Hostname: page-component-586b7cd67f-rcrh6 Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-11-22T13:19:22.919Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Political Solutions to Discriminatory Behavior

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  30 August 2022

THORBJØRN SEJR GUUL*
Affiliation:
University of Southern Denmark and Aarhus University, Denmark
*
Thorbjørn Sejr Guul, Associate Professor, Department of Political Science and Public Management, University of Southern Denmark, Denmark; affiliated with TrygFonden’s Centre for Child Research, Department of Economics and Business Economics and Centre for Integrated Register-Based Research, Aarhus University, Denmark, tguul@sam.sdu.dk.
Rights & Permissions [Opens in a new window]

Abstract

Discriminatory treatment of minorities by public authorities remains a serious challenge and breaks with the central principles of impartiality. However, little research examines how discrimination can be reduced through political means. This article argues that discrimination occurs when the perceived marginal cost of serving a minority citizen exceeds the funding per user and/or when excess of demand forces the provider to prioritize which citizens to serve. This also suggests that increasing the funding per user and increasing supply to meet demand might reduce differential treatment. These predictions are tested in a high school enrollment system where the funding is linked to the number of students enrolled. Unique, fine-grained administrative data show that minority applicants are 9 percentage points less likely to be enrolled in their preferred high school. More importantly, an administrative reform shows how increasing the supply-side flexibility and pay per user cuts the difference in half.

Type
Research Article
Copyright
© The Author(s), 2022. Published by Cambridge University Press on behalf of the American Political Science Association

INTRODUCTION

According to Weber, a fundamental advantage of modern bureaucracy is that “Everyone is subject to formal equality of treatment; that is, everyone in the same empirical situation.” (Weber Reference Weber1947, 340). In fact, equality concerns are often a primary argument for the choice of public provision of a service because the private market solution would be deemed too unfair (Le Grand Reference Le Grand1991). However, recently, differential treatment of minorities by public authorities has received increased attention throughout the Western world (e.g., Reny and Newman Reference Reny and Newman2021). Thus, even though central principles of impartiality are widely approved and antidiscrimination laws are broadly set in motion (Schram et al. Reference Schram, Soss, Fording and Houser2009, 401), discriminatory treatment of minorities remains a serious challenge. In addition, numerous studies employing survey experimental (e.g., Pedersen, Stritch, and Thuesen Reference Pedersen, Stritch and Thuesen2018; Schram et al. Reference Schram, Soss, Fording and Houser2009) as well as field experimental (e.g., Dinesen, Dahl, and Schiøler Reference Dinesen, Dahl and Schiøler2021; Einstein and Glick Reference Einstein and Glick2017; Hemker and Rink Reference Hemker and Rink2017; Olsen, Kyhse-Andersen, and Moynihan Reference Olsen, Kyhse-Andersen and Moynihan2022; White, Nathan, and Faller Reference White, Nathan and Faller2015) approaches confirm that minority citizens are, indeed, treated differently from majority citizens by public authorities. Apart from the detrimental effects for minority citizens and the fact that discrimination breaks with the central principles of impartiality, research has also shown adverse effects on political trust, efficacy, and participation (Schneider and Ingram Reference Schneider and Ingram1993; Soss Reference Soss1999; Ziller and Helbling Reference Ziller and Helbling2019).

Though discrimination prevails in various encounters with public authorities and is undesirable for several reasons, precious little research examines how such discrimination can be reduced by political means. More generally, reviews across disciplines agree that “the literature does not reveal whether, when, and why interventions reduce prejudice in the world” (Paluck and Green Reference Paluck and Green2009, 360; see also Bertrand and Duflo Reference Bertrand and Duflo2016, 85; Paluck, Green, and Green Reference Paluck, Green and Green2019, 133). The lack of evidence might reflect the fact that studying sustainable methods of reducing discrimination at the hands of public authorities with political means proves to be an incredibly difficult task for at least three reasons.

The first reason relates to the challenge of identifying policies that actually reduce discrimination. Ample psychological literature provides evidence on debiasing interventions in the lab (Bertrand and Duflo Reference Bertrand and Duflo2016). However, researchers have called for caution while applying findings from the lab in the real world (Spencer, Charbonneau, and Glaser Reference Spencer, Charbonneau and Glaser2016). The situations in the lab are rarely similar to what you face in the field, and the identified interventions are not easily controllable by political means (Spencer, Charbonneau, and Glaser Reference Spencer, Charbonneau and Glaser2016).

The second reason relates to causally identifying the effects of such policies. Policies are often implemented either globally treating all units, which makes it difficult to generate a valid control group, or locally as a response to specific organizational performance or behavior, making the policy endogenous to the outcome of interest.

The third reason relates to the challenge of detecting discrimination at all. Existing studies often categorize the explanations of discrimination as based on taste (Becker Reference Becker1957), statistical associations between minorities and specific traits (Phelps Reference Phelps1972), or implicit biases (Bertrand, Chugh, and Mullainathan Reference Bertrand, Chugh and Mullainathan2005). Following the first and second explanation, discrimination might reflect a conscious decision. But because discrimination is outlawed throughout the Western world and impartiality is particularly articulated as a virtue of modern bureaucracy, explicitly acknowledging differential treatment is unlikely. If discrimination is caused by implicit biases that work outside the discriminator’s conscious, people might not even be aware of discriminatory behavior though they might be willing to admit it.

To identify relevant policies, this study builds a theoretical model that suggests that discrimination occurs due to two simple premises that often shape the provision of public services. The first relates to a perception of minority citizens as being more costly to serve. The second premise is that the funding scheme for the provider is related to the number of users they serve. This is a typical way of funding public services and covers various funding systems including quasi-markets, voucher systems, and contracting out. The model predicts that discrimination is likely to occur if the perceived marginal cost of serving a minority citizen exceeds the pay per user and/or excess of demand for a provider forces the provider to prioritize which citizens to serve—a common situation because no price mechanism limits the demand for popular providers (Lipsky Reference Lipsky2010). As a consequence, the model also suggests that increasing the funding per user and increasing supply to meet excess of demand might reduce differential treatment.

