Hostname: page-component-586b7cd67f-rdxmf Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-11-22T06:17:03.301Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Consolidating Progress: The Selection of Female Ministers in Autocracies and Democracies

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  20 July 2023

JACOB NYRUP*
Affiliation:
University of Oslo, Norway
HIKARU YAMAGISHI*
Affiliation:
Harvard University, United States
STUART BRAMWELL*
Affiliation:
Royal Holloway, University of London, United Kingdom
*
Jacob Nyrup, Associate Professor, Department of Political Science, University of Oslo, Norway, jacob.nyrup@stv.uio.no.
Hikaru Yamagishi, Postdoctoral Fellow, Weatherhead Center for International Affairs, Harvard University, United States, hikaruyamagishi@fas.harvard.edu.
Stuart Bramwell, Postdoctoral Fellow, Department of Politics, International Relations and Philosophy, Royal Holloway, University of London, United Kingdom, stuart.bramwell@rhul.ac.uk.
Rights & Permissions [Opens in a new window]

Abstract

Though governments historically have been a men’s club, women are increasingly gaining access. We argue that democratic institutions are important drivers of women’s inclusion in government. This stems from the rationales of autocratic versus democratic leaders when selecting ministers. Autocrats fear a coup by inner-circle elites, who are mostly men, incentivizing them to assign ministerial positions as co-optation. In contrast, democratic leaders are accountable to the citizenry through elections and must satisfy increasing demands for gender equality. Furthermore, we argue that it is historical experience with democracy that matters, rather than the level, as it takes time to create an even playing field, change attitudes, and generate trust in democracy. To support this, we contribute with the first study using the most comprehensive dataset, WhoGov, on women’s access to cabinets. Overall, we show that democracy is a process that gradually enables women to enter the highest echelons of power.

Type
Research Article
Creative Commons
Creative Common License - CCCreative Common License - BY
This is an Open Access article, distributed under the terms of the Creative Commons Attribution licence (http://creativecommons.org/licenses/by/4.0), which permits unrestricted re-use, distribution and reproduction, provided the original article is properly cited.
Copyright
© The Author(s), 2023. Published by Cambridge University Press on behalf of the American Political Science Association

INTRODUCTION

One of the most remarkable political developments over the last century has been the increase in women who hold political office. At the executive level, the average share of women in cabinets worldwide increased from 1% in 1966 to 23% in 2021. There is, on average, greater gender balance in cabinets in democratic governments than in their autocratic counterparts, but progress has been uneven across time and place (Nyrup and Bramwell Reference Nyrup and Bramwell2020). This raises the question: do democratic institutions aid women in accessing the most important political offices?

The literature has yet to offer a clear answer as to whether democratic institutions support women attaining positions of formal political power. While some scholars see democratization as an opportunity for female advancement in politics and find that democracy promotes women (Arriola and Johnson Reference Arriola and Johnson2014; Lindberg Reference Lindberg2004; Rai Reference Rai1994), others find ambivalent results (Donno and Kreft Reference Donno and Kreft2019; Htun and Weldon Reference Htun and Laurel Weldon2012; Stockemer Reference Stockemer2017; Stockemer and Kchouk Reference Stockemer and Kchouk2017). Others have pointed to the lackluster performance of many emerging democracies and the fact that several autocracies, such as Uganda and Rwanda, lead in the descriptive advancement of women into politics (Bauer Reference Bauer2012; Blankenship and Kubicek Reference Blankenship and Kubicek2018; Donno, Fox, and Kaasik Reference Donno, Fox and Kaasik2021). This article contributes to this discussion by arguing that a country’s historical experience with democratic institutions increases women’s access to government.

The cabinet is a compelling level for comparative analysis relative to other levels of political office. An explanation for the inconclusive results in extant cross-country studies focusing on national legislatures could be the varied role of legislative members across countries. Many autocracies have “rubber-stamp” legislative assemblies where members have limited influence (Bjarnegård and Melander Reference Bjarnegård and Melander2013; Truex Reference Truex2014). On the other hand, cabinet members hold significant decision-making power in most, if not all, countries and thus are more comparable across regimes. Furthermore, cabinets provide a distinct insight into the composition of power in the highest echelons of government. Even when democratic institutional features such as the expansion of the electorate are introduced, cabinets can function as change-resistant, insulated centers of power upholding legacies of social exclusion (Albertus and Menaldo Reference Albertus and Menaldo2018). Lastly, there has been comparatively less research on women’s access to government positions due to, until recently, little available data. We utilize a new dataset, WhoGov, to fill this gap (Nyrup and Bramwell Reference Nyrup and Bramwell2020).

We base our argument on a new theoretical framework of gender and ministerial selection across regime types. Following Norris (Reference Norris1987; Reference Norris and Norris1997), Escobar-Lemmon and Taylor-Robinson (Reference Escobar-Lemmon and Taylor-Robinson2005), and Bego (Reference Bego2014), we divide the cabinet recruitment market into supply and demand dynamics. In this framework, the pressures for and against women’s representation in the cabinet can either come from the preferences or strategic considerations of the government leader (i.e., the demand side) or the gender composition of potential ministerial candidates (i.e., the supply side). We assume that the central goal of leaders is to stay in power. From there, different political regimes shape the ministerial selection incentives of leaders.

For autocratic leaders, staying in power is a game of minimizing threats from their inner circle and outside influences (Geddes, Wright, and Frantz Reference Geddes, Wright and Frantz2018; Svolik Reference Svolik2012). Autocratic leaders fear being overthrown in a coup, leading them to bias cabinet appointments toward inner-circle elites who can potentially form coup coalitions. Inner-circle elites in autocracies are typically drawn from male-dominated organizations that can credibly threaten the leader, such as the military, authoritarian parties, and to a lesser extent, royal families (Gandhi Reference Gandhi2008; Geddes, Wright, and Frantz Reference Geddes, Wright and Frantz2018). As a result, we would expect governments in autocracies to be predominantly male.

For democratic leaders, staying in power is determined by winning elections. These leaders usually choose cabinet ministers from among members of parliament, party members, business leaders, or technocrats with expert knowledge. These professions are more open to change than the elite groups in autocracies, offering women more pathways to power. Furthermore, feminist activists shift public perceptions of legitimacy to incorporate the criteria of women’s political inclusion, inducing leaders to use their power to incorporate more women into the executive (Annesley, Beckwith, and Franceschet Reference Annesley, Beckwith and Franceschet2019; Franceschet, Annesley, and Beckwith Reference Franceschet, Annesley and Beckwith2017). When accountability to the electorate is institutionalized, female politicians provide an electoral advantage for democratic governments (Dolan Reference Dolan2010; Huddy and Terkildsen Reference Huddy and Terkildsen1993; Schwarz and Coppock Reference Schwarz and Coppock2022). Thus, democracies hold more favorable conditions for women’s promotion to cabinet positions through both the public demand for gender-balanced cabinets and the underlying composition of the groups that typically make up the cabinet.

However, these rationales are based on two ideal types of regimes. In reality, most regimes are somewhere in between. Furthermore, when democracy is first implemented, demand and supply forces are tilted to favor the original, male-dominated elite.

On the demand side, feminist mobilization of public support for women’s political inclusion (Annesley, Beckwith, and Franceschet Reference Annesley, Beckwith and Franceschet2019) is a process that gains potency as democratic liberties, such as freedom of expression and freedom of organization, enable women to express their preferences, organize, and connect to networks (Kuran Reference Kuran1997; Rai Reference Rai1994; Wang et al. Reference Wang, Lindenfors, Sundstrom, Jasson, Paxton and Lindberg2017). On the supply side, former authoritarian elites play a significant role after the transition to democracy (Albertus and Menaldo Reference Albertus and Menaldo2018), often securing positions of political power that limit the ability of a new political elite to gain power (Miller Reference Miller2021). In addition, the emergence of a pipeline of qualified women “ministrables” (Annesley, Beckwith, and Franceschet Reference Annesley, Beckwith and Franceschet2019, 212–36) is also gradual. Many women will already have made life choices and arrangements that maximize their personal interests under the previous autocratic regime. Thus, changes may be better observed over time.

Therefore, we argue that the effect of democracy on gender balance in government is better captured as a historical phenomenon taking place over the long run rather than as a level at a given point in time (Gerring et al. Reference Gerring, Knutsen, Maguire, Skaaning, Teorell and Coppedge2020; Gerring, Thacker, and Alfaro Reference Gerring, Thacker and Alfaro2012). As a result, we follow Gerring, Thacker, and Alfaro (Reference Gerring, Thacker and Alfaro2012) in operationalizing democracy as a “stock” variable, in essence adding up the years with which a country has had experience with democracy.

We test our hypothesis using a new dataset of cabinet ministers worldwide, WhoGov, which has yearly data on cabinet compositions from 1966 to 2021 (Nyrup and Bramwell Reference Nyrup and Bramwell2020).Footnote 1 We find that democracies, on average, have approximately twice the share of women in cabinet compared with autocracies. However, using fixed effects, we also show that the pattern of gender balance is not explained by the level of democracy per se. Instead, when we operationalize democracy as a stock variable and thereby as a cumulative process, we find a strong association between democracy and the share of women ministers. The results are robust to a range of extra tests and controls, such as women’s empowerment or the level of development, ruling out the possibility that the results are an artifact of modernization (Lipset Reference Lipset1959).

Furthermore, we test the implications of our model and show that only measures of real electoral competition (such as clean elections) are related to an increase of women in cabinet and that there is no association for more “hollow” measures (such as the mere existence of elections). In addition, we find that the effect sizes are larger for non-OECD countries, poorer countries, and in more recent years, which suggests that our theory better captures developments in countries that tend to receive less attention in the literature. In sum, we show that democratization does not instantly or deterministically empower women. Instead, it is a system that enables more women to enter the highest echelons of power gradually.

The article contributes to the literature on regime types and the study of politics and gender. We leverage a new dataset, WhoGov, which has global data on governments over a 55-year period (Nyrup and Bramwell Reference Nyrup and Bramwell2020), resulting in the most granular analysis of women’s access to governments to date. Our contributions, however, go beyond using a new dataset. There is a rich and ongoing discussion on the advantages of democracy relative to autocracy in areas such as economic growth (Acemoglu et al. Reference Acemoglu, Naidu, Restrepo and Robinson2019; Przeworski et al. Reference Przeworski, Alvarez, Cheibub and Limongi2000) and human development (Gerring, Thacker, and Alfaro Reference Gerring, Thacker and Alfaro2012; Sen Reference Sen2001). We contribute to this literature by arguing that democratic experience is one of the main drivers for allowing women to access political power at the highest levels. This is important not only for descriptive reasons but also for policy outcomes. Female politicians tend to care more about gender equality and gendered public goods (Chattopadhyay and Duflo Reference Chattopadhyay and Duflo2004; Lovenduski and Norris Reference Lovenduski and Norris2003), be less corrupt when in public office (Bauhr, Charron, and Wängnerud Reference Bauhr, Charron and Wängnerud2019; Dollar, Fisman, and Gatti Reference Dollar, Fisman and Gatti2001), are more likely to fulfill policy promises (Homola Reference Homola2021), and are linked to economic growth (Dahlum, Knutsen, and Mechkova Reference Dahlum, Knutsen and Mechkova2022). Furthermore, research shows that female political leaders inspire political interest among young women (Campbell and Wolbrecht Reference Campbell and Wolbrecht2006) and empower female legislators (Blumenau Reference Blumenau2021; Wahman, Frantzeskakis, and Yildirim Reference Wahman, Frantzeskakis and Yildirim2021).

