustav Cassels,” Zeitschrift für Nationalökonomie, 4, June, 456–72CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Staley, Charles E. (1989), A History of Economic Thought. From Aristotle to Arrow, Cambridge, MA: Basil BlackwellGoogle Scholar
Steiner, Philippe (1999), “L'entrepreneur parétien et la théorie de l'action,” Revue européenne des sciences sociales, 37 (116), 103–118Google Scholar
Stigler, George (1941), Production and Distribution Theories; The Formative Period, New York: Macmillan CompanyGoogle Scholar
Syll, Lars Pålsson (1993), “Wicksell on Harmony Economics: The Lausanne School vs. Wicksell,” Scandinavian Economic History Review, 41 (2), Winter, 172–88CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Tatti, Elena (2000), “Âtre et devoir âtre chez Léon Walras,” in Dockès et al. 2000, 417–28
Vacherot, Etienne (1858), La métaphysique et la science ou principes de métaphysique positive; 2nd ed., 1863, 3 vols., Paris: Librairie de F. ChamerotGoogle Scholar
Daal, Jan and Walker, Donald A. (1990), “The Problem of Aggregation in Walras's General Equilibrium Theory,” History of Political Economy, 22 (3), Fall, 489–505; and in Walker 2001a, 2, 341–57CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Daal, Jan and Jolink, Albert (1989), “Léon Walras's Mathematical Economics and the Mechanical Analogies,” History of Economics Society Bulletin, 11 (1), Spring, 25–32; and in Walker 2001a, 1, 93–100Google Scholar
van Daal, Jan and Albert Jolink (1993), “Walras's ‘General’ General-Equilibrium Model,” in Hébert, Robert F. (ed.), Themes on Economic Discourse, Method, Money and Trade: Selected Papers from the History of Economics Conference 1991, Perspectives on the History of Economic Thought, 9, Aldershot: Edward Elgar for the History of Economics Society, 121–36Google Scholar
Wald, Abraham (1934–1935), “Über die Produktionsgleichungen der ökonomischen Wertlehre (II),” Ergebnisse eines mathematischen Kolloquiums, Heft 7; Leipzig and Wein: Frank Deuticke, 1936, 1–6; translated by William J. Baumol as “On the Production Equations of Economic Value Theory, Part 2,” in Baumol and Goldfeld 1968, 289–93
Wald, Abraham (1936), “Über einige Gleichungssysteme der mathematischen Ökonomie,” Zeitschrift für Nationalökonomie, 7 (5), 637–70; translated by Otto Eckstein as “On Some Systems of Equations of Mathematical Economics,” Econometrica, 19, October, 1951, 368–403CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Walker, Donald A. (1970), “Léon Walras in the Light of His Correspondence and Related Papers,” Journal of Political Economy, 78 (4), July-August, 685–701CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Walker, Donald A. (1971a), “The Static Analysis of Disequilibrium Transactions Markets,” Indian Economic Journal, 18 (3), January-March, 305–327Google Scholar
Walker, Donald A. (1971b), “The Determinateness of Equilibrium in Isolated Competitive Markets,” International Review of Economics and Business, 18 (12), December, 1158–1179Google Scholar
Walker, Donald A. (1983), “William Jaffé, Officier de liaison intellectuel,” in The Craft of the Historian of Economic Thought, vol. 1 of Research in the History of Economic Thought and Methodology, edited by Samuels, Warren J., Greenwich, CT: JAI Press, 19–39Google Scholar
Walker, Donald A. (1984), “Is Walras's Theory of General Equilibrium a Normative Scheme?History of Political Economy, 16 (3), Fall, 445–69CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Walker, Donald A. (1987a) “Walras's Theories of Tatonnement,” Journal of Political Economy, 95(4), 758–74CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Walker, Donald A. (1987b), “Walras, Léon (1934–1910),” in Eatwell et al., 4, 852–63
Walker, Donald A. (1987c), “Bibliography of the Writings of Léon Walras,” 1st ed., History of Political Economy, 19 (4), 667–702CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Walker, Donald A. (1989), “A Primer on Walrasian Theories of Economic Behavior,” History of Economics Society Bulletin, 11, Spring, 1–23; reprinted in Blaug 1992, 214–36CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Walker, Donald A. (1990), “Commentary by Donald A. Walker” on “The Lausanne Tradition: Walras and Pareto,” by Claude Ménard, in Neoclassical Economic Theory, 1870 to 1930, edited by Hennings, Klaus and Samuels, Warren J., Boston, Dordrecht, London: Kluwer Academic Publishers, 137–50CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Walker, Donald A. (1991), Review of “The Invisible Hand: Economic Equilibrium in the History of Science, by Bruna Ingrao and Giorgio Israel,” 1990, History of Political Economy, 23, no. 3, Fall, 560–65CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Walker, Donald A. (1996), Walras's Market Models, Cambridge, New York, and Melbourne: Cambridge University PressCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Walker, Donald A. (1997a), “The School of Lausanne,” in Encyclopedia of Keynesian Economics, edited by Cate, Thomas, with associate editors Colander, David and Harcourt, Geoffrey, Cheltenham, UK, and Brookfield, VT: Edward Elgar Publishing Limited, 361–65Google Scholar