To examine the validity of the model, this study focuses on a highly important context: high school enrollment. High schools differ substantially in terms of the quality of teaching, ability of peers, and level of segregation seen in them. Being admitted to the high school of your choice might also strongly affect your engagement and commitment to the program. Also, being admitted to a service of your choice increases the match between individual preferences for services with the provided service—a primary argument for offering citizens in a democracy a choice between different providers (Tiebout Reference Tiebout1956). Finally, public schooling is provided around the world and is one of the largest public providers of service in many countries. More specifically, this study focuses on high school allocation in Denmark where the funding has been determined by free school choice and the number of enrolled students but with little supply-side flexibility since 2007. Thus, the providers had an incentive to be selective in their enrollment practices. In addition, previous studies have found that minority citizens (specifically non-Western citizens) are more likely to be referred to another class or school than are their majority citizen peers (Andersen and Guul Reference Andersen and Guul2019; Olsen, Kyhse-Andersen, and Moynihan Reference Olsen, Kyhse-Andersen and Moynihan2022) in a Danish context, indicating that minority status is, indeed, perceived as costly in this setting.

Most importantly, an administrative reform in 2010 increased the supply-side flexibility and increased the pay per student. The reform let the providers buy their own buildings (instead of using them for free), thereby increasing the ability to determine the high school capacity locally. In exchange, the providers got an 11% increase in the pay per student. For the full population of high school applicants (more than 115,000 applications) in Denmark from 2009 to 2012, highly detailed register data from the enrollment process makes it possible to observe applicants, which high school they apply for, and whether they are enrolled in the prioritized high school, as well as detailed individual characteristics including measures of academic abilities (GPA from middle school) and minority status (non-Western applicant or not), and link them through unique personal identifiers. This allows this study to meet the third challenge (detecting discrimination) by modeling the enrollment process extremely accurately and detecting whether minority and majority applicants in the same empirical situation are evenly admitted to their preferred high school.

This data and a difference-in-difference design comparing the difference in enrollment in preferred high schools between non-Western and Western applicants before and after the reform make it possible to meet the second challenge and identify whether these policy changes have induced public providers to discriminate less. Prereform fixed effects estimates within receiving first-priority high schools and sender middle schools show that non-Western applicants are 9 percentage points less likely to get enrolled in their preferred high school than are Western applicants. The reform effectively eliminates half of the difference in first-priority enrollment rate between Western and non-Western applicants. Various robustness checks and a placebo test support the conclusions. Particularly interestingly and in accordance with expectations, the reduction in discriminatory treatment of non-Western applicants appears to be driven by oversubscribed providers. The findings implicate that redesigning the economic incentives in public service delivery makes it possible to reduce differential treatment through politically controllable means.

The next section introduces the theoretical explanations of discrimination and their potential political solutions; it also reviews the sparse evidence found on policies that reduce discriminatory treatment. The second section develops the theoretical model and derives its empirical implications. The third section presents the empirical setting before the estimation strategy, data, and measurement are discussed. The descriptive statistics and results follow. The findings are further discussed in relation to other possible political means of reducing discrimination and potential mechanisms.

THEORY AND EXISTING EVIDENCE

Discrimination and Political Solutions

There are at least three theoretical explanations for why discrimination occurs that also apply to discrimination by public authorities. First, discrimination might be a result of racism and a distaste for minority citizens (Becker Reference Becker1957). Second, it might occur because people make decisions based on statistical associations between minorities and specific traits (Phelps Reference Phelps1972). Finally, discrimination might occur because of implicit biases that people unintentionally rely on in decision making (Bertrand, Chugh, and Mullainathan Reference Bertrand, Chugh and Mullainathan2005). Although the first and third explanations arguably reflect irrational and biased decision processes and the second a more rational and potentially unbiased response from the perspective of the minority citizen, the outcome is the same: you are treated according to your minority status instead of based on your specific situation.

Previous studies have looked into interventions that might reduce exclusionary attitudes among ordinary voters. For instance, Kalla and Broockman (Reference Kalla and Broockman2020) find that nonjudgmentally exchanging narratives in interpersonal conversations can facilitate durable reductions in exclusionary attitudes. Similarly, a recent review by Paluck, Green, and Green (Reference Paluck, Green and Green2019) has examined the support for the contact hypothesis but concludes that “the jury is still out regarding the contact hypothesis and its efficacy as a policy tool” (133). Furthermore, it remains an open question whether these types of interventions can reduce exclusionary attitudes and ultimately transform into less discriminatory behavior by public authorities.

Few studies have examined political solutions to discrimination by public authorities. Generally speaking there are three main political solutions to societal problems: (1) regulatory, (2) informational, and (3) economic (Vedung Reference Vedung, Bemelmans-Videc, Rist and Vedung2011). However, pure regulation appears ineffective because antidiscrimination laws are already set in motion in many countries (e.g., the Civil Rights Act of 1964 in the United States). Concerning informational solutions, Fang, Guess, and Humphreys (Reference Fang, Guess and Humphreys2018) examine in a field experiment whether government information can deter landlords from discriminating their potential tenants through their responses to them. However, the results are inconclusive, and the authors suggest that this might be explained by the fact that they need to estimate the interaction between minority status and the policy in question to determine the policy’s effect, which requires additional power. Moreover, the examined policy targets private providers and the same tools might not be effective for public providers. In relation to economic solutions, a further distinction between providing economic resources and creating economic incentives can be made (Vedung Reference Vedung, Bemelmans-Videc, Rist and Vedung2011). Concerning the first, a recent study finds that the random provision of resources that reduces the workload for a sample of public school teachers also reduces discriminatory responses in a survey experiment afterwards (Andersen and Guul Reference Andersen and Guul2019). Though the authors conclude that whether the reduction in discriminatory responses might be temporary remains an open question, this suggests that economic instruments might be a way to reduce differential treatment. Concerning economic incentives, less is known. However, the use of economic incentives in relation to the provision of public service is exactly what signifies market-based reforms that introduce user choice and competition. Therefore, the next section develops a model for how such market-based reforms might affect discriminatory behavior by public authorities.