PREVIOUS RESEARCH ON THE SELECTION OF FEMALE POLITICIANS ACROSS AUTOCRACIES AND DEMOCRACIES

Does democracy promote women into holding political office? History does not offer a clear answer. From ancient Athens (Osborne Reference Osborne2010) to early modern democracies in Europe, and the Americas (Caraway Reference Caraway2004), women were initially barred from formally participating in politics. However, women made significant gains with the opening of political forums by the end of the Second World War (Paxton Reference Paxton2000).

The advancement of gender balance in politics has not been a solely democratic feature. While democratic institutions sustain the advancement of women through solidifying norms of gender balance for democratic legitimacy (Annesley, Beckwith, and Franceschet Reference Annesley, Beckwith and Franceschet2019), factors such as communist ideology (Harsch Reference Harsch and Smith2014) and external pressure from international institutions have led to autocratic regimes extending positions of power to women as well (Donno, Fox, and Kaasik Reference Donno, Fox and Kaasik2021; Fallon, Swiss, and Viterna Reference Fallon, Swiss and Viterna2012; Kroeger and Kang Reference Kroeger and Kang2022). The role of women in autocratic cabinets has been varied: while dictatorships drew the political elite heavily from male-dominated organizations such as the military (Gandhi Reference Gandhi2008; Geddes, Wright, and Frantz Reference Geddes, Wright and Frantz2018), the rise of electoral or competitive authoritarianism has seen an increase in female political participation while at the same time witnessing an eschewing of fair elections (Bauer Reference Bauer2012; Blankenship and Kubicek Reference Blankenship and Kubicek2018; Donno, Fox, and Kaasik Reference Donno, Fox and Kaasik2021; Kroeger and Kang Reference Kroeger and Kang2022). Thus, it is unclear whether democracy promotes women into cabinet.

One reason for this may be significant variation in how democracy and women’s political empowerment are discussed and operationalized. Regime type is either operationalized as a binary category (e.g., Stockemer Reference Stockemer2017) or as existing on a continuum that runs from ideal-type autocracies to ideal-type democracies (e.g., Arriola and Johnson Reference Arriola and Johnson2014). While many studies have posited that democracy impacts women’s representation, whether positively or negatively, autocracy is often treated as a residual category rather than a distinct political regime (e.g., Paxton, Hughes, and Painter Reference Paxton, Hughes and Painter2010). We address this lacuna by theorizing differences in elite-level political competition between the two regimes, as dealt with extensively in the political regimes literature (e.g., Geddes, Wright, and Frantz Reference Geddes, Wright and Frantz2018; Wintrobe Reference Wintrobe2000).

While many scholars of democratization are cognizant of the fact that empowering hitherto marginalized groups such as women is unlikely to happen overnight (e.g., Dahl Reference Dahl1971; Gerring, Thacker, and Alfaro Reference Gerring, Thacker and Alfaro2012; Rai Reference Rai1994), many studies on women’s representation assume that the effect of democracy is the same in newly democratizing countries as it is in consolidated democracies (e.g., Arriola and Johnson Reference Arriola and Johnson2014; Stockemer Reference Stockemer2017). By contrast, studies that treat democracy as a time-varying phenomenon find more consistently positive and significant results (Fallon, Swiss, and Viterna Reference Fallon, Swiss and Viterna2012; Jacob, Scherpereel, and Adams Reference Jacob, Scherpereel and Adams2014; Paxton, Hughes, and Painter Reference Paxton, Hughes and Painter2010). We provide theoretical context as to why this may be the case, positing that path dependencies from the previous authoritarian regime exist, which structurally hinder the emergence of new female elites.

While we locate our contribution in the gender and political power-sharing literature, our theoretical framework intersects with deeper theoretical insights found within feminist insights on gender, critical views of democratization, and epistemic justice (Fricker Reference Fricker2007). We contend, much like Rai (Reference Rai1994), that democracy helps women identify exclusion from power as an injustice that, consequently, needs to be addressed through political processes which aim to dismantle entrenched patriarchal norms. Insights from the regional- and country-level studies of democracies have convincingly shown the importance of government formation processes and elite actors (Krook and O’Brien Reference Krook and O’Brien2012), and how democratic competition for legitimacy can gradually build a “concrete floor” of gender balance that is difficult to reverse once established (Annesley, Beckwith, and Franceschet Reference Annesley, Beckwith and Franceschet2019; Davis Reference Davis1997).

Generally, political office-holding at the national level can be distinguished between two branches or levels of representation: legislative and executive. While both forms of political power are essential to study, we propose that the executive level is a better comparative measure of women’s political empowerment for two reasons. First, cabinets play a more consistent role across political regimes. Legislatures often vary dramatically in the level of autonomy enjoyed by the executive, with some acting as rubber stamps for decisions made by the executive, whereas others have the power to remove the political leader (Bjarnegård and Melander Reference Bjarnegård and Melander2013; Truex Reference Truex2014). Second, cabinet appointments can be seen as more prized by political elites when compared with legislative seats. The individuals appointed to the cabinet draw considerable public attention, make important decisions, and, in most cases, manage large budgets.

However, due to limited data, econometric analyses of cabinet appointments are less developed than those of legislative seats. As a result, such analyses are either purely cross-sectional (Krook and O’Brien Reference Krook and O’Brien2012), collected at 5-year or irregular intervals (Jacob, Scherpereel, and Adams Reference Jacob, Scherpereel and Adams2014; Stockemer Reference Stockemer2017), limited to specific regions (Arriola and Johnson Reference Arriola and Johnson2014; Claveria Reference Claveria2014; Escobar-Lemmon and Taylor-Robinson Reference Escobar-Lemmon and Taylor-Robinson2005), include only democracies (Claveria Reference Claveria2014; Escobar-Lemmon and Taylor-Robinson Reference Escobar-Lemmon and Taylor-Robinson2005), or focus on specific portfolios (Barnes and O’Brien Reference Barnes and O’Brien2018). By contrast, we leverage yearly data on a globally representative sample of countries. In doing so, we can make more credible cross-sectional and temporal inferences about the relationship between democracy and female participation in cabinets compared with previous studies.

A THEORY OF GENDERED CABINET SELECTION ACROSS POLITICAL REGIMES

Despite the far-reaching research on women in politics, we have limited knowledge about whether democracy supports women’s access into government. We address this research gap by proposing and testing an original theoretical framework that argues that democratic institutions, over time, tend to foster more opportunities for the inclusion of women in the cabinet.

The gender composition of cabinets is determined by the processes of supply and demand, as proposed by previous studies of ministerial candidate selection (e.g., Escobar-Lemmon and Taylor-Robinson Reference Escobar-Lemmon and Taylor-Robinson2005; Norris Reference Norris1987; Reference Norris and Norris1997). The demand side is defined by the incentives of the leader, who selects the cabinet. The supply side consists of the pool of potential ministers.

The primary objective of the leader is to survive in office (De Mesquita et al. Reference De Mesquita, Smith, Siverson and Morrow2005).Footnote 2 However, the modality of political competition fundamentally differs in autocracies compared with democracies (Svolik Reference Svolik2012), creating different incentives for autocratic and democratic leaders.

Using a Dahlian approach, we define democracy as a political regime where contestation in the form of free and fair elections occurs in the context of widespread public participation (Dahl Reference Dahl1971). This shapes the composition of the groups to whom the political elite are held accountable. The political elite in autocracies is accountable to a narrow winning coalition with whom they share power (De Mesquita et al. Reference De Mesquita, Smith, Siverson and Morrow2005; Svolik Reference Svolik2012), whereas the political elite in democracies is accountable to their party, coalition partners, and, ultimately, the broader electorate, thus adding the importance of the general public’s demands (Annesley, Beckwith, and Franceschet Reference Annesley, Beckwith and Franceschet2019; Krook and O’Brien Reference Krook and O’Brien2012; Randall Reference Randall1982; Strom, Budge, and Laver Reference Strom, Budge and Laver1994; Tremblay Reference Tremblay2012).

To contextualize our argument, we start the discussion with two ideal types of regime: (1) an autocracy, where elections either are not held or are so flawed that the results are essentially meaningless, causing the opposition to have no institutionalized influence, and (2) a democracy with free and fair elections, universal suffrage, freedom of expression, and a functioning opposition.

The Inclusion of Women in Cabinets under Autocracy

We start with the ideal-type autocracy. Since elections only serve as pro forma acclamations, political competition is characterized by an evolving balance of power under conditions of anarchy (Svolik Reference Svolik2012). Therefore, the primary threats to the ruler come through extra-legal methods, either from the regime in the form of coups or from the broader civil society in the form of revolutions (De Mesquita et al. Reference De Mesquita, Smith, Siverson and Morrow2005; Geddes, Wright, and Frantz Reference Geddes, Wright and Frantz2014; Svolik Reference Svolik2012).

We expect the demand for women in cabinet to be low in autocracies. This is not to say that the underlying gender-related attitudes of the general public are antagonistic toward women. Instead, private attitudes are effectively crowded out by other issues that relate more directly to the leader’s survival. Therefore, autocrats must first and foremost appoint individuals who can help them survive threats.

Research in authoritarian politics has firmly established that coups by elites represent the most common threat that autocrats face (Svolik Reference Svolik2012). To keep the elite under control, the autocrat has an incentive to appoint loyal individuals (Egorov and Sonin Reference Egorov and Sonin2011) and co-opt potentially dangerous groups into organizations such as the cabinet, legislatures, and the party (Arriola, DeVaro, and Meng Reference Arriola, DeVaro and Meng2021; Arriola and Johnson Reference Arriola and Johnson2014; Blaydes Reference Blaydes2010; De Mesquita et al. Reference De Mesquita, Smith, Siverson and Morrow2005; Gandhi Reference Gandhi2008; Lust-Okar Reference Lust-Okar2006).

The autocrat can avoid a revolution by using repression (Gerschewski Reference Gerschewski2013). This causes them to rely on people who can keep “subversive” parts of the population subdued (Scharpf and Gläßel Reference Scharpf and Gläßel2020). This often involves using violence on a mass scale to subdue real or perceived enemies of the revolution (Kim Reference Kim2018). Due to historical processes and discrimination, men may be more readily available to occupy positions based on perceptions of credible threats of violence, making them more suitable (in the eyes of the leader) for governance in a repressive regime.

By contrast, organizations in which women have been more prominent, such as popular movements (Beckwith Reference Beckwith2001), typically exert power through nonviolent means and so cannot ransom the autocrat to the same degree. While we do not claim that women are intrinsically less violent than men, we contend that social pressures tend to restrict women from using violent tactics to achieve political ends to a greater degree than men (Best, Shair-Rosenfield, and Wood Reference Best, Shair-Rosenfield and Wood2019). Without being able to threaten violence credibly, we posit that women will be unable to extract concessions from the leader under an ideal-type autocracy. Additionally, public feminist movements are less prevalent to begin with in autocracies, given preference falsification of private attitudes in the face of social pressures (Kuran Reference Kuran1997).

