Hostname: page-component-586b7cd67f-dsjbd Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-11-24T05:50:47.371Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Conflict, War, and Redistribution

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  01 December 1985

Dagobert L. Brito
Affiliation:
Rice University
Michael D. Intriligator
Affiliation:
University of California, Los Angeles

Abstract

This article analyzes the circumstances under which conflict leads to the outbreak of war using a formal model which incorporates both the redistribution of resources as an alternative to war and imperfect information. Countries act as rational agents concerned with both consumption and the public bad of a war. In the first period both countries can either consume or build arms, whereas in the second period there can be either the threat or the use of force to reallocate resources. If both countries are fully informed, then there will be no war but rather a voluntary redistribution of resources. In a situation of asymmetric information, however, in which one country is fully informed and the other is not, a war can occur if the uninformed country uses a separating equilibrium strategy, precommitting itself to a positive probability of war in order to prevent bluffing by the informed country.

Type
Research Article
Copyright
Copyright © American Political Science Association 1985

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

References

Brams, S. J., Davis, M. D., & Straffin, P. D. Jr., The geometry of the arms race. International Studies Quarterly, 1979, 23, 567588.10.2307/2600329CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Brito, D. L. A dynamic model of an armaments race. International Economic Review, 1972, 13, 359375.10.2307/2526030CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Brito, D. L., Buoncristiani, A. M., & Intriligator, M. D. A new approach to the Nash bargaining problem. Econometrica, 1977, 45, 11631172.10.2307/1914064CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bueno de Mesquita, B. The war trap. New Haven, Conn.: Yale University Press, 1981.Google Scholar
Cramton, P. Role of time in bargaining. Stanford, Calif.: Working Paper, Stanford University, 1983.Google Scholar
Freixas, X., Guesnerie, R., & Tirole, J. Planning under incomplete information and the ratchet effect. Paris: Centre d'Enseignement et de Recherche en Analyse Socio-Economique, Paper 17, 1983.Google Scholar
Fudenberg, D., & Tirole, J. Sequential bargaining under incomplete information. Review of Economic Studies, 1982, 50, 221247.10.2307/2297414CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Intriligator, M. D. Mathematical optimization and economic theory. Englewood Cliffs N.J.: Prentice Hall, 1971.Google Scholar
Intriligator, M. D. Strategic considerations in the Richardson model of arms races. Journal of Political Economy, 1975, 83, 339353.10.1086/260326CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Intriligator, M. D. Research on conflict theory: Analytic approaches and areas of application. Journal of Conflict Resolution, 1982, 26, 307327.10.1177/0022002782026002006CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Intriligator, M. D., & Brito, D. L. Formal models of arms races. Journal of Peace Science, 1976, 2, 7788.10.1177/073889427600200106CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Intriligator, M. D., & Brito, D. L. Can arms races lead to the outbreak of war? Journal of Conflict Resolution, 1984, 28, 6384.10.1177/0022002784028001004CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kreps, D., & Wilson, R. Sequential equilibria. Econometrica, 1982, 50, 863894.10.2307/1912767CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lambelet, J. C. Do arms races lead to war? Journal of Peace Research 1975, 12, 123128.10.1177/002234337501200204CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Mirrlees, J. An exploration in the theory of optimum income taxation. Review of Economic Studies, 1971, 38, 175228.10.2307/2296779CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Morton, S. The optimality of strikes in labor negotiations. New Orleans: Murphy Institute of Political Economy Discussion Paper, Tulane University, 1983.Google Scholar
Nalebuff, B. Prizes and incentives. Oxford: Nuffield College D. Phil, thesis, 1982.Google Scholar
Nash, J. Equilibrium points in N-person games. Proceedings of National Academy of Sciences, 1950, 36, 4849.10.1073/pnas.36.1.48CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Organski, A. F. K., & Kugler, J. The war ledger. Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 1983.Google Scholar
Owen, G. Game theory (2nd ed.). New York: Academic Press, 1982.Google Scholar
Richardson, L. F. Could an arms race end without fighting? Nature, September 29, 1951, pp. 567568.Google Scholar
Richardson, L. F. Arms and insecurity. Pittsburgh: Boxwood Press, 1960.Google Scholar
Schelling, T. C. Arms and influence. New Haven, Conn.: Yale University Press, 1966.Google Scholar
Siverson, R., & Tennefoss, M. Power, alliances and the international conflict, 1815-1965. American Political Science Review, 1983, 77, 10571069.Google Scholar
Smith, T. C. Arms race instability and war. Journal of Conflict Resolution, 1980, 24, 253284.10.1177/002200278002400204CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Szilard, L. Minimal deterrent vs. saturation parity. Bulletin of the Atomic Scientists, 1964, 20, 612.10.1080/00963402.1964.11454630CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Wallace, M. D. Arms races and escalation: Some new evidence. Journal of Conflict Resolution, 1979, 23, 316.10.1177/002200277902300101CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Wallace, M. D. Armaments and escalation: Two competing hypotheses. International Studies Quarterly, 1982, 26, 3756.10.2307/2600598CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Submit a response

Comments

No Comments have been published for this article.