Theoretical Model for Public Service Discrimination and Reduction

Market-based reforms have gained popularity across the globe in various service areas such as education, health care, social services, and nursing home services (Blöhliger Reference Blöchliger2008). These types of reforms might be popular because it makes it possible to balance two often conflicting goals. On the one hand, a common rationale behind the decision to provide a service in the public rather than the private domain is that the results would be too unequal in the private domain (Le Grand Reference Le Grand1991). On the other hand, a common critique of public service provision is that it makes the provider responsive to the political leadership rather than the users of the service (Chubb and Moe Reference Chubb and Moe1988). To compensate for the latter without compromising the first, a widespread response by political authorities is to introduce elements of choice and competition. The main idea involves two elements: (1) giving the users a choice between at least two providers of the service in question and (2) paying the provider a fixed price per user for their service. The specific setup varies empirically in many ways. Thus, a system can be created with only public providers, only private providers, or both as long as the government pays a fixed price for the provision of the service. In practice, such systems are known as quasi-markets, voucher systems, or agreements to contracting out (Blöchliger Reference Blöchliger2008).

A system of choice and competition resembles a pure private solution but with several differences. One important difference is that the user demand for a specific provider becomes unrelated to the price of the service, as it is the same for all providers (typically zero from the user’s perspective). Thus, the demand for a specific service has other determinants. For simplicity, I consider the demand exogenous in the current model. Thus, I treat the demand for a specific provider as fixed. The marginal cost function for the providers, on the other hand, is expected to be closely tied to the quantity of the service provided. This is expected for at least two reasons. First, production costs are, in general, expected to increase at a certain point due to diseconomies of scale (Boyne Reference Boyne1995). The second and more important element in the cost function is specifically linked to the marginal cost of providing service for specific users because we would expect some users to be more demanding or rewarding to serve than others due to individual user characteristics. One such factor might be minority status. Thus, some users might be perceived as high-cost users and others as low-cost users. Although discriminatory perceptions have given several different explanations (as described above) for the purpose of the model, we can be agnostic about whether the cost assessments are accurate or biased. Nonetheless, two experimental studies from the educational context show what can be viewed as discriminatory behavior and thereby support that public authorities have negative perceptions of minority citizens in this context. Thus, minority fathers are faced with more administrative burdens when they ask whether it is possible to move their children to a new school in Denmark (Olsen, Kyhse-Andersen, and Moynihan Reference Olsen, Kyhse-Andersen and Moynihan2022), and Pfaff et al. (Reference Pfaff, Crabtree, Kern and Holbein2021) show, in the context of the US, that whether or not a parent receives a response to a request for a meeting with a possible school for their child depends on their religious affiliation.

When the pay per user is fixed and the marginal cost of increasing supply grows with the number of users served, we would expect the providers to increase the supply of their service as long as the marginal cost of providing another unit of the service is below the fixed pay per user. Note that because the pay per user is fixed, the marginal pay per user is constant and the marginal pay per user is equivalent to the marginal revenue.

This simple model for the provision of service is depicted for a specific provider in Figure 1, Panel A. Thus, if the user demand for the service is fixed at D1 and the marginal cost of providing the service for the costliest user is below the pay per user P $ {}_1 $ , we would expect to end up in situation A where all users with a preference for a specific provider are served by this provider. However, if the marginal cost of providing the service exceeds the pay per user and the demand for the service is fixed at D2 and thus above this threshold, we would expect the providers to choose not to enroll a number of users. Additionally and specifically, we would expect them to decline the users they find most costly to enroll in the program. As mentioned, if minority status enters this cost assessment, one implication of such an excess of demand would be that minority users would be rejected and thus receive differential treatment (with all else being equal).

Figure 1. Theoretical Models for the Relationship between User Demand, Pay Per User, Cost Per User, and Quantity of Provided Units of Service under a Choice and Competition Funding System

Note: The y-axis indicates price and the x-axis indicates quantity. D1 and D2 indicate different levels of fixed demand. P1 and P2 indicate fixed levels of pay per user. “Supply Cap” indicates a fixed cap for the supply quantity. The diagonal line illustrates the increasing marginal cost per user. Panel A depicts a situation with complete supply-side flexibility, and Panel B depicts a situation where a supply cap is introduced.

Studies from the educational policy literature on school choice support that schools are selective in their intake of students. Lubienski, Gulosino, and Weitzel (Reference Lubienski, Gulosino and Weitzel2009) show that schools across three different school choice programs in the US use a variety of exclusionary strategies. Similar results are found in the context of the United Kingdom by Burgess, Propper, and Wilson (Reference Burgess, Propper and Wilson2007), who suggest that the combination of school choice policies and limited supply-side flexibility ultimately forces the schools to introduce criteria for a selective intake of students. Parallel patterns are found after the introduction of school choice in New Zealand, where oversubscribed schools implemented enrollment schemes and minority and disadvantaged students became disproportionately concentrated in specific schools (Ladd and Fiske Reference Ladd and Fiske2001).

Instead of changing the perceived costs, one simple solution to this type of discrimination would be to increase the pay per user to make it more profitable to increase supply to meet demand. Thus, if politicians changed the pay per user from P1 to P2, we would end up in situation B where all users preferring the specific provider are served by this provider.

An important assumption for this to be true is supply-side flexibility. Thus, the providers must be able to increase the units of the service supplied. Panel B depicts a situation where the supply is capped at a fixed quantity. If the demand for the service is above the supply cap (as depicted by D2 in Panel B), we would expect the same as described above—namely, that the providers decline the service for some users based on their perceived costs even though the marginal cost of increasing the supply is below the pay per user (depicted by P2 in Panel B). Again, we would expect that removing such a limitation would increase the supply to meet demand and potentially reduce discriminatory decline decisions. Furthermore, it would make it possible to end up in situation F instead of E. Importantly, this argument is robust even if we relax the fixed demand assumption. Thus, we would expect a similar result even if the demand is affected by changes in the quantity of the service provided as long as the change in demand is smaller than the change in quantity.