Nonetheless, autocrats can have reasons to pick women to serve in the cabinet. They may want to positively signal to international donors, lenders, and investors by appointing women (Donno, Fox, and Kaasik Reference Donno, Fox and Kaasik2021; Fallon, Swiss, and Viterna Reference Fallon, Swiss and Viterna2012; Kroeger and Kang Reference Kroeger and Kang2022). Furthermore, as we argue later on, autocrats will have incentives to pick female leaders from popular movements to incorporate those groups into their support coalition if the regime evolves toward a more competitive form of authoritarianism. Despite these reasons, there is little pressure on the autocrat to select female ministers on the whole.

The main sources of potential cabinet ministers in autocracies are usually groups of inner-circle elites since these groups have resources and are willing to use violence to unseat the leader through a coup. Inner-circle elites typically come from the military, the ruling party, or the royal family (Barnes and O’Brien Reference Barnes and O’Brien2018; Gandhi Reference Gandhi2008; Geddes, Wright, and Frantz Reference Geddes, Wright and Frantz2018), all groups that are predominantly male. The military is the clearest example of an organization in which men dominate the upper echelons and upon which the autocrat relies to keep the population in line through repression (Barnes and O’Brien Reference Barnes and O’Brien2018; Svolik Reference Svolik2012).

Autocratic parties are designed to extend autocratic power and durability (Geddes Reference Geddes1999). They can do so by improving elite cohesion, monitoring citizens, providing patronage, co-opting opposition groups, and funneling state benefits to the elite (Magaloni and Kricheli Reference Magaloni and Kricheli2010; Miller Reference Miller2020; Slater Reference Slater2010). Therefore, they serve a very different purpose compared with parties in democracies where they are vehicles for electoral competition, meaning that parties need to be responsive and help mobilize voters (Aldrich Reference Aldrich1995; Downs Reference Downs1957). As a result, autocratic parties are less susceptible to change, and promotion within the party will be based on different criteria such as loyalty to the leader, willingness to commit violence, participation in corruption, and, to a lesser degree, competence (Egorov and Sonin Reference Egorov and Sonin2011; Scharpf and Gläßel Reference Scharpf and Gläßel2020). Autocratic parties have, therefore, in many cases devolved into de facto old boys’ clubs. While women can join authoritarian parties, they are often placed in legislative positions with little real influence or pigeonholed into gendered roles (Bjarnegård and Melander Reference Bjarnegård and Melander2013; Fallon, Swiss, and Viterna Reference Fallon, Swiss and Viterna2012; Harsch Reference Harsch and Smith2014; Stockemer Reference Stockemer2017; Tripp Reference Tripp2001).

Dynastic ties have been shown to help women access political office (Baturo and Gray Reference Baturo and Gray2018). This could be a factor in monarchies, where bloodline trump social forces, and the supply pool, therefore, are primarily the leader’s family. However, most of the world’s remaining monarchies are located in Middle Eastern countries (Gerring et al. Reference Gerring, Wig, Veenendaal, Weitzel, Teorell and Kikuta2021), where many regimes actively promote highly patriarchal norms, with some even continuing to bar women from public office at the turn of the century (Norris and Inglehart Reference Norris and Inglehart2001). As a result, it is reasonable to assume that the supply pools of ministerial candidates in autocracies are overwhelmingly male.

The Inclusion of Women in Cabinets in Democracies

In the ideal-type democracy, power is transferred according to the results of free and fair elections, and accountability is institutionalized (e.g., Dahl Reference Dahl1971).Footnote 3 Therefore, democratic leaders need to pick cabinet members who can contribute toward re-election, which may pressure the leader to select more women for four reasons.

First, the establishment of civil liberties that accompany democratization provides opportunities to politicize women’s interests. The full inclusion of women into formal democratic institutions requires a shift whereby women’s interests, previously constrained in the private sphere, are imagined as a matter of rights in the public political sphere (Rai Reference Rai1994). Civil rights counter the social pressures that lead to the falsification of true preferences (Kuran Reference Kuran1997), enabling feminist organizing (Wang et al. Reference Wang, Lindenfors, Sundstrom, Jasson, Paxton and Lindberg2017).

Second, the entrepreneurial force that materializes this fuel of (less organized) preferences is feminist activists (Annesley, Beckwith, and Franceschet Reference Annesley, Beckwith and Franceschet2019). Scholars studying cabinet selection processes in democracies demonstrate how gender in cabinets gains electoral salience as gender balance gets established as part of public perceptions of representational legitimacy (Annesley, Beckwith, and Franceschet Reference Annesley, Beckwith and Franceschet2019; Franceschet, Annesley, and Beckwith Reference Franceschet, Annesley and Beckwith2017, 235). While we do not suggest that democracies deterministically increase female cabinet ministers, we argue akin to Annesley, Beckwith, and Franceschet (Reference Annesley, Beckwith and Franceschet2019) that democratic elections establish “concrete floors” of cabinet participation through which incumbent and opposition leaders face punishment at the polls should they fall short. Moreover, as Annesley, Beckwith, and Franceschet (Reference Annesley, Beckwith and Franceschet2019) and other authors (e.g., Bauer and Darkwah Reference Bauer and Darkwah2022) also demonstrate, this concrete floor tends to rise as contenders for office propose more gender-inclusive cabinets. While democracies may be limited in enabling constituent principals to monitor their representative agents, they can facilitate the struggle for collective principles such as inclusion (Hayward Reference Hayward, Benhabib, Shapiro and Petranovich2007).

Third, once selectors use their power to include more women in cabinets, further electoral benefits arise in appointing women.Footnote 4 Women make up around 50% of the population in all countries and, as such, constitute the single biggest national cross-cutting cleavage (Teele Reference Teele2018). A group of studies examining gender effects in more generalized candidate choice scenarios has revealed that female candidates and politicians are just as favored or slightly more favored relative to their male counterparts regardless of the gender of the respondent (e.g., Bridgewater and Nagel Reference Bridgewater and Nagel2020; Dassonneville, Quinlan, and McAllister Reference Dassonneville, Quinlan and McAllister2021; Schwarz and Coppock Reference Schwarz and Coppock2022). Furthermore, women are perceived to be more competent in areas relating to social policy (Dolan Reference Dolan2010; Huddy and Terkildsen Reference Huddy and Terkildsen1993). A large body of research further suggests that significant differences in policy preferences exist between men and women (e.g., Aidt and Dallal Reference Aidt and Dallal2008; Kittilson Reference Kittilson2011) and that social policy becomes more balanced between these competing preferences when more women attain positions of political power (Atchison Reference Atchison2015; Clayton and Zetterberg Reference Clayton and Zetterberg2018; Kittilson Reference Kittilson2011). All this leads gender-parity cabinets to receive public praise and positive media coverage (Beckwith and Franceschet Reference Beckwith and Franceschet2022).

Fourth, the portfolio specificity of cabinet positions can insulate the executive arena from some of the demand-side social expectations that hold women back in arenas such as the legislature (e.g., Dolan Reference Dolan2010; Huddy and Terkildsen Reference Huddy and Terkildsen1993; Teele, Kalla, and Rosenbluth Reference Teele, Kalla and Rosenbluth2018). If gender-based social roles operate as a heuristic in the absence of candidate quality information (e.g., Alexander and Andersen Reference Alexander and Andersen1993), the specification of portfolio and expertise in cabinet positions may dampen the relevance of social roles, stereotypes, and statistical discrimination. In fact, examining party leaders, Dassonneville, Quinlan, and McAllister (Reference Dassonneville, Quinlan and McAllister2021) find that female party leaders are more favored than their male counterparts among experienced politicians.

Overall, there are substantial reasons to expect that democratic leaders have incentives to appoint women to the cabinet. This will particularly be the case where traditional gender norms and associated constraints have declined.

We also contend that democratic institutions foster conditions that result in an increased supply of female cabinet members. Cabinet ministers in democracies are usually selected from among members of parliament, party members, business leaders, or technocrats with expert knowledge (Escobar-Lemmon and Taylor-Robinson Reference Escobar-Lemmon and Taylor-Robinson2016). Although men have traditionally dominated these groups, they are more open to change than elite groups in autocracies, offering women more pathways to power. As a result, democracies are better than their autocratic counterparts at capturing developments at a mass level.

While democratic parties vary substantially to the degree to which they promote women (Caul Reference Caul1999), all significant parties are vote-seeking organizations (Aldrich Reference Aldrich1995; Downs Reference Downs1957).Footnote 5 Consequently, we expect them to be more open toward change, easier to join, and more responsive toward pressure for including underrepresented candidates compared with their autocratic counterparts. In short, we expect that they will include women to greater degrees.

Along with joining a political party, women can also be assigned cabinet appointments based on expertise in a given subject and can thus be drawn from academia, the civil service, or third-sector charities (e.g., Tripp Reference Tripp2001). Over the last decades, we have seen women increasingly access the labor force and, in many places, match or surpass the educational attainment of men. We also see developments at the elite level. Countries around the world are electing an increasing number of women to their parliaments (Wängnerud Reference Wängnerud2009) and women are increasingly obtaining leadership positions in the public sector, business, and academia (Huang et al. Reference Huang, Gates, Sinatra and Barabási2020). Therefore, there is a larger share of women in the supply pool of candidates in democracies relative to their autocratic counterparts, particularly in recent years.Footnote 6

Taken together, democracies hold more favorable conditions for women’s promotion to cabinet positions both through the voter-derived demand for balanced cabinets and the underlying composition of societal groups that typically make up the cabinet. Our main points are summarized in Table 1.

Table 1. Demand and Supply Forces in Cabinet Selection of Female Ministers

Transition, Consolidation, and Gender Equality

The previous sections argued that the nature of political competition in democracies should result in higher levels of female participation in government relative to autocracies. However, autocracies are increasingly adopting democratic institutions, blurring the line between the two regime types, meaning that the ideal types used to construct our theoretical argument rarely exist. Instead, we are seeing countries moving along a continuum (Levitsky and Way Reference Levitsky and Way2010). Furthermore, most countries have not been democratic throughout, but have instead experienced transitions from autocracy. While democratization opens a path for women to access political offices that were essentially built in their absence, new democracies and old democracies are not the same. Instead, new democracies have path dependencies from previous authoritarian regimes which hold back increased gender equality in government. We point to three factors that hold women back in new democracies.

First, a history of autocracy can depress the number of women in the pipeline to power (Lawless and Fox Reference Lawless and Fox2005). This is particularly challenging in new democracies where existing structures and patriarchal social norms may have stunted women’s potential political careers (Lee and McClean Reference Lee and McClean2022). In the early days of democracy, women will have rationally made life choices and arrangements that maximize their interests under the old, male-centric regime. Women might have falsified private preferences due to repression (Kuran Reference Kuran1997), calculated that pursuing a political career is too risky, and accrued sunk costs. In addition, women may not be connected to the political networks that serve as pathways to power, and political entrepreneurs may not approach women if they are not a part of the political system (Goyal Reference Goyal2019). However, certain components of democracies can decrease the costs facing women. For example, freedom of expression and freedom of organization can give women opportunities to speak about their preferences and drop pretenses of preference falsification. Moreover, continued experience of democracy generates more viability and trust in the institution, resulting in more women opting for careers in politics. In addition, democratization and political change enable women’s organizations to push for greater political representation at lower levels (Hughes and Tripp Reference Hughes and Tripp2015). Thus, although women often play a significant role in democratization and women’s organization is pivotal in putting pressure on the authoritarian regime, men tend to have a head start in the pipeline to power after democratization.