Walker, Donald A. (1997b), Advances in General Equilibrium Theory, Cheltenham, UK, Lyme, CT: Edward Elgar Publishing Limited; in French, translated by the author: La théorie de l'équilibre général: De nouveaux éclairages, Paris: Economica, 1999Google Scholar
Walker, Donald A. (1998), “Léon Walras,” in The Handbook of Economic Methodology, edited by Davis, John B., Hands, D. Wade, and Maki, Uskali, Cheltenham, UK, Northampton, MA: Edward Elgar Publishing Limited, 541–45CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Walker, Donald A. (ed.) (2000a), Equilibrium, 3 vols., in Hoover, Kevin D. and Blaug, Mark (general eds.), Critical Ideas in Economics, no. 2, Cheltenham, UK, and Northampton, MA: Edward Elgar Publishing LimitedGoogle Scholar
Walker, Donald A. (2000b), “La relation entre la Bourse au ⅪXe siècle et le modèle de Léon Walras d'un marché organisé,” in Dockès et al. 2000, 443–57
Walker, Donald A. (ed.) (2001a), The Legacy of Léon Walras, 2 vols., in Medema, Steven G., (series ed.), Intellectual Legacies in Modern Economics, Cheltenham, UK, and Northampton, MA: Edward Elgar Publishing LimitedGoogle Scholar
Walker, Donald A. (2001b), “A factual account of the functioning of the nineteenth-century Paris Bourse,” European Journal of the History of Economic Thought, 8 (2), 186–207CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Walker, Donald A. (2003), “Early General Equilibrium Economics: Walras, Pareto, and Cassel,” in A Companion to the History of Economic Thought, edited by Samuels, Warren J., Biddle, Jeff E., and Davis, John B., Malden, MA, Oxford, UK, Melbourne, Berlin: Blackwell Publishing Ltd., ch. 18, 278–93Google Scholar
Walras, Auguste (1831), De la nature de la richesse et de l'origine de la valeur, Paris: Alexandre JohanneauGoogle Scholar
Weintraub, E. Roy (1983), “On the Existence of a Competitive Equilibrium: 1930–1954,” Journal of Economic Literature, 21 (1), 1–39Google Scholar
Wicksell, Knut (1893), Über Wert, Kapital und Rente, nach den neueren nationalökonomischen Theorien, Jena: G. FisherGoogle Scholar
Wicksell, Knut (1898), Geldzins und Güterpreise bestimmenden Ursachen, Jena: G. Fischer; translated by R. F. Kahn as Interest and Prices; A Study of the Causes Regulating the Value of Money, London: Macmillan, 1936Google Scholar
Wicksell, Knut (1901, 1906), Vorlesungen über Nationalökonomie; 2nd ed. 1911, translated by E. Classen as Lectures on Political Economy, 2 vols., London: Routledge & Kegan Paul, 1934Google Scholar
Wicksell, Knut (1919), “Professor Cassel's System of Economics,” in Wicksell 1934, appendix 1, 219–57
Wicksell, Knut (1934), Lectures on Political Economy, vol. 1, General Theory, translated from the Swedish by E. Classen, London: Routledge and Kegan PaulGoogle Scholar
Witteloostuijn, A. and Maks, J. A. H. (1988), “Walras: A Hicksian avant la lettre,” Economie Appliquée, 41 (3), 595–608Google Scholar
Wieser, Friedrich (1891), “The Austrian School and the Theory of Value,” Economic Journal, 1, March, 108–21CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Witteloostuijn, A. and Maks, J. A. H. (1990), “Walras on Temporary Equilibrium and Dynamics,” History of Political Economy, 22 (2), 223–37CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Wood, John C. (ed.) (1993), Léon Walras: Critical Assessments, 3 vols., London: RoutledgeGoogle Scholar
Zatarin, Joseph (1972), “La théorie des tâtonnements chez Walras,” Revue d'Economie Politique, 82 (6), 1222–28Google Scholar
Zawadzki, Wńadyslaw (1914), Les mathématiques appliquées à l'économie politique, Paris: M. RivièreGoogle Scholar
Zeuthen, Frederik L. B. (1928), Den konomiske Fordeling, Copenhagen: BusckGoogle Scholar
Zeuthen, Frederik L. B. (1933), “Das Princip der Knappheit, Technische Kominatin und Ökonomische Qualität,” Zeitschrift für Nationalökonomie, 4, 1–24Google Scholar
Zylberberg, André (1988), “L'économie mathématique chez les actuaires français au temps de Walras (1820–1914),” Oeconomia, 9, 35–64Google Scholar
Zylberberg, André (1990), L'économie mathématique en France 1870–1914, Paris: EconomicaGoogle Scholar