In summary, when minority status enters the providers’ cost assessment in a choice and competition funding system, we would expect discrimination to occur in situations where demand exceeds the marginal cost of increasing supply or with limited supply-side flexibility and increasing the pay per user and/or the supply-side flexibility would reduce discriminatory treatment. To test these propositions, I need to study a service area governed by choice and competition where some providers experience an excess of demand. But most importantly I need exogenous changes in the pay per user and/or supply-side flexibility. A reform within the Danish public high school program in 2010 constitutes an excellent case with respect to all these subjects, and the next section describes this empirical setting in more detail.

RESEARCH DESIGN

Empirical Setting

The Danish educational system consists of 10 years of compulsory schooling: preschool class and grade 1 to 9 (equivalent to elementary and middle school in the US). Roughly 80% of Danish students attend a public school. After 9th grade, students can attend the voluntary 10th grade, apply for further education, or enter the labor market. If the student chooses to apply for further education, they can continue on to high school or enter vocational training. The largest high school program is the General Upper Secondary Education Program (STX), which generally prepares the students for further college education (roughly 38% of the cohort enrolled in this program in 2009).Footnote 1 Contrary to the compulsory schooling, almost all students attend a public high school (approximately 96% of all STX students in the studied period). The high schools have been run as self-governing institutions, with local boards organized under the national Ministry of Education since 2007. Denmark has a multitier government system, with a national, regional, and municipal level, and regional governments (five in total) have a formal role in coordinating the overall upper-secondary educational capacity in the region. Within each region, all high schools take part in allocation committees in their local area that are formed based on geographical proximity. If a high school is oversubscribed, the school is legally supposed to pass on all applications to the allocation committee that will then allocate the applicants.

Legal documents describe the enrollment process further, but several important steps are informally determined. The high schools are obliged to report their student capacity to the regional government the following school year in November. The regional government approves the reported capacity in January. In March, the applicants fill out a prioritized list of high schools they would like to attend. The application is sent to their current middle school, which makes sure that information concerning the applicant’s academic abilities (final GPA or teacher-assessed GPA) as well as personal information concerning their address and name are attached. Then, the current middle school passes the application on to the high school with the highest priority on the applicant’s list. The relevant high school is then responsible for assessing whether the applicant is eligible for high school.Footnote 2 If the applicant is deemed eligible and the number of first-priority applications do not surpass the capacity, the applicant will be offered the chance to attend the high school the following school year, without further ado. If the school is oversubscribed, it needs to be determined who among the eligible applicants should be enrolled in the preferred high school.

In the application process, the high schools can observe several things about the applicants. As mentioned they directly observe the applicant’s academic abilities (GPA), the applicant’s current middle school (the sender of the application), and what grade they currently attend (9th grade or the voluntary 10th grade). Based on the applicant’s name, it is also possible to determine the gender (male or female) as well as the minority status of the applicant (non-Western or Western)—a common way of observing these attributes. The specific address of the applicants might also implicitly signal their socioeconomic status. High schools might be aware of where the applicants with higher-educated parents tend to live in their local area. Also, high schools can take travel distance into consideration when determining which applicants to enroll.

Though the allocation committees are supposed to handle the allocation process in the case of oversubscribed high schools, their power to do so remains limited for several reasons. The legal work sets up a few guidelines for the allocation mechanism. The committee should seek to meet all applicants’ first priority before starting applicant redistribution steps, and they are supposed to take travel patterns into account. However, the committees consist of principals from relevant local high schools, and the distribution of applicants can be viewed as an unequal bargaining process where the oversubscribed high schools have a better bargaining position than the high schools with too few first-priority applicants. Whether this is true is of course an empirical question. However, if the allocation committees to some extent reduce selective enrollment behavior among oversubscribed schools, it would only make the estimates of any remaining selectivity in enrollment behavior more conservative, compared with a situation without allocation committees. In fact, several anonymous principals reported that the oversubscribed high schools could pick and choose which applicants to accept in an assessment of the allocation committees in the studied period (Pluss 2012). For instance, a principal stated, “It is very much up to the schools who they choose to pass on, and it is no secret that the school that passes the students on makes the decision and that it might seem a bit nontransparent how things end up the way they do” (Principal, Capital Region; Pluss 2012, 21). On top of that, some regions explicitly allowed their high schools to file a list of applicants they would like to admit.

The high schools’ funding consists primarily of activity-based grants related to the number of students enrolled and those who graduate from high school. Before the 2010 reform, the central government owned the high school buildings and the high school providers were allowed to use the buildings free of charge. However, that also meant that attempts to increase the capacity needed permission from central government authorities. The reform made it possible for the schools to buy their buildings at a favorable price based on an assessment of their ability to pay, making it markedly easier for the high schools to increase capacity. In addition, if the schools chose to buy the buildings, the pay per enrolled student would increase dramatically. Thus, the reform made it a lot easier for the high schools to increase the capacity and intake of students, and in addition, it increased the incentive to do so because the pay per student increased. The Finance Committee in the Danish parliament made the decision. The official background for the decision was that decentralized responsibility would give providers an increased economic incentive to optimize resources based on local conditions (Finance Committee, Danish Parliament 2009). Within 10 months, 91% of the high schools had accepted the offer, with more to come.Footnote 3 More specifically, the high schools receive five activity-based grants relative to the number of students enrolled. The exact numbers are shown in Table 1. The activity-based grants are divided into several parts called taximeter grants. The largest is a grant intended to cover costs related to teaching activities. The second largest is a grant given for each student who graduates from the specific high school. Finally, three different grants are related to other costs such as administration, buildings, and maintenance. As mentioned earlier, of particular interest here is a new grant introduced in 2010 intended to cover building costs as a consequence of the providers taking over the ownership. Ultimately, the reform increased the pay per user by roughly 11%.