Second, authoritarian elites may cling to power despite democratization. Authoritarian elites often play a significant role in writing national constitutions before transitions occur in such a way that political competition is limited, albeit legally (Albertus and Menaldo Reference Albertus and Menaldo2018). Furthermore, authoritarian elites also secure positions of political power which limits the ability of a new political elite to gain power (Loxton and Power Reference Loxton and Power2021; Miller Reference Miller2021). A regime transition may not necessarily entail a transition of members of the elite, at least in the short run. Nevertheless, as authoritarian influence in executive politics wanes, the previous elite may give way to a new and potentially more gender-balanced elite.

Third, as the relative proportion of women increases in the pool of qualified ministerial candidates, a dynamic previously perceived as women’s underrepresentation may be reappraised as the overrepresentation of relatively less talented men (Murray Reference Murray2014). At the same time, voters may find it easier to punish the overrepresentation of less qualified men when the alternative (more qualified female candidates) becomes apparent. Furthermore, establishing and elevating concrete floors may reduce the political knowledge gap between men and women, particularly among younger cohorts less affected by authoritarian legacies (Dassonneville and McAllister Reference Dassonneville and McAllister2018), creating a virtuous cycle of younger voters challenging male overrepresentation in politics to a greater extent than voters of previous generations.

Consequently, democracy is, in the light of our research question, better captured as a historical phenomenon, taking place over the long run rather than as a level defined cross-sectionally (Gerring et al. Reference Gerring, Knutsen, Maguire, Skaaning, Teorell and Coppedge2020; Gerring, Thacker, and Alfaro Reference Gerring, Thacker and Alfaro2012). Thus, we expect the closest association between regime type and gender balance in cabinets to be in a country’s historical experience of democracy. As a result, we follow Gerring, Thacker, and Alfaro (Reference Gerring, Thacker and Alfaro2012) in operationalizing democracy as a “stock” variable, in essence adding up the years for which a country has had the experience of democracy. In summary, our main hypothesis is the following:

Hypothesis: When countries gain more experience of democracy, the proportion of women in cabinets will increase.

DATA AND EMPIRICAL METHODS

Measuring Women’s Representation in Cabinet

To test whether democracies select more women than autocracies, we use a new dataset on cabinet members, WhoGov (Nyrup and Bramwell Reference Nyrup and Bramwell2020). The dataset contains detailed information on cabinet members for every July in the period of 1966–2021 in all countries with a population of more than four hundred thousand citizens. In total, the dataset contains yearly information on 56,063 cabinet members in 177 countries, adding up to 8,814 country years, although not all are included throughout the analysis due to missingness on other variables. In addition to gender, the dataset includes information on the type of portfolio, enabling us to look at whether women gain access to high-prestige cabinet positions.

Throughout the analysis, we primarily rely on the share of female cabinet members as the dependent variable. To construct this measure, we select all full-ranking cabinet members and calculate the female share for every country in every year. Thus, we exclude junior ministers, the leader herself, and noncabinet officials when constructing the measure.

While the theory focuses on the share of female ministers, we triangulate our results using two alternative measures of female representation that are sensitive to the importance of the different ministries. Thereby, we are able to show that women are also qualitatively assigned more power in democracies.

First, we calculate the share of high-prestige ministerial posts occupied by women. We use the classification included in WhoGov as a baseline. Here, portfolios are divided into three levels. High-prestige portfolios are positions distinguished in terms of their visibility and significant control over policy. The minister of defense, finance, foreign affairs, and home/interior are included in this category. This also includes the deputy prime minister and, in presidential systems, the prime minister. Ministries that control significant resources, but have lesser status, are classified as medium prestige. These are, for example, agriculture, education, and transportation. Lastly, low-prestige positions are characterized by less resources and refer to ministries like youth, culture, and sports.Footnote 7 We make some exceptions to the general classification. For example, the minister of natural resources is considered highly prestigious in OPEC+ countries (including former members of OPEC). For more details on the coding, see Appendix A of the Supplementary Material. If the same person controls multiple portfolios or ministries, we only include the most prestigious position.

Lastly, we create a weighted share of female ministers. We give high-prestige portfolios a score of 3, medium-prestige portfolios a score of 2, and low-prestige a score of 1. Then we add all scores that are held by women in a given year and divide it by the total sum for a cabinet in a given year. An example is shown in Appendix B of the Supplementary Material.

Measuring Democracy

There are many indexes of democracy and the choice of an index can be important for results (Gerring et al. Reference Gerring, Knutsen, Maguire, Skaaning, Teorell and Coppedge2020; Munck and Verkuilen Reference Munck and Verkuilen2002). We rely on the V-Dem project’s Polyarchy measure, which is based on Dahl (Reference Dahl1971) and has five components that are combined into the Polyarchy scale, which ranges from 0 (most autocratic) to 1 (most democratic). We choose this measure because it has broad coverage (covering the same period as WhoGov, 1966–2021), distinguishes between democracies and autocracies based on both the contestation and participation criteria, is continuous (since our theory perceives regime types as levels rather than binary categories), is comparatively transparent, and is gathered in a rigorous manner (Teorell et al. Reference Teorell, Coppedge, Lindberg and Skaaning2019). Furthermore, we can deconstruct the measure, allowing us to look at different components of democracy.

To ensure that our results are not driven by the choice of democracy index, we triangulate the main findings using one additional continuous measure of democracy, namely Polity (Marshall, Gurr, and Jaggers Reference Marshall, Gurr and Jaggers2019), and two binary measures, namely Boix, Miller and Rosato (Reference Boix, Miller and Rosato2013) and the Democracy-Dictatorship Index (Cheibub, Gandhi, and Vreeland Reference Cheibub, Gandhi and Vreeland2010). The results are almost identical and can be found in Appendix C of the Supplementary Material.

To test our theory, we operationalize democracy both as a level and as a stock. Similarly to Gerring, Thacker, and Alfaro (Reference Gerring, Thacker and Alfaro2012), we create the stock measure of democracy by summing up each country’s score from 1900 (or, if the country gained independence after the year 1900, the first year) to the given year, applying an annual depreciation rate. We mainly rely on a depreciation rate of 95%, but vary it to show that the results are consistent.Footnote 8 Substantively, the stock variable implies that a country’s stock of democracy stretches back over time but that recent years receive more weight than distant years. We standardize the stock variable to a bound from 0 to 1 to ease interpretation and comparability. Thus, a score of 1 or close to 1 represents countries with the most democratic history, such as Sweden or Denmark, whereas the countries with a low stock of democracy, such as North Korea or Eritrea, get a score of 0 or close to 0. In Appendix D of the Supplementary Material, we provide simulations to give the reader an impression of how the stock of democracy varies dependent on the depreciation rate.

Estimation

The empirical analysis consists of both descriptive statistics and time-series cross-national estimations in which we regress the measures of female representation on measures of democracy, along with controls and fixed effects. We mainly focus on the determinants of the within-country variation over time in the share of female ministers, w, in country c at date t using a linear model. The estimated equation is

(1) $$ \begin{array}{rl}{w}_{ct}=\theta {d}_{ct-1}+\gamma {x}_{ct-1}+{\mu}_c+{\alpha}_t+{\eta}_{ct},& \end{array} $$

where $ {w}_{ct} $ is the share of female ministers in country c at year t. The main independent variable of interest is the lagged measure of democracy denoted by $ {d}_{ct-1} $ . $ {\mu}_c $ is a country-fixed effect, $ {\alpha}_t $ is a year dummy, $ \gamma {x}_{ct-1} $ are other time-variant controls lagged by 1 year, and $ {\eta}_{ct} $ is the error term. We cluster the standard errors by country to allow for arbitrary within-country correlations in the errors.

By including country and year dummy variables in all specifications, we control for fixed country characteristics, such as history and culture, which might affect the share of women in government, and global macro-trends, such as rising levels of women’s representation. In addition, we include a battery of controls. These are discussed and presented in the analysis. We refer to Appendix B of the Supplementary Material for a detailed description of each variable, Appendix E for links to all datasets used in the analysis, and Appendix F for descriptive statistics on all variables used in the analysis.

DO DEMOCRACIES SELECT MORE FEMALE MINISTERS?

Figure 1 shows the share of women in government over time divided by regime type using the binary measure provided by Boix, Miller and Rosato (Reference Boix, Miller and Rosato2013). In 1966, only 1% of cabinet members were women across both regime types, but the share of women has steadily increased since. This is particularly the case in democracies where more than a quarter of all ministers were female in 2020. The relative increase in the share of female ministers in democracies is reflected in the bottom panel of Figure 1, which shows the difference in the share of female ministers between democracies and autocracies. The gap has increased from less than 1 percentage point in 1966 to more than 10 percentage points in 2020. The growing disparity between regime types indicates that democracies are better at capturing developments favoring women at the elite level.

Figure 1. Trends in the Share of Women in Cabinet

In the bottom part of Figure 1, we use a trichotomous regime rating that divides regimes into electoral autocracies (e.g., regimes that allow flawed multiparty elections), closed autocracies (e.g., regimes without multiparty elections), and electoral democracies (Bjørnskov and Rode Reference Bjørnskov and Rode2020; Cheibub, Gandhi, and Vreeland Reference Cheibub, Gandhi and Vreeland2010). Research has shown that electoral institutions in autocracies can be important for outcomes such as economic growth and human development (Gandhi Reference Gandhi2008; Miller Reference Miller2015). We find that electoral autocracies have higher levels of female cabinet participation than closed autocracies after 1990 but at lower levels than democracies. This indicates that if ordinary citizens participate in selecting their leaders in some way, then those leaders, to some degree, need to demonstrate that they represent a significant cross-section of the population to justify their rule. Therefore, and in line with our theory, pressure to select more women in cabinet has a larger impact on the share of women in cabinet in electoral autocracies than in closed autocracies.

However, the descriptive analysis does not tell us whether more women are included in cabinet as a function of democracy or whether some countries inherently are both more democratic and have a higher degree of gender equality due to other unaccounted-for factors. Hence, we utilize the panel structure of the data to investigate further the relationship between democracy and women’s representation in government.

Democratization and the Proportion of Women in Government

Figure 2 plots the proportion of women in cabinet, the level of polyarchy, and the stock of polyarchy in 20 countries that have democratized since 1966. The countries are selected to secure diversity in geography, time of democratization, and prior type of authoritarian regime. In many countries, for example, Argentina, Bulgaria, and Indonesia, we see a rapid increase in the polyarchy score but a comparatively slow increase in both the stock of polyarchy and the proportion of female ministers. This suggests that the effect of democracy on the share of female cabinet members is not immediate but rather the result of a process where women gradually gain access to government.

Figure 2. Share of Women in Cabinet during Democratization across 20 Countries

Next, we test this systematically. The results are reported graphically in Figure 3. The figure shows the regression coefficients when we regress the three measures of female government representation on both the level and the stock of Polyarchy.

