Hostname: page-component-78c5997874-fbnjt Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-11-18T02:18:57.421Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Interest Representation: The Dominance of Institutions

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  01 August 2014

Robert H. Salisbury*
Affiliation:
Washington University

Abstract

Interest group theory traditionally assumed that policies advocated by group representatives in some sense grow out of the interests or values of the group's members. Mancur Olson and others compelled important revisions in this assumption, but still left the process of interest advocacy to membership groups. It is contended here that institutions, such as corporations or local governments, occupy a dominant position with respect to interest representation in Washington, and this finding requires substantial revisions in both theoretical and descriptive formulations of the governmental process.

Type
Research Article
Copyright
Copyright © American Political Science Association 1984

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

References

Asch, R.Social movements in America. Chicago: Markham, 1972.Google Scholar
Barker, L. J.Third parties in litigation. Journal of Politics, 1967, 29, 4169.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bauer, R., Pool, I. de S., and Dexter, L.A.American business and public policy. New York: Atherton, 1963.Google Scholar
Bentley, A.The process of government. Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 1908.Google Scholar
Berger, S.Organizing interests in western Europe: pluralism, corporatism and the transformation of politics. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1981.Google Scholar
Berry, J.M.Lobbying for the people. Princeton, N.J.: Princeton University Press, 1977.Google Scholar
Blaisdell, D.C.American democracy under pressure. New York: Ronald, 1957.Google Scholar
Cherington, P.W., & Gillen, R.L.The business representative in Washington. Washington, D.C.: Brookings Institution, 1962.Google Scholar
Close, A.C. (Ed.). Washington representatives, 1981 (5th ed.). Washington, D.C.: Columbia Books, 1981.Google Scholar
Close, A.C. (Ed.). Washington representatives, 1982 (6th ed.). Washington, D.C.: Columbia Books, 1982.Google Scholar
Conway, M.M.PACs, the new politics, and congressional campaign. In Cigler, A. J. & Loomis, B. A. (Eds.). Interest group politics. Washington, D.C.: Congressional Quarterly Press, 1983.Google Scholar
Dexter, L. A.How organizations are represented in Washington. Indianapolis: Bobbs-Merrill, 1969.Google Scholar
Eulau, H.The role of the representative: some empirical observations on the theory of Edmund Burke. American Political Science Review, 1959, 53, 742756.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Eulau, H.Changing views of representation. In de Sola Pool, I. (Ed.). Contemporary political science: toward empirical theory. New York: McGraw-Hill, 1967.Google Scholar
Gamson, W.A.The strategy of social protest. Homewood, I11.: Dorsey, 1975.Google Scholar
Gilbert, C.E.Operational doctrines of representation. American Political Science Review, 1963, 57, 604618.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Gusfield, J. R.Symbolic crusade: status politics and the American temperance movement. Urbana, Ill.: University of Illinois Press, 1963.Google Scholar
Hagan, C. B.The group in a political science. In Young, R. (Ed.). Approach to the study of politics. Evanston, Ill.: Northwestern University Press, 1958.Google Scholar
Handler, E., & Mulkern, J. R.Business in politics: campaign strategies of corporate political action committees. Lexington, Mass.: Lexington Books, 1982.Google Scholar
Helyar, J.Capital's service sector gives area economy a safety net. Wall Street Journal, 04 28, 1981.Google Scholar
Hirschman, A.O.Exit, voice and loyalty. Cambridge, Mass.: Harvard University Press, 1970.Google Scholar
Key, V. O. Jr.Politics, parties and pressure groups (5th ed.). New York: Crowell, 1964.Google Scholar
King, L. R.The Washington lobbyists for higher education. Lexington, Mass.: Lexington, 1975.Google Scholar
Krislov, S.The Amicus Curiae brief: from friendship to advocacy. Yale Law Journal, 1963, 72, 694721.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Maclver, R. M.Interests. In Seligman, E. R. A. (Ed.). Encyclopedia of the social sciences. New York: Macmillan, 1932.Google Scholar
Madison, C.Is Japan trying to buy Washington or just do business capital style? Washington: National Journal, 10 9, 1982.Google Scholar
Malbin, M. J. (Ed.). Parties, interest groups, and campaign finance laws. Washington, D.C.: American Enterprise Institute, 1980.Google Scholar
McCarthy, J. D., & Zald, M. N.The trend of social movments. In J. D. McCarthy & M. D. Zald, America: professionalization and resource mobilization. Morristown, N.J.: General Learning Press, 1973.Google Scholar
McConnell, G.Private power and American democracy. New York: Knopf, 1966.Google Scholar
McFarland, A. S.Public interest lobbies: decision making on energy. Washington, D.C.: American Enterprise Institute, 1976.Google Scholar
Milbrath, L. W.The Washington lobbyists. Chicago: Rand McNally, 1963.Google Scholar
Moe, T. M.The organization of interests. Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 1980.Google Scholar
Olson, M.J.The logic of collective action. Cambridge, Mass.: Harvard University Press, 1965.Google Scholar
Pitkin, H.F.The concept of representation. Berkeley: University of California Press, 1967.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Proliferating political action committees. National Journal, 01 29, 1983.Google Scholar
Radosh, R.American labor and U.S. foreign policy. New York: Random House, 1969.Google Scholar
Salisbury, R.H.An exchange theory of interest groups. Midwest Journal of Political Science, 1969, 13, 132.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Salisbury, R. H.Interest groups. In Polsby, N. & Greenstein, F. (Eds.). Handbook of political science. Reading, Mass.: Addison-Wesley, 1975.Google Scholar
Salisbury, R. H.Why no corporatism in America. In Schmitter, P. C. & Lehmbruch, G. (Eds.). Trends toward corporatist Intermediation. Beverly Hills, Calif.: Sage, 1979.Google Scholar
Salisbury, R. H.Are interest groups morbific forces. Paper presented to the Conference Group on Political Economy of Advanced Industrial Societies. Washington, D.C., 1980.Google Scholar
Schattschneider, E. E.The semi-sovereign people. New York: Holt, Rinehart and Winston, 1960.Google Scholar
Schlesinger, A.M.Paths to the present. New York: Macmillan, 1949.Google Scholar
Sorauf, F.J.The wall of separation. Princeton, N.J.: Princeton University Press, 1976.Google Scholar
Teeley, S. E.Trade associations are shrinking with economy. Washington Post, 01 31, 1983, p. Bl.Google Scholar
Truman, D.B.The governmental process. New York: Knopf, 1951.Google Scholar
Vogel, D.Lobbying the corporation. New York: Basic Books, 1978.Google Scholar
Wahlke, J.C., Eulau, H., Buchanan, W., & Ferguson, L.C.The legislative system: explorations in legislative behavior. New York: Wiley, 1962.Google Scholar
Walker, J.The origins and maintenance of interest groups in America. American Political Science Review, 1983, 77, 390406.Google Scholar
Wilson, G. K.Unions in American national politics. London: Macmillan, 1977.Google Scholar
Wilson, G. K.Interest groups in the United States. New York: Oxford University Press, 1981.Google Scholar
Wilson, J.Q.Political organizations. New York: Basic Books, 1973.Google Scholar
Ziegler, H., & Baer, M.A.Lobbying: interaction and influence in American state legislatures. Belmont, Calif.: Wadsworth, 1969.Google Scholar
Submit a response

Comments

No Comments have been published for this article.