Table 1. Pay Per User in High School, 2009–2010

Note: All numbers are in nominal Danish kroner 6.15 DKK ~ US$1. These data are obtained from the yearly governmental financial bills in 2009 and 2010. Further, one-third of the completion grant is calculated as part of the total pay per user because it usually takes three years to complete the high school program.

Empirical Strategy

As mentioned initially, studying policies that reduce discrimination is challenging. Policies that might reduce discrimination rarely randomly generate valid control and treatment groups. Policies are either implemented globally, leaving no one unaffected, or locally as a response to performance or organizational behavior that makes the policy endogenous to the outcome of interest. To be fair, it might be possible to handle some policy solutions in a randomized control trial—for instance, the information campaign examined in Fang, Guess, and Humphreys (Reference Fang, Guess and Humphreys2018). However, many relevant policy instruments (such as changing the incentive scheme in the public sector) are difficult to manipulate by the researcher. In addition, as the authors of the former study mention, statistical power becomes an issue in this type of study.

Although the policy reform described above was implemented nationally, it is possible to gain leverage from the fact that we would expect the policy to affect specific groups of applicants differently according to their perceived cost. Thus, we would expect the policy to increase the enrollment rate particularly for non-Western applicants because the increase in the pay per student would make it beneficial to include students who would have previously exceeded the perceived costs. This makes it possible to use a difference-in-difference design to estimate whether the policy increased the enrollment in preferred high schools more for non-Western applicants than for Western applicants. Importantly, although the increase in the pay per student could affect the enrollment of Western students as well, this would only make the difference-in-difference estimate of the policy effect more conservative. The validity of the difference-in-difference design relies on the common trend assumption. Although it is impossible to test the assumption, if the assumption holds, it is possible to take both time-invariant factors and potential time trends into account.

In addition, it is necessary to get a reliable measure of whether discrimination takes place. A frequently used approach is to use name cues—either in a survey or field experimental setup to isolate the effect of minority status from other potential (and legitimate) reasons for differential treatment. However, it might not be feasible to combine this approach with relevant policy changes as described above (Fang, Guess, and Humphreys Reference Fang, Guess and Humphreys2018).

Therefore, this study takes another approach and relies on unique detailed administrative data to get an estimate of potential discriminatory treatment that makes it possible to model the decision process with high precision. Thus, it becomes possible to estimate whether applicants with different minority statuses have a different probability of getting enrolled in their preferred high school using high school fixed effects and middle school fixed effects, with controls for gender, GPA, grade at the time of application (9th or 10th grade), and parental educational background. These data make it possible to observe applicant characteristics directly, with a few exemptions. First, it might be possible for the providers to gather further information (e.g., by contacting the school that the applicant currently attends or by looking into other qualitative data sources), but gathering such additional information is a costly process—especially because the high schools, on average, enroll more than 200 students per year. Second, applicant address is not observed. If the non-Western applicants systematically live further away from the school that they prioritize than do their majority peers, that could be a legitimate concern in the system under investigation. However, the middle school fixed effects handle these issues to a large extent because only applicants from the same school districts are compared in these models. School districts are geographically rather small; thus, travel time between students seldom differs markedly, and we would expect socioeconomic differences might also be reduced if students with similar backgrounds are selected into the same school district. Furthermore, if this is the case the middle school fixed effects also take into account whether applicants from less-affluent school districts apply less strategically. In addition to account for socioeconomic signals from applicant address, I include controls for parental education in the analysis.

Furthermore, while the assumption behind the detection of discrimination in this setup is that all empirical differences observable by the high schools are measured, the difference-in-difference assumptions are more relaxed. Thus, I can validly estimate the effect of the reform even if the estimate of discrimination is biased as long as the estimation bias is time invariant. This implies that the reform estimate would be valid even though the providers gather unobserved additional information, as long as they do it to the same extent in the pre- and postreform periods. Similarly, even if the providers use residential patterns to select applicants, it does not affect the validity of the difference-in-difference estimate as long as these patterns are constant over time. Due to the relatively limited time perspective, it seems unlikely that such patterns would change dramatically during the studied period. Because not all high schools accepted the offer to buy their buildings and thereby also received the increase in the pay per user, we can consider the difference-in-difference estimate as an intention-to-treat estimate. The primary outcome is whether applicants are enrolled in their preferred high school. More formally, the primary outcome variable, Y, is an indicator variable taking the values

(1) $$ Y\hskip0.35em =\hskip0.35em \left\{\begin{array}{ll}1,& \mathrm{student}\ \mathrm{enrollment}\ \mathrm{in}\ \mathrm{first}-\mathrm{priority}\ \mathrm{high}\ \mathrm{school}\\ 0, &\mathrm{Otherwise}\end{array}\right. $$

The full model can be written as follows:

(2) $$ {Y}_{ihm}\hskip0.35em =\hskip0.35em \alpha +{\beta}_1{G}_i+{\beta}_2T+{\beta}_3{G}_iT+{\mathbf{x}}_{\mathbf{i}}+{\theta}_h+{\lambda}_m+{\varepsilon}_{ihm}, $$

where Yihm signifies enrollment in preferred high school for applicant i applying for enrollment in high school h from middle school m, and Gi is an indicator of whether student i is of non-Western descent. The variable T is a time dummy taking the value 0 for the prereform year 2009 and 1 for the postreform years 2010–2012, and x i is a vector of applicant level covariates. $ {\theta}_h $ and $ {\lambda}_m $ signify high school and middle school fixed effects, respectively.

All models are estimated with ordinary least squares (OLS), and because the outcome is binary, they are interpreted as linear probability models (Wooldridge Reference Wooldridge2010, 562). Robustness analysis based on logistic regressions produces similar results.Footnote 4 Abadie et al. (Reference Abadie, Athey, Imbens and Wooldridge2017) argue that you should cluster standard errors at the level of treatment. Because the enrollment decision is largely determined at individual high schools and the reform specifically changed the incentives that individual high schools received, the standard errors are clustered at the high school level. However, clustering at the level of middle schools or the allocation committee also produces significant results (see Table A.4 in the supplementary materials for the exact p values).Footnote 5

To summarize, most importantly, the reform allows us to examine whether changing the theoretically relevant determinants of differential treatment can effectively reduce discrimination. The described approach makes it possible to determine the enrollment rate for Western and non-Western applicants in the same empirical situation. Thus, this study relies on a difference-in-difference design based on observing the enrollment of Western and non-Western applicants before and after the implementation of the reform.