Figure 3. Regression Analysis on the Three Measures of Female Representation

Note: Independent variable is level or stock of Polyarchy. The models are based on an OLS with country-clustered standard errors. The thick bars show the 90% confidence intervals, whereas the thin bars show the 95% confidence intervals. The measure of Polyarchy is lagged by 1 year and no other controls are included. For full model results, see Supplementary Table G1 for “Share female” ( $ N=8,388 $ country years), Supplementary Table G2 for “Share female weighted” ( $ N=8,388 $ country years), and Supplementary Table G3 for “Share female high prestige” ( $ N=8,365 $ country years).

In the first model, we include only the level of democracy. Here, we see that democracy is significantly and positively correlated with women’s representation in government. This finding is independent of how we measure female representation. Substantively, we see that the most democratic country, on average, has 19% more female ministers than the least democratic.

In the second model, we include year-fixed effects. This takes into account longitudinal trends. Most importantly, we have seen an increase in both the number of democratic countries and the proportion of women in government across the world. Not surprisingly, including year-fixed effects decreases the size of the coefficient, albeit remaining statistically significant. Thus, women’s higher representation in government in democracies is not just an artifact of the rise of democracy (Huntington Reference Huntington1993; Teorell et al. Reference Teorell, Coppedge, Lindberg and Skaaning2019).

Third, we include country-fixed effects and, therefore, take into account time-invariant country-specific variables such as history or culture, meaning that we only look at variation in women’s representation and democracy within the same country. This diminishes the size of the coefficient, causing the effect of democracy to lose significance. Thus, we do not find that a country, on average, has significantly more women in government when it has a higher level of democracy.

However, when we operationalize democracy as a stock in the fourth model, we find that democracy is highly predictive of the share of women in government. In other words, when a country has more experience with democracy, the share of women in government increases. Furthermore, as shown in model 5 relative to model 4, the effects are larger as we place more emphasis on the past by reducing the depreciation rate. When using the 95% stock measure, a country with the democratic history of Denmark (in 2021) is predicted to have a 16% higher proportion of female cabinet members, relative to a country with the “democratic” history of North Korea, all else being equal.

We find that the results are substantively similar when using alternative measures of women’s representation that take into account the importance of the portfolios women are assigned to, meaning that women are assigned more portfolios, but also more important portfolios, when a country has more experience with democracy.

Testing for Potential Confounders

Many other factors could confound the relationship, even when including two-way fixed effects. We may particularly worry about time-variant variables, such as economic development, or other stock variables, such as GDP per capita. To counter some alternative explanations, we run a number of alternative specification tests in Table 2. Below, we only show the results for the share of female ministers, but in Appendixes H and I of the Supplementary Material, we find that the results are comparable when using the weighted share of female ministers and the share of female ministers in high prestige positions.

Table 2. Specification Tests

Note: All right-side variables lagged by 1 year. Country-clustered standard errors in parentheses. Estimator: OLS (ordinary least squares). FE = fixed effects (country and year), RE = random effects. * $ p<0.05 $ .

Model 1 shows the base model, where we only include the measure of the stock of democracy with country- and year-fixed effects. In model 2, we include the year as a trend instead of using fixed effects. This is another way of controlling for the effect of time by controlling for possibly spurious correlations between the measure of democracy and any similarly-trended independent variables. Using this measure of time increases the coefficient for the stock of democracy relative to the benchmark. Model 3 includes several time-varying measures of economic growth, such as GDP per capita and urbanization. Most importantly, we also include the log of GDP per capita, which also can be perceived as a stock measure for the level of development.Footnote 9 Likewise, we include measures of human development in model 4. Democracy may be related to both economic development (Acemoglu et al. Reference Acemoglu, Naidu, Restrepo and Robinson2019; Przeworski et al. Reference Przeworski, Alvarez, Cheibub and Limongi2000) and human development (Gerring, Thacker, and Alfaro Reference Gerring, Thacker and Alfaro2012). Furthermore, economic growth is known to be related to women’s representation (Matland Reference Matland1998). Coefficient estimates for the stock of democracy are stable across these tests and comparable in magnitude. Thus, the finding is not an artifact generated by increases in human development or economic capacity in democratizing countries and our findings are, therefore, not due to modernization (Lipset Reference Lipset1959).

In model 5, we control for other measures of women’s empowerment, such as women’s political empowerment index and the share of female legislators. These controls can, to some degree, be considered “bad controls,” since, as discussed in the theory, it is likely that the effect of democratization runs through these variables. However, we want to ensure that the findings are not caused by women’s general political empowerment in democratizing countries, but that there is something specific about democracy. We find that the stock of democracy remains significant and that the share of female legislators and women’s political rights are related to more female cabinet ministers. In contrast, the women’s political empowerment index is, surprisingly, related to fewer women in government. It should be noted that the controls for women’s empowerment are highly correlated and we should, therefore, be cautious when interpreting them in the same regression.

Model 6 includes several indices that focus on institutional capacity from the V-Dem dataset, such as property rights, the rule of law, judicial constraints, and party institutionalization, and shows a similar estimate for the measure of democracy. This suggests that the results are driven by the democratic feature and not other capacity-related features of institutions. Including these indices also mitigates a potential threat to inference stemming from country experts assigning a high score to a country along some institutional parameter during a period in which a country has more female ministers. If so, the relationship could be spurious and a product of coding circularity (Bizzarro et al. Reference Bizzarro, Gerring, Knutsen, Hicken, Bernhard, Skaaning and Coppedge2018).

In model 7, we include a lagged dependent variable. The coefficient for the lagged dependent variable is large (75.05), which is not surprising given that a country with more female ministers in one year will most likely have more ministers in the next year. The inclusion of the lagged dependent variable means that the coefficients for the stock of democracy capture only the short-term effects and we only estimate how the stock of democracy at $ t-1 $ affects the share of female ministers from $ t-1 $ to t. We find a strong, positive, and significant effect of the stock of democracy on the share of female ministers in the short run.

Lastly, in model 8, we include a number of fixed covariates to the benchmark model, such as ethnic fractionalization, percent Muslim, and the continent. These variables, which change little or not at all across the period of observation, lead us to replace country-fixed effects with a random-effects model. The coefficient for the stock of democracy remains significant in this specification.

While we include a long range of tests in Table 2, the list is not exhaustive. Hence, we include further robustness tests in the Supplementary Material. In Appendix J of the Supplementary Material, we show that the longer a view we have on history, that is, a lower deprecation rate, the stronger the association between the stock of democracy and the share of female ministers. Furthermore, we show that the results are comparable across different measures of democracy in Appendix C of the Supplementary Material, both when we use dichotomous measures, namely Boix, Miller and Rosato (Reference Boix, Miller and Rosato2013) and the DD index (Cheibub, Gandhi, and Vreeland Reference Cheibub, Gandhi and Vreeland2010), and another fine-grained measure, Polity IV (Marshall, Gurr, and Jaggers Reference Marshall, Gurr and Jaggers2019). In addition, we find that the results are similar when using imputed data for missing values, as seen in Appendix K of the Supplementary Material.

The analysis supports our argument that it is not the level of democracy that explains women’s access to public office but rather the historical experience with democracy. However, to strengthen the credibility of our theory, we proceed by testing further implications of the theoretical model.

Dividing Democracy into Its Composite Measures

In Figure 4, we split the measure of Polyarchy into its composite measures and run the models separately for the stock of each measure, including country- and year-fixed effects.

Figure 4. Which Component of Polyarchy Best Predicts the Share of Female Ministers?

Note: Share of female ministers. Based on separate models using an OLS regression with country- and year-fixed effects. Country-clustered standard errors in parentheses. The thin bars show the 95% confidence intervals, whereas the thick bars show the 90% confidence intervals. The measure of democracy is lagged by 1 year and no other controls are included. For full model results, see Supplementary Table L1: column 1 for Stock of Clean Elections ( $ N=8,144 $ ), column 2 for Stock of Freedom of Expression ( $ N=8,304 $ ), column 3 for Stock of Associational Autonomy ( $ N=8,365 $ ), column 4 for Stock of Elected Officials ( $ N=8,082 $ ), and column 5 for Stock of Suffrage ( $ N=8,255 $ ).

The measures of clean elections and freedom of expression are significantly and positively related to the share of female ministers, whereas associational autonomy is positive but outside conventional bounds for statistical significance. On the other hand, the measures of elected officials and suffrage are negative. At first, these results may seem puzzling, but elected officials and suffrage can be seen as minimum requirements for democracy and, therefore, “hollow” measures of democracy. A country can have sham elections with full suffrage, causing it to score high on these two measures, while having limited or no competition for power in reality. Meanwhile, the three measures focusing on whether the leader loses (at least some) control over the electoral process and, as a result, faces electoral competition, are all positive. This indicates that only real electoral competition changes the motives for selecting female ministers. This is in line with our theory and supports the idea that competitive elections and “real” democracy are important for the inclusion of women in government.

Transition to and from Democracy

Next, we investigate the implications of transitions to and from democracy on the share of female ministers when using a binary measure. This can be seen as a more general test of our main argument. Following our theoretical argument, we would not expect to see a drastic increase in the share of women being included in government immediately after democratization. Instead, the increase should be slow and gradual.

We test this in Figure 5, where we compare the share of female ministers before and after a country democratizes according to Boix, Miller, and Rosato (Reference Boix, Miller and Rosato2013). We use the share of ministers relative to the year of a democratic transition (year 0) to better take into account that democratization is clustered in time (Huntington Reference Huntington1993) and to better isolate the “effect” of democratization. As predicted, there is no sudden, large jump in the proportion of female ministers immediately following democratization, albeit we do see a small and significant increase in the share of female ministers in the year of democratization compared with the preceding autocratic period. Interestingly, we see little to no increase in the share of female ministers in the years immediately after democratization. However, four years after democratization, the share of female ministers starts increasing markedly, and eight years after democratization, we find that there is a significantly larger proportion of the cabinet that is female relative to the year of democratization. We may see these jumps because of four-year election cycles.

Figure 5. Democratic Transitions and the Share of Female Ministers

Note: The share of female ministers relative to the year of a democratic transition according to Boix, Miller, and Rosato (Reference Boix, Miller and Rosato2013) which have been merged with WhoGov, so the year of democratization corresponds to the first democratic cabinet. Ninety democratizations are included in the analysis. See Supplementary 96 M1 for full model results.

Split Samples

In the last section of the analysis, we investigate the relationship between regime type and female cabinet representation in subsets of the full sample to explore mechanisms further. The results are shown in Figure 6.

Figure 6. Split Sample Tests

Note: Dependent variable is the share of female ministers. Independent variable is the stock of Polyarchy. The models are based on an OLS with country-clustered standard errors. The thick bars show the 90% confidence intervals, whereas the thin bars show the 95% confidence intervals. The measure of stock of Polyarchy is lagged by 1 year and no other controls are included. For full model results, see Supplementary Table N1: column 1 for OECD ( $ N=1,734 $ ), column 2 for Non-OECD ( $ N=6,654 $ ), column 3 for GDPpc $ >7,000 $ ( $ N=4,000 $ ), column 4 for GDPpc $ <7,000 $ ( $ N=3,616 $ ), column 5 for Pre-1993 ( $ N=3,551 $ ), and column 6 for Post-1993 ( $ N=4,837 $ ).