Save book to Kindle

To save this book to your Kindle, first ensure coreplatform@cambridge.org is added to your Approved Personal Document E-mail List under your Personal Document Settings on the Manage Your Content and Devices page of your Amazon account. Then enter the ‘name’ part of your Kindle email address below. Find out more about saving to your Kindle.

Note you can select to save to either the @free.kindle.com or @kindle.com variations. ‘@free.kindle.com’ emails are free but can only be saved to your device when it is connected to wi-fi. ‘@kindle.com’ emails can be delivered even when you are not connected to wi-fi, but note that service fees apply.

Find out more about the Kindle Personal Document Service.

  • References
  • Donald A. Walker, Indiana University of Pennsylvania
  • Book: Walrasian Economics
  • Online publication: 02 September 2009
  • Chapter DOI: https://doi.org/10.1017/CBO9780511510748.014
Available formats
×

Save book to Dropbox

To save content items to your account, please confirm that you agree to abide by our usage policies. If this is the first time you use this feature, you will be asked to authorise Cambridge Core to connect with your account. Find out more about saving content to Dropbox.

  • References
  • Donald A. Walker, Indiana University of Pennsylvania
  • Book: Walrasian Economics
  • Online publication: 02 September 2009
  • Chapter DOI: https://doi.org/10.1017/CBO9780511510748.014
Available formats
×

Save book to Google Drive

To save content items to your account, please confirm that you agree to abide by our usage policies. If this is the first time you use this feature, you will be asked to authorise Cambridge Core to connect with your account. Find out more about saving content to Google Drive.

  • References
  • Donald A. Walker, Indiana University of Pennsylvania
  • Book: Walrasian Economics
  • Online publication: 02 September 2009
  • Chapter DOI: https://doi.org/10.1017/CBO9780511510748.014
Available formats
×