Data and Measurement

The study capitalizes on detailed administrative data on the admission process (see Table A.15 in the supplementary materials for an overview of the administrative data sources). As mentioned above, the regular application process for high school involves filling out an online application formula with a prioritized list of schools for further education. This study is based on records of all first priority applications for a public high school from 2009 to 2012.Footnote 6 As a matter of fact, 2009 is the oldest entry of the application data. In 2012, a flexible class-size cap was introduced that could have affected the results, so 2012 is the endpoint of the analysis. However, changing the postreform period does not change the results substantially (see Table A.13 in the supplementary materials).

To measure whether the applicants are enrolled in their preferred high school, both measures of the preferred high school and actual enrollment are needed. For each applicant, I can directly observe the high school that the applicant would prefer. Whenever a person enrolls in an educational program, it is also reported to a central register. Unique personal identifiers make it possible to link the information and create a measure of enrollment in the preferred high school. Ideally, I would like to observe the offer of enrollment, because applicants with different backgrounds could accept it to different extents; however, as long as such tendencies do not change with the reform, the difference-in-difference also takes that into account. In a Danish setting, minority status relates to whether you are of non-Western or Western descent.Footnote 7 The public political debate of immigration in Denmark has focused on non-Western origins (Green-Pedersen and Krogstrup Reference Green-Pedersen and Krogstrup2008, 611); official statistics are telling about the concentration of non-Western immigrants, and policies are based on it (Danish Parliament 2010). Finally, previous Danish (e.g., Dinesen and Sønderskov Reference Dinesen and Sønderskov2015; Villadsen and Wulff Reference Villadsen and Wulff2017) as well as European studies (Schneider Reference Schneider2008) have used non-Western origins as the basis for empirical analysis on the role of ethnicity and minority status.Footnote 8 Place of birth of the applicant and their parents are also directly observable in central registers and used to construct the measure of minority status. The applicant’s gender is measured as a simple indicator of whether the applicant is female or male based on biological sex at birth. Their GPA is measured as a simple average of their middle school grades in all exams as well as classroom grades assessed by their teachers if they apply after the voluntary 10th grade or as a simple average of their classroom grades if the they apply from 9th grade because the exam grades are usually not available when the application is submitted in March. The GPA is standardized within each cohort of 9th-grade students (standard deviation = 1, mean = 0). Finally, parental background is measured with a set of indicator variables for highest educational attainment for each parent (MA or PhD level, BA level, academy level, below academy level, and missing).

Descriptives and the Common Trend Assumption

Table 2 shows descriptive statistics for the sample before and after the reform. The reform slightly decreased the share of applicants that did not enroll in their preferred high school. This would also be expected because the reform made it easier for the providers to increase supply and thus meet surplus in demand. The share of females, non-Western, 10th grade applications, and applicants with missing GPAs did not change markedly. However, the standardized GPA decreased slightly, indicating that applicants performing slightly more poorly within their cohort applied for a high school. Both before and after the reform, the applicants performed above the cohort mean (set to 0).

Table 2. Descriptive Statistics Prereform and Postreform

Note: All variables except the GPA standardized are indicator variables. The GPA is calculated by taking the mean of all exam grades and classroom-assessed grades for 10th-grade students and all classroom assessed grades for 9th-grade students. The GPA has been standardized within each full cohort of 9th-grade students. Furthermore, 2009 constitutes the prereform period and 2010–2012 the postreform period.

Figure 2 shows additional descriptive statistics of enrollment patterns. Panel A shows the raw rates of enrollment in the preferred high school by minority status from 2009 to 2012. The figure clearly shows the initial difference in enrollment rates between non-Western and Western applicants, that the enrollment rate changes markedly for the non-Western applicants after the reform, and that the enrollment rates are relatively stable in the postreform period. Panel B shows the average number of students enrolled per provider in the period 2007 (first year under the described funding system) to 2012. Thus, it is possible to examine the changes in enrollment across years in both the pre- and postreform periods. The graph shows that the average number of students per provider has been slowly increasing since 2007, but the average enrollment took a huge jump in the year after the reform, indicating that the reform induced the providers to increase intake (gray line, right y-axis). At the same time, the share of non-Western students enrolled is fairly constant throughout the period (black line, left y-axis).

Figure 2. Descriptives for First-Priority Enrollment Rates and Enrolled Students

Note: Panel A represents raw rates of enrollment in first-priority high schools by the minority status during the period 2009–2012. The vertical lines represent 95% confidence intervals. Panel B depicts the average number of students enrolled in high schools during the period 2007–2012 (gray line, right y-axis) and share of non-Western students enrolled (black line, left y-axis). The vertical dashed line indicates the timing of the reform.

Unfortunately, it is not possible to assess the trend in first-priority high school enrollment during the prereform period, which could support the validity of the common trend assumption, as the application data necessary to create the measure is only available for one year before the reform. A potential violation to the common trend assumption would be if the share of non-Western applicants took a dramatic drop during the postreform period. However, as Table 2 shows, this is not the case.

Another potential threat to the design would be if the non-Western applicants started submitting applications more strategically following the reform. One way to test this is to examine whether non-Western applicants are less likely to apply for oversubscribed high schools than are Western applicants during the postreform period than during the prereform period. However, a supplementary analysis shows that this does not seem to be the case (see Table A.5 in the supplementary materials). There appear to be slightly fewer applicants for oversubscribed schools during the postreform period, but this is not significantly lower for non-Western applicants.Footnote 9 In summary, though it is not possible to examine the prereform trends, the available evidence supports that the common trend assumption appears to be valid.