We begin by dividing the sample into countries in the OECD (in 2018) and those that are not. Countries in the OECD are mainly established democracies integrated in the global economic system and have no recent history of being colonized. Furthermore, these countries have received the bulk of scholarly attention. We do not find conclusive evidence of a significant relationship between the stock of democracy and the share of female ministers in OECD countries. One possibility is that the result lacks statistical power because most OECD countries are older democracies (and, therefore, at the higher end of the global sample of stock of democracy). Thus, our independent variable may not capture enough variation within this narrower subset of well-established democracies. Here, other explanations, such as Franceschet, Annesley, and Beckwith’s (Reference Franceschet, Annesley and Beckwith2017) model of formal and informal selection rules, may be better at capturing the nuanced ways in which different types of established democracies continue on their paths to gender parity. In comparison, we see that the results are strongly significant in non-OECD countries, where most countries range from the lower to high-intermediate zone of global democratic stock. This suggests that our theoretical model is particularly well-suited to explain variation in this group of emerging democracies that are often overlooked in the literature.

Subsequently, we run the analysis within a sample of richer countries (GDP per capita $ >\$7,000 $ ) and poorer countries (GDP per capita $ <\$7,000 $ ) (in the given year) and find that democratic experience matters more in poorer countries. This reiterates that the finding has little to do with the level of development and highlights that democracy is of extra relevance in poorer countries for helping women access positions of power.

In the last two columns, we find that the point estimate is higher after the fall of the Soviet Union (1993–2021) than during the Cold War (1966–92). The fall of the Soviet Union was followed by democratic transition and consolidation in Africa, Eastern Europe, and elsewhere. Furthermore, there has been a higher demand for women in government in more recent years due to the decline in traditional gender norms, which, as discussed in the theory, should particularly have an impact on democracies. Lastly, some governments try to cater to international organizations and donors by appointing more women. For example, this was the case for a group of post-communist countries trying to obtain EU membership (Bego Reference Bego2014). Combined, these factors push the estimate upward in the period after the Cold War.

CONCLUSION

Women worldwide are increasingly gaining access to the highest positions of power—positions seldom intended for them to occupy. We posit that the historical nature of democracy is especially pertinent when explaining patterns of increasing inclusion.

The introduction of democratic institutions changes individual incentives to shift both demand and supply dynamics in favor of female ministers. Democracies capture developments at the mass level through the political entrepreneurship of activists and selectorates. However, these factors are unlikely to take effect immediately. Instead, path dependencies from the previous authoritarian regime hinder women’s access to the cabinet in democratizing countries. This means that the accumulation of democratic experiences, or the “stock” of democracy, shapes the patterns of gender balance in cabinets around the world.

Our analyses show that democracies indeed select more female ministers relative to autocracies. However, the association between the level of democracy and the share of female ministers disappears when comparing within country and year (meaning that we follow the same country as it democratizes, taking into account the global trend). However, when we instead operationalize democracy as a stock variable, we find a strong and robust relationship between democracy and the share of women in cabinets. Thus, democracy, working as a chisel, slowly helps chip away at the barriers facing women.

The results provide cause for both optimism and pessimism. While democracy became the dominant political regime as the twentieth century unfolded, progress has halted in later years, with democracy even in decline in some places (Hellmeier et al. Reference Hellmeier, Cole, Grahn, Kolvani, Lachapelle, Lührmann and Maerz2021). The findings of this article suggest that democratic breakdown can close doors in the face of women trying to gain access to the highest political positions, resulting in less gender-diverse governments. Therefore, our article is ultimately an argument for democracy as an instrument for opening windows for previously marginalized groups to access power.

These findings have a number of implications for current and future research on gender and cabinet composition. The article mainly looks at the share of female ministers but also includes more qualitative measures of prestige to triangulate the results. However, future research could explore these qualitative measures further and also look into specific types of ministries. For example, are finance ministers in democracies more likely to be female? In addition, this article only focuses on the difference between autocracies and democracies. However, this leaves much variance within regime type unexplained. One may wonder how different democratic institutions (such as term limits, the type of electoral system, partisan ideology, or the strength of party system) impact women’s access to government. Likewise, future research could explore the role of women in governments across autocratic regime types. Finally, the article does not deal with the consequences of having more women in executive positions. While a growing literature investigates these causes and consequences, there is still much ground to be covered in understanding gendered patterns of access to the highest echelons of power.

SUPPLEMENTARY MATERIAL

To view supplementary material for this article, please visit https://doi.org/10.1017/S000305542300062X.

DATA AVAILABILITY STATEMENT

Research data that support the findings of this study are openly available at the American Political Science Review Dataverse: https://doi.org/10.7910/DVN/I9E6EX.

ACKNOWLEDGMENTS

This article is dedicated to Frances McCall Rosenbluth who empowered so many through her work and through her living. We would like to thank Frances McCall Rosenbluth, Didac Queralt, Isabela Mares, Daniel Mattingly, Laure Bokobza, Charles Crabtree, Sarah Bush, Jean Lachapelle, Sona Golder, Susan Franceschet, Malliga Och, Svend-Erik Skaaning, Ken Benoit, participants at the Political Regimes and Their Correlates Workshop at Aarhus University, participants at the comparative politics workshop at Aarhus University, participants at the Comparative Institutions and Regimes workshop at the University of Oslo, and participants at the Asian Politics Online Seminar Series for their helpful comments and suggestions. We are also grateful to Yale University for supporting the project and for having Jacob as an exchange student. This is where this project started. Finally, we would like to thank the three anonymous reviewers and the editors of APSR who provided extensive and constructive feedback to improve our manuscript.

FUNDING STATEMENT

Jacob Nyrup acknowledges funding from the European Research Council (ERC) under the European Union’s Horizon 2020 research and innovation program (Grant Agreement No. 863486).

Stuart Bramwell acknowledges funding from the Economic and Social Research Council (ESRC), which is part of UK Research and Innovation (UKRI) (Award Ref. ES/W007142/1). The funding was hosted at the Department of Methodology at the London School of Economics.

CONFLICT OF INTEREST

The authors declare no ethical issues or conflicts of interest in this research.

ETHICAL STANDARDS

The authors affirm this research did not involve human subjects.

Footnotes

1 The original dataset only contains data up to 2016. It has since been updated to 2021.

2 We expect our theory to extend to democratic systems with term limits. Party organizations constrain democratic leaders’ choices to sustain electoral advantages into the next period (Alesina and Spear Reference Alesina and Spear1988). Democratic leaders may also care for selfish reasons, since the popularity and sustained power of their party can help maintain their own influence after leaving office. Furthermore, some leaders try to contravene term limits and rely on electoral trends to do so (McKie Reference McKie2019). Lastly, maintaining popularity reduces the likelihood of potentially being removed from office before the end of their term (Llanos and Pérez-Liñán Reference Llanos and Pérez-Liñán2021).

3 In coalition governments, the prime minister delegates some of the control over the selection of cabinet ministers to the coalition partners which in turn reduces the number of positions available per party. This may reduce women’s appointments to cabinet (Krook and O’Brien Reference Krook and O’Brien2012). Nonetheless, the theory should still travel to coalition governments since they have to act with some unity (Fortunato Reference Fortunato2021), and because many of the arguments, such as the groups from which the candidates are drawn from, still are valid.

4 This effect should exist even in countries with high party polarization since candidates may propose a more gender-balanced cabinet to get out the women’s vote among their own partisan support base. Furthermore, partisanship, ideology, and support for women’s representation are not always congruent (Celis and Childs Reference Celis and Childs2012), depending on nuances of individual voter utilities (West Reference West2022).

5 Although all major parties, at least to some degree, try to gain votes, they may not want to maximize votes, and instead focus on maximizing policy or spoils from being in office (Strom Reference Strom1990).

6 Additionally, the small size of the cabinet can give the leader more latitude in selection, in a kind of opposite dynamic found by Murray (Reference Murray2014) in legislatures where representational quality suffers from having to draw a large group from a narrow talent pool.

7 It should be noted that portfolios related to women’s affairs and equality are classified as low prestige following the coding used in WhoGov (Nyrup and Bramwell Reference Nyrup and Bramwell2020).

8 The variable stock s of polyarchy p at time t is defined as $ {s}_t={p}_{t-1}\alpha +{p}_t $ , where $ \alpha $ is a fixed depreciation rate. Note that when $ \alpha =0 $ , $ {s}_t={p}_t $ .

9 It should be noted that even though we only include the control for log of GDP per capita in this model, the analysis is consistent to including it throughout.