RESULTS

Influence of the Reform on Differential Treatment

Table 3 shows the results (see Table A.3 in the supplementary materials for the full model results). All reported coefficients are significant at the 5% level or lower. Model 1 shows that non-Western students were 19 percentage points less likely to be enrolled in their preferred high school during the prereform period. The coefficient drops by taking differences in background characteristics and high school fixed effects into account to a difference of 10 percentage points (Model 4). Thus, observable empirical differences explain approximately half of the difference in enrollment rates between the non-Western and Western applicants and the high school to which they apply. Introducing middle school fixed effects does only reduce the difference marginally (Model 6). Thus, under the assumption of no unobserved confounders, non-Western applicants in the same empirical situation were 9 percentage points less likely to be enrolled in their preferred high school. The reform coefficients represent the difference in enrollment rate before and after the reform for Western applicants. Thus, the reform increased enrollment in preferred high schools by approximately 3.5 percentage points for Western applicants. The coefficient does not change markedly across specifications, indicating that slightly more applicants were enrolled in their preferred high school during the postreform period. Finally, the interaction term between non-Western applicant and reform constitutes the difference-in-difference estimate. The coefficient in Model 1 indicates that the reform reduced the difference in enrollment rate between non-Western and Western applicants by approximately 6 percentage points. Including covariates, high school fixed effects, and middle school fixed effects only slightly changes the estimates (still roughly 5 percentage points in Model 6). This suggests that the reform eliminated half of the difference between Western and non-Western applicants’ enrollment rates in preferred high schools, indicating a substantial reduction in the differential treatment of non-Western applicants.

Table 3. Enrolled in First-Priority High School, Non-Western Applicant and Reform

Note: Coefficients from linear probability models (OLS). Standard errors clustered at high school level in parentheses. All reported variables are indicator variables. Covariates included are standardized GPA and GPA missing indicator, indicators for parental education, and indicators for female applicant and grade of application (9th or 10th grade). See Table A.3 in the supplementary materials for the full model results. *p < 0.05, **p < 0.01, ***p < 0.001.

Additional Robustness Analysis and Possible Mechanisms

Figure 3, Panel A shows more detailed results by plotting the predicted enrollment rates in preferred high schools for Western and non-Western applicants before and after the reform based on Model 6 in Table 3—the most conservative estimates. Importantly, although the difference in the enrollment rate between Western and non-Western students drops from 9 percentage points during the prereform period to 4.5 percentage points during the postreform period, the difference is still significant, indicating that the reform did not completely eliminate differential treatment.

Figure 3. Predicted Enrollment Rates by Minority Status Prereform and Postreform and Difference-in-Difference Estimates

Note: Panel A shows predicted enrollment rates by minority status prereform and postreform based on Table 3, Model 6. Differences and difference-in-difference estimates are above the horizontal bracket. The vertical lines represent 95% confidence intervals. Panel B shows difference-in-difference estimates for different specifications based on Model 6 in Table 3 above and Model 6 in Tables A.6, A.7, A.8, A.9, and A.10 in the supplementary materials. The horizontal lines represent 95% confidence intervals. All estimates are based on standard errors clustered at the high school level.*p < 0.05, **p < 0.01, ***p < 0.001.

Figure 3, Panel B summarizes several alternative difference-in-difference specifications that support the expected mechanisms linking the increase in the pay per student to the reduction in differential treatment. The first estimate corresponds directly to the estimate from Table 3, Model 6 for comparison. A potential concern relates to whether the reduction in differential treatment is actually caused by differences in perceived cost or other mechanical changes in enrollment caused by the reform. One way to test this is to conduct a placebo test and calculate the difference-in-difference estimate based on an observable characteristic that might not be perceived as costly by the provider. The gender of the applicants constitutes such a characteristic. Thus, if it is the costly assessment of minority status that drives the results, I would expect the difference-in-difference estimate for a noncostly characteristic to be insignificant. Because gender balance is much closer to 50% (approximately 60% are females), the coefficient based on gender can be estimated with higher precision than that based on minority status (only 10% of the applicants are non-Western). Still the difference-in-difference estimate (the second estimate in Panel B) in the placebo test is insignificant and zero in practical terms. The reported estimate is based on the same specification as Model 6 in Table 3; however, the estimate is very stable across specifications (see Table A.6 in the supplementary materials).

Another observable implication of the proposed theoretical model is that I would expect the level of demand for the specific provider to affect their response to the reform (as shown in Figure 1, Panel A). Thus, I would only expect the difference in enrollment rate to change for providers with a surplus of demand. One way to test this proposition is by grouping the providers based on whether or not the number of first-priority applications exceeded the number of enrolled applicants during the prereform period—in other words, whether the individual high school initially had to refer some applicants to other high schools or whether they received some students who had prioritized other schools as their first priority. The third and fourth difference-in-difference estimate in Figure 3, Panel B shows the difference-in-difference estimate for providers of initially undersubscribed and oversubscribed high schools, respectively, during the prereform period. The results show that virtually all of the reduction in differential treatment can be attributed to the providers with an excess of demand, with an estimated reduction of almost 10 percentage points. Contrary to this, the difference-in-difference estimate is insignificant and close to zero for the providers with an excess of supply (see Table A.7 and A.8 in the supplementary materials for the full models). This indicates that the reduction is, indeed, driven by increased intake in schools that previously experienced an excess of demand.Footnote 10

A further observable implication is that I would expect the largest reduction in discriminatory intake among the providers that experienced the largest surplus of demand before the reform. The last two difference-in-difference estimates in Figure 3, Panel B show the effects among the surplus schools that experienced above and below the median level of oversubscription during the prereform period (see also Tables A.9 and A.10 in the supplementary materials). The difference-in-difference estimate is 11 percentage points among the schools with the largest surplus and only 7 percentage points among the low-surplus schools. Furthermore, during the prereform period non-Western applicants are 13 percentage points less likely to be enrolled in their preferred schools among the schools with the largest surplus compared with 9 percentage points among the schools with the smaller surplus (see Tables A.9 and A.10 in the supplementary materials).Footnote 11