References

Acemoglu, Daron, Naidu, Suresh, Restrepo, Pascual, and Robinson, James A.. 2019. “Democracy Does Cause Growth.” Journal of Political Economy 127 (1): 47100.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Aidt, Toke S., and Dallal, Bianca. 2008. “Female Voting Power: The Contribution of Women’s Suffrage to the Growth of Social Spending in Western Europe (1869–1960).” Public Choice 134 (3): 391417.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Albertus, Michael, and Menaldo, Victor. 2018. Authoritarianism and the Elite Origins of Democracy. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Aldrich, John H. 1995. Why Parties?: The Origin and Transformation of Political Parties in America. Chicago, IL: University of Chicago Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Alesina, Alberto, and Spear, Stephen E.. 1988. “An Overlapping Generations Model of Electoral Competition.” Journal of Public Economics 37 (3): 359–79.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Alexander, Deborah, and Andersen, Kristi. 1993. “Gender as a Factor in the Attribution of Leadership Traits.” Political Research Quarterly 46 (3): 527–45.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Annesley, Claire, Beckwith, Karen, and Franceschet, Susan. 2019. Cabinets, Ministers, and Gender. New York: Oxford University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Arriola, Leonardo R., DeVaro, Jed, and Meng, Anne. 2021. “Democratic Subversion: Elite Cooptation and Opposition Fragmentation.” American Political Science Review 115 (4): 1358–72.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Arriola, Leonardo R., and Johnson, Martha C.. 2014. “Ethnic Politics and Women’s Empowerment in Africa: Ministerial Appointments to Executive Cabinets.” American Journal of Political Science 58 (2): 495510.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Atchison, Amy. 2015. “The Impact of Female Cabinet Ministers on a Female-Friendly Labor Environment.” Journal of Women, Politics & Policy 36 (4): 388414.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Barnes, Tiffany D., and O’Brien, Diana Z.. 2018. “Defending the Realm: The Appointment of Female Defense Ministers Worldwide.” American Journal of Political Science 62 (2): 355–68.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Baturo, Alexander, and Gray, Julia. 2018. “When Do Family Ties Matter? The Duration of Female Suffrage and Women’s Path to High Political Office.” Political Research Quarterly 71 (3): 695709.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bauer, Gretchen. 2012. “‘Let There Be a Balance’: Women in African Parliaments.” Political Studies Review 10 (3): 370–84.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bauer, Gretchen, and Darkwah, Akosua K.. 2022. ““The President’s Prerogative”? The Cabinet Appointment Process in Ghana and the Implications for Gender Parity.” Politics & Gender 18 (2): 546–73.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bauhr, Monika, Charron, Nicholas, and Wängnerud, Lena. 2019. “Exclusion or Interests? Why Females in Elected Office Reduce Petty and Grand Corruption.” European Journal of Political Research 58 (4): 1043–65.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Beckwith, Karen. 2001. “Women’s Movements at Century’s End: Excavation and Advances in Political Science.” Annual Review of Political Science 4: 371–90.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Beckwith, Karen, and Franceschet, Susan. 2022. “Gendering Cabinet Reshuffles in France and Spain.” Government and Opposition, 122. https://doi.org/10.1017/gov.2022.31.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bego, Ingrid. 2014. “Accessing Power in New Democracies: The Appointment of Female Ministers in Postcommunist Europe.” Political Research Quarterly 67 (2): 347–60.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Best, Rebecca H., Shair-Rosenfield, Sarah, and Wood, Reed M.. 2019. “Legislative Gender Diversity and the Resolution of Civil Conflict.” Political Research Quarterly 72 (1): 215–28.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bizzarro, Fernando, Gerring, John, Knutsen, Carl Henrik, Hicken, Allen, Bernhard, Michael, Skaaning, Svend-Erik, Coppedge, Michael, et al. 2018. “Party Strength and Economic Growth.” World Politics 70 (2): 275320.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bjarnegård, Elin, and Melander, Erik. 2013. “Revisiting Representation: Communism, Women in Politics, and the Decline of Armed Conflict in East Asia.” International Interactions 39 (4): 558–74.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bjørnskov, Christian, and Rode, Martin. 2020. “Regime Types and Regime Change: A New Dataset on Democracy, Coups, and Political Institutions.” Review of International Organizations 15: 531–51.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Blankenship, Jenna, and Kubicek, Paul. 2018. “Democratization and Gender Equality in Sub-Saharan Africa.” Journal of the Middle East and Africa 9 (1): 2750.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Blaydes, Lisa. 2010. Elections and Distributive Politics in Mubarak’s Egypt. New York: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Blumenau, Jack. 2021. “The Effects of Female Leadership on Women’s Voice in Political Debate.” British Journal of Political Science 51 (2): 750–71.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Boix, Carles, Miller, Michael K., and Rosato, Sebastian. 2013. “A Complete Data Set of Political Regimes, 1800–2007.” Comparative Political Studies 46 (12): 1523–54.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bridgewater, Jack, and Nagel, Robert Ulrich. 2020. “Is There Cross-National Evidence That Voters Prefer Men as Party Leaders? No.” Electoral Studies 67: 16.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Campbell, David E., and Wolbrecht, Christina. 2006. “See Jane Run: Women Politicians as Role Models for Adolescents.” Journal of Politics 68 (2): 233–47.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Caraway, Teri L. 2004. “Inclusion and Democratization: Class, Gender, Race, and the Extension of Suffrage.” Comparative Politics 36 (4): 443–60.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Caul, Miki. 1999. “Women’s Representation in Parliament: The Role of Political Parties.” Party Politics 5 (1): 7998.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Celis, Karen, and Childs, Sarah. 2012. “The Substantive Representation of Women: What to Do with Conservative Claims?Political Studies 60 (1): 213–25.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Chattopadhyay, Raghabendra, and Duflo, Esther. 2004. “Women as Policy Makers: Evidence from a Randomized Policy Experiment in India.” Econometrica 72 (5): 1409–43.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Cheibub, José Antonio, Gandhi, Jennifer, and Vreeland, James Raymond. 2010. “Democracy and Dictatorship Revisited.” Public Choice 143 (1–2): 67101.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Claveria, Silvia. 2014. “Still a ‘Male Business’? Explaining Women’s Presence in Executive Office.” West European Politics 37 (5): 1156–76.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Clayton, Amanda, and Zetterberg, Pär. 2018. “Quota Shocks: Electoral Gender Quotas and Government Spending Priorities Worldwide.” Journal of Politics 80 (3): 916–32.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Dahl, Robert Alan. 1971. Polyarchy: Participation and Opposition. New Haven, CT: Yale University Press.Google Scholar
Dahlum, Sirianne, Knutsen, Carl Henrik, and Mechkova, Valeriya. 2022. “Women’s Political Empowerment and Economic Growth.” World Development 156: 119.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Dassonneville, Ruth, and McAllister, Ian. 2018. “Gender, Political Knowledge, and Descriptive Representation: The Impact of Long-Term Socialization.” American Journal of Political Science 62 (2): 249–65.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Dassonneville, Ruth, Quinlan, Stephen, and McAllister, Ian. 2021. “Female Leader Popularity and the Vote, 1996–2016: A Global Exploratory Analysis.” European Journal of Politics and Gender 4 (3): 341–59.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Davis, Rebecca Howard. 1997. Women and Power in Parliamentary Democracies: Cabinet Appointments in Western Europe, 1968–1992. Lincoln: University of Nebraska Press.Google Scholar
De Mesquita, Bruce Bueno, Smith, Alastair, Siverson, Randolph M., and Morrow, James D.. 2005. The Logic of Political Survival. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.Google Scholar
Dolan, Kathleen. 2010. “The Impact of Gender Stereotyped Evaluations on Support for Women Candidates.” Political Behavior 32 (1): 6988.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Dollar, David, Fisman, Raymond, and Gatti, Roberta. 2001. “Are Women Really the “Fairer” Sex? Corruption and Women in Government.” Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization 46 (4): 423–29.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Donno, Daniela, Fox, Sara, and Kaasik, Joshua. 2021. “International Incentives for Women’s Rights in Dictatorships.” Comparative Political Studies 55 (3): 451–92.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Donno, Daniela, and Kreft, Anne-Kathrin. 2019. “Authoritarian Institutions and Women’s Rights.” Comparative Political Studies 52 (5): 720–53.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Downs, Anthony. 1957. An Economic Theory of Democracy. New York: Harper & Row.Google Scholar
Egorov, Georgy, and Sonin, Konstantin. 2011. “Dictators and Their Viziers: Endogenizing the Loyalty–Competence Trade-Off.” Journal of the European Economic Association 9 (5): 903–30.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Escobar-Lemmon, Maria C., and Taylor-Robinson, Michelle M.. 2005. “Women Ministers in Latin American Government: When, Where, and Why?American Journal of Political Science 49 (4): 829–44.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Escobar-Lemmon, Maria C., and Taylor-Robinson, Michelle M.. 2016. Women in Presidential Cabinets: Power Players or Abundant Tokens? New York: Oxford University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Fallon, Kathleen M., Swiss, Liam, and Viterna, Jocelyn. 2012. “Resolving the Democracy Paradox: Democratization and Women’s Legislative Representation in Developing Nations, 1975 to 2009.” American Sociological Review 77 (3): 380408.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Fortunato, David. 2021. The Cycle of Coalition: How Parties and Voters Interact under Coalition Governance. New York: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Franceschet, Susan, Annesley, Claire, and Beckwith, Karen. 2017. “What Do Women Symbolize? Symbolic Representation and Cabinet Appointments.” Politics, Groups, and Identities 5 (3): 488–93.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Fricker, Miranda. 2007. Epistemic Injustice: Power and the Ethics of Knowing. Oxford: Oxford University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Gandhi, Jennifer. 2008. Political Institutions under Dictatorship. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Geddes, Barbara. 1999. “What Do We Know about Democratization after Twenty Years?Annual Review of Political Science 2: 115–44.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Geddes, Barbara, Wright, Joseph, and Frantz, Erica. 2014. “Autocratic Breakdown and Regime Transitions: A New Data Set.” Perspectives on Politics 12 (2): 313–31.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Geddes, Barbara, Wright, Joseph, and Frantz, Erica. 2018. How Dictatorships Work: Power, Personalization, and Collapse. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Gerring, John, Knutsen, Carl Henrik, Maguire, Matthew, Skaaning, Svend-Erik, Teorell, Jan, and Coppedge, Michael. 2020. “Democracy and Human Development: Issues of Conceptualization and Measurement.” Democratization 28 (2): 125.Google Scholar
Gerring, John, Thacker, Strom C., and Alfaro, Rodrigo. 2012. “Democracy and Human Development.” Journal of Politics 74 (1): 117.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Gerring, John, Wig, Tore, Veenendaal, Wouter, Weitzel, Daniel, Teorell, Jan, and Kikuta, Kyosuke. 2021. “Why Monarchy? The Rise and Demise of a Regime Type.” Comparative Political Studies 54 (3–4): 585622.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Gerschewski, Johannes. 2013. “The Three Pillars of Stability: Legitimation, Repression, and Co-Optation in Autocratic Regimes.” Democratization 20 (1): 1338.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Goyal, Tanushree. 2019. “Local Political Representation as a Pathway to Power: A Natural Experiment in India.” Working Paper. https://papers.ssrn.com/sol3/papers.cfm?abstract˙id=3590118.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Harsch, Donna. 2014. “Communism and Women.” In The Oxford Handbook of the History of Communism, ed. Smith, Stephen Anthony, 488504. Oxford: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Hayward, Clarissa Rile. 2007. “Binding Problems, Boundary Problems: The Trouble with ‘Democratic Citizenship’.” In Identities, Affiliations, and Allegiances, eds. Benhabib, Seyla, Shapiro, Ian, and Petranovich, Danilo, 181205. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hellmeier, Sebastian, Cole, Rowan, Grahn, Sandra, Kolvani, Palina, Lachapelle, Jean, Lührmann, Anna, Maerz, Seraphine F., et al. 2021. “State of the World 2020: Autocratization Turns Viral.” Democratization 28 (6): 1053–74.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Homola, Jonathan. 2021. “The Effects of Women’s Descriptive Representation on Government Behavior.” Legislative Studies Quarterly 47 (2): 295308.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Htun, Mala, and Laurel Weldon, S.. 2012. “The Civic Origins of Progressive Policy Change: Combating Violence against Women in Global Perspective, 1975–2005.” American Political Science Review 106 (3): 548–69.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Huang, Junming, Gates, Alexander J., Sinatra, Roberta, and Barabási, Albert-László. 2020. “Historical Comparison of Gender Inequality in Scientific Careers across Countries and Disciplines.” Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences 117 (9): 4609–16.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Huddy, Leonie, and Terkildsen, Nayda. 1993. “The Consequences of Gender Stereotypes for Women Candidates at Different Levels and Types of Office.” Political Research Quarterly 46 (3): 503–25.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hughes, Melanie M., and Tripp, Aili Mari. 2015. “Civil War and Trajectories of Change in Women’s Political Representation in Africa, 1985–2010.” Social Forces 93 (4): 1513–40.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Huntington, Samuel P. 1993. The Third Wave: Democratization in the Late Twentieth Century. Norman: University of Oklahoma Press.Google Scholar
Jacob, Suraj, Scherpereel, John A., and Adams, Melinda. 2014. “Gender Norms and Women’s Political Representation: A Global Analysis of Cabinets, 1979–2009.” Governance 27 (2): 321–45.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kim, Nam Kyu. 2018. “Revolutionary Leaders and Mass Killing.” Journal of Conflict Resolution 62 (2): 289317.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kittilson, Miki Caul. 2011. “Women, Parties and Platforms in Post-Industrial Democracies.” Party Politics 17 (1): 6692.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kroeger, Alex, and Kang, Alice J.. 2022. “The Appointment of Women to Authoritarian Cabinets in Africa.” Government and Opposition, 124. https://doi.org/10.1017/gov.2022.32.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Krook, Mona Lena, and O’Brien, Diana Z.. 2012. “All the President’s Men? The Appointment of Female Cabinet Ministers Worldwide.” Journal of Politics 74 (3): 840–55.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kuran, Timur. 1997. Private Truths, Public Lies. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.Google Scholar
Lawless, Jennifer L., and Fox, Richard L.. 2005. It Takes a Candidate: Why Women Don’t Run for Office. New York: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Lee, Don S., and McClean, Charles T.. 2022. “Breaking the Cabinet’s Glass Ceiling: The Gendered Effect of Political Experience in Presidential Democracies.” Comparative Political Studies 55 (6): 9921020.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Levitsky, Steven, and Way, Lucan A.. 2010. Competitive Authoritarianism: Hybrid Regimes after the Cold War. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lindberg, Staffan I. 2004. “Women’s Empowerment and Democratization: The Effects of Electoral Systems, Participation, and Experience in Africa.” Studies in Comparative International Development 39 (1): 2853.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lipset, Seymour Martin. 1959. “Some Social Requisites of Democracy: Economic Development and Political Legitimacy.” American Political Science Review 53 (1): 69105.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Llanos, Mariana, and Pérez-Liñán, Aníbal. 2021. “Oversight or Representation? Public Opinion and Impeachment Resolutions in Argentina and Brazil.” Legislative Studies Quarterly 46 (2): 357–89.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lovenduski, Joni, and Norris, Pippa. 2003. “Westminster Women: The Politics of Presence.” Political Studies 51 (1): 84102.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Loxton, James, and Power, Timothy. 2021. “Introducing Authoritarian Diasporas: Causes and Consequences of Authoritarian Elite Dispersion.” Democratization 28 (3): 465–83.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lust-Okar, Ellen. 2006. “Elections under Authoritarianism: Preliminary Lessons from Jordan.” Democratization 13 (3): 456–71.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Magaloni, Beatriz, and Kricheli, Ruth. 2010. “Political Order and One-Party Rule.” Annual Review of Political Science 13: 123–43.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Marshall, Monty G., Gurr, Ted Robert, and Jaggers, Keith. 2019. “Polity IV Project: Political Regime Characteristics and Transitions, 1800–2018.” Center for Systemic Peace.Google Scholar
Matland, Richard E. 1998. “Women’s Representation in National Legislatures: Developed and Developing Countries.” Legislative Studies Quarterly 23 (1): 109–25.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
McKie, Kristin. 2019. “Presidential Term Limit Contravention: Abolish, Extend, Fail, or Respect?Comparative Political Studies 52 (10): 1500–34.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Miller, Michael K. 2015. “Electoral Authoritarianism and Human Development.” Comparative Political Studies 48 (12): 1526–62.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Miller, Michael K. 2021. “Don’t Call It a Comback: Autocratic Ruling Parties after Democratization.” British Journal of Political Science 51 (2): 559–83.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Miller, Michael K. 2020. “The Autocratic Ruling Parties Dataset: Origins, Durability, and Death.” Journal of Conflict Resolution 64 (4): 756–82.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Munck, Gerardo L., and Verkuilen, Jay. 2002. “Conceptualizing and Measuring Democracy: Evaluating Alternative Indices.” Comparative Political Studies 35 (1): 534.Google Scholar
Murray, Rainbow. 2014. “Quotas for Men: Reframing Gender Quotas as a Means of Improving Representation for All.” American Political Science Review 108 (3): 520–32.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Norris, Pippa. 1987. Politics and Sexual Equality the Comparative Position of Women in Western Democracies. Brighton, UK: Wheatsheaf.Google Scholar
Norris, Pippa. 1997. “Introduction: Theories of Recruitment.” In Passages to Power: Legislative Recruitment in Advanced Democracies, ed. Norris, Pippa, 114. New York: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Norris, Pippa, and Inglehart, Ronald. 2001. “Women and Democracy: Cultural Obstacles to Equal Representation.” Journal of Democracy 12 (3): 126–40.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Nyrup, Jacob, and Bramwell, Stuart. 2020. “Who Governs? A New Global Dataset on Members of Cabinets.” American Political Science Review 114 (4): 1366–74.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Nyrup, Jacob, Yamagishi, Hikaru, and Bramwell, Stuart. 2023. “Replication Data for: Consolidating Progress: The Selection of Female Ministers in Autocracies and Democracies.” Harvard Dataverse. Dataset. https://doi.org/10.7910/DVN/I9E6EX.Google Scholar
Osborne, Robin. 2010. Athens and Athenian Democracy. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Paxton, Pamela. 2000. “Women’s Suffrage in the Measurement of Democracy: Problems of Operationalization.” Studies in Comparative International Development 35 (3): 92111.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Paxton, Pamela, Hughes, Melanie M., and Painter, Matthew A.. 2010. “Growth in Women’s Political Representation: A Longitudinal Exploration of Democracy, Electoral System and Gender Quotas.” European Journal of Political Research 49 (1): 2552.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Przeworski, Adam, Alvarez, Michael E., Cheibub, Jose Antonio, and Limongi, Fernando. 2000. Democracy and Development: Political Institutions and Well-Being in the World, 1950–1990. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Rai, Shirin M. 1994. “Gender and Democratization: Or What Does Democracy Mean for Women in the Third World?Democratization 1 (1): 209–28.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Randall, Vicky. 1982. Women and Politics. London: Macmillan.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Scharpf, Adam, and Gläßel, Christian. 2020. “Why Underachievers Dominate Secret Police Organizations: Evidence from Autocratic Argentina.” American Journal of Political Science 64 (4): 791806.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Schwarz, Susanne, and Coppock, Alexander. 2022. “What Have We Learned about Gender from Candidate Choice Experiments? A Meta-Analysis of Sixty-Seven Factorial Survey Experiments.” Journal of Politics 84 (2): 655–68.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Sen, Amartya. 2001. Development as Freedom. Oxford: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Slater, Dan. 2010. Ordering Power: Contentious Politics and Authoritarian Leviathans in Southeast Asia. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Stockemer, Daniel. 2017. “The Proportion of Women in Legislatures and Cabinets: What Is the Empirical Link?Polity 49 (3): 434–60.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Stockemer, Daniel, and Kchouk, Bilel. 2017. “(Democratic) Regime Change and the Representation of Women in Parliament.” International Review of Sociology 27 (3): 491509.Google Scholar
Strom, Kaare. 1990. “A Behavioral Theory of Competitive Political Parties.” American Journal of Political Science 34 (2): 565–98.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Strom, Kaare, Budge, Ian, and Laver, Michael J.. 1994. “Constraints on Cabinet Formation in Parliamentary Democracies.” American Journal of Political Science 38 (2): 303–35.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Svolik, Milan W. 2012. The Politics of Authoritarian Rule. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Teele, Dawn Langan. 2018. Forging the Franchise: The Political Origins of the Women’s Vote. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Teele, Dawn Langan, Kalla, Joshua, and Rosenbluth, Frances. 2018. “The Ties That Double Bind: Social Roles and Women’s Underrepresentation in Politics.” American Political Science Review 112 (3): 525–41.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Teorell, Jan, Coppedge, Michael, Lindberg, Staffan I., and Skaaning, Svend-Erik. 2019. “Measuring Polyarchy across the Globe, 1900–2017.” Studies in Comparative International Development 54 (1): 7195.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Tremblay, Manon. 2012. Women and Legislative Representation: Electoral Systems, Political Parties, and Sex Quotas. New York: Palgrave Macmillan.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Tripp, Aili Mari. 2001. “Women and Democracy: The New Political Activism in Africa.” Journal of Democracy 12 (3): 141–55.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Truex, Rory. 2014. “The Returns to Office in a ‘Rubber Stamp’ Parliament.” American Political Science Review 108 (2): 235–51.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Wahman, Michael, Frantzeskakis, Nikolaos, and Yildirim, Tevfik Murat. 2021. “From Thin to Thick Representation: How a Female President Shapes Female Parliamentary Behavior.” American Political Science Review 115 (2): 360–78.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Wang, Yi-Ting, Lindenfors, Patrik, Sundstrom, Aksel, Jasson, Fredrik, Paxton, Pamela, and Lindberg, Staffan I.. 2017. “Women’s Rights in Democratic Transitions: A Global Sequence Analysis, 1900–2012.” European Journal of Political Research 56 (4): 735–56.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Wängnerud, Lena. 2009. “Women in Parliaments: Descriptive and Substantive Representation.” Annual Review of Political Science 12: 5169.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
West, Emily Anne. 2022. “Ingroup Bias, Partisanship, and Gendered Voting.” Political Psychology 43 (6): 1147–68.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Wintrobe, Ronald. 2000. The Political Economy of Dictatorship. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Figure 0

Table 1. Demand and Supply Forces in Cabinet Selection of Female Ministers

Figure 1

Figure 1. Trends in the Share of Women in Cabinet

Figure 2

Figure 2. Share of Women in Cabinet during Democratization across 20 Countries

Figure 3

Figure 3. Regression Analysis on the Three Measures of Female RepresentationNote: Independent variable is level or stock of Polyarchy. The models are based on an OLS with country-clustered standard errors. The thick bars show the 90% confidence intervals, whereas the thin bars show the 95% confidence intervals. The measure of Polyarchy is lagged by 1 year and no other controls are included. For full model results, see Supplementary Table G1 for “Share female” ($ N=8,388 $ country years), Supplementary Table G2 for “Share female weighted” ($ N=8,388 $ country years), and Supplementary Table G3 for “Share female high prestige” ($ N=8,365 $ country years).

Figure 4

Table 2. Specification Tests

Figure 5

Figure 4. Which Component of Polyarchy Best Predicts the Share of Female Ministers?Note: Share of female ministers. Based on separate models using an OLS regression with country- and year-fixed effects. Country-clustered standard errors in parentheses. The thin bars show the 95% confidence intervals, whereas the thick bars show the 90% confidence intervals. The measure of democracy is lagged by 1 year and no other controls are included. For full model results, see Supplementary Table L1: column 1 for Stock of Clean Elections ($ N=8,144 $), column 2 for Stock of Freedom of Expression ($ N=8,304 $), column 3 for Stock of Associational Autonomy ($ N=8,365 $), column 4 for Stock of Elected Officials ($ N=8,082 $), and column 5 for Stock of Suffrage ($ N=8,255 $).

Figure 6

Figure 5. Democratic Transitions and the Share of Female MinistersNote: The share of female ministers relative to the year of a democratic transition according to Boix, Miller, and Rosato (2013) which have been merged with WhoGov, so the year of democratization corresponds to the first democratic cabinet. Ninety democratizations are included in the analysis. See Supplementary 96 M1 for full model results.

Figure 7

Figure 6. Split Sample TestsNote: Dependent variable is the share of female ministers. Independent variable is the stock of Polyarchy. The models are based on an OLS with country-clustered standard errors. The thick bars show the 90% confidence intervals, whereas the thin bars show the 95% confidence intervals. The measure of stock of Polyarchy is lagged by 1 year and no other controls are included. For full model results, see Supplementary Table N1: column 1 for OECD ($ N=1,734 $), column 2 for Non-OECD ($ N=6,654 $), column 3 for GDPpc $ >7,000 $ ($ N=4,000 $), column 4 for GDPpc $ <7,000 $ ($ N=3,616 $), column 5 for Pre-1993 ($ N=3,551 $), and column 6 for Post-1993 ($ N=4,837 $).

Supplementary material: Link

Nyrup et al. Dataset

Link
Supplementary material: PDF

Nyrup et al. supplementary material

Appendices A-M

Download Nyrup et al. supplementary material(PDF)
PDF 207.8 KB
Submit a response

Comments

No Comments have been published for this article.