Finally, although the differential treatment of minority applicants has detrimental effects for the individual and breaks with the principles of impartiality, it is interesting to examine whether the perceived costs are actually observable by the providers. One way to examine this is to analyze whether different groups of applicants have different probabilities of finishing high school. More specifically, I can examine this by regressing completion ratesFootnote 12 on observable characteristics. Table 4 shows that non-Western students have 11 percentage points lower completion rates. Similarly, females have 2 percentage points higher completion rates than do males. However, the most important predictor of completion rate is GPA from middle school, which directly measures academic abilities (and explains 7% of the variation in the completion rate). Interestingly, when I include all characteristics in one model, non-Western students only have 3 percentage points lower completion rates than do Western students, which is quite close to the difference between male and female students, indicating that most of the difference in completion rates is explained by differences in GPA. The fact that the reform did increase the enrollment of non-Western applicants in their preferred high school (main analysis above) but not the enrollment of male applicants (the placebo test) indicates that the differential treatment might reflect more than an assessment of the applicants’ propensity to complete high school.Footnote 13

Table 4. High School Completion for Enrolled Students

Note: Coefficients from linear probability model (OLS). Standard errors clustered at high school level in parentheses. All reported variables are indicator variables except for the standardized GPA. The completion rate is measured for all students enrolled during the prereform years 2007 and 2008. *p < 0.05, **p < 0.01, ***p < 0.001.

DISCUSSION OF POLITICAL SOLUTIONS AND DISCRIMINATION

The findings above indicate that discrimination happens in predictable ways and that adjusting the pay per user can reduce discriminatory behavior. These findings have several interesting implications. First, the findings show promise in relation to how discrimination can be reduced. Importantly, the reform did not increase the average cost per high school student; it merely changed the funding so that an increased share of the funding was based on the pay per user (because of the introduction of the building taximeter) and less funding was fixed (as a result of the free use of the buildings). Thus, the reform only muddled around with the money that was already in the system. However, the results also show that increasing the pay per user might not be a perfect political solution to discrimination. First, when you consider the intake of minority applicants across high schools throughout the studied period, the share is relatively constant, indicating that increased pay per student might not increase the providers’ willingness to enroll minority students but only increases the overall intake. Thus, though the outcome might have improved for minority applicants, the providers might discriminate to the same extent as before. In addition, the results show that the reform reduced discrimination but did not eliminate it. This makes it relevant to consider other possible solutions to discriminatory behavior.

One alternative means of reducing discrimination could be to increase the pay per user for specific groups of applicants (e.g., with minority backgrounds). However, this could easily cause new problems with stigma associated with belonging to a specific group of citizens. Also, it could foster new types of strategic behavior such as selection within the group of applicants that would imply additional pay per user (e.g., the preferred group of minority applicants or those with the best academic track records). Another related alternative would be to use quotas and thereby force the providers to enroll a certain proportion of minority applicants. However, that could cause the same types of strategic behavior as described above because oversubscribed high schools would still have to refer some (minority) students to other providers.

Another widespread funding model is fixed funding that is unrelated to the number of users. However, this could arguably even increase discrimination because it would give the providers an incentive to avoid all applicants they would perceive as costly. These considerations could indicate that a funding system with increased dependence on pay per user could indeed be the best possible political solution. However, there are at least two other alternatives that are worth considering. One alternative would be to let an independent agency determine which applicants should be enrolled in which schools. In fact, that was supposed to be the point of the allocation committees in the system under investigation. However, this case also stresses that the agency needs to have actual power to decide on the distribution of applicants to be effective. Another possibility might be to establish clear and unbendable criteria for the distribution of applications. Both responses would reduce discretion at the high school level, which could be a more viable solution. However, setting up these rules and simultaneously keeping some extent of choice for the applications is difficult. If authorities, for instance, sort applicants based on grades, they might end up with highly segregated schools in terms of academic abilities. Another possibility is to use travel distance, but that will de facto remove the possibility of free choice. The discussion shows the importance of carefully considering the consequences of different modes for the provision of service for discriminatory behavior, but it ultimately remains a political question as to how to balance these concerns.

Furthermore, though it is not the purpose of the analysis above to determine the type of discrimination at play, the analysis shed some light on possible explanations. Even though it is possible for some unobserved confounder to explain the differential enrollment of non-Western applicants, the fact that this difference remains substantial using high school fixed effects and middle school fixed effects, with controls for gender, GPA, grade of application (9th or 10th grade), and parental educational background suggests that this difference can indeed be attributed to minority status. The fact that minority students are less likely to graduate on average during the pretreatment period (as shown in Table 4) could indicate that the differential treatment of non-Western applicants constitutes a case of statistical discrimination. However, the placebo test with female applicants shows they are less likely to get enrolled in their preferred high school during both the prereform and the postreform period (see Table A.6 in the supplementary materials) even though they are more likely to graduate; this fact indicates that there is something other than pure rational motives at stake. Another possible explanation within the rational explanatory framework relates to the almost constant share of non-Western students across the studied period, which could indicate that the providers are concerned about getting too large a proportion of non-Western students and therefore consciously seek to control the share throughout the studied period. If the differential enrollment was purely based on taste, why the economic incentives should affect the enrollment pattern is less straightforward. However, the pattern we see could also be consistent with implicit biases that simply become less dominant when the number of available seats increases. However, more research focusing on the different explanations is needed to answer this question with greater certainty.

CONCLUSION

Although the reasons to look for political solutions to discriminatory behavior are abundant, little research empirically examines how to do so. This study argues that the pay-per-user funding that is widely used might be both a potential source for discrimination and a possible solution. If minority users are perceived as more costly than majority users, simply increasing the pay per user as well as supply-side flexibility might prove to be easy tools that reduce discrimination by public authorities.

The analysis in the current study relies on rich data, but as discussed in the methodology section, the conclusions are only valid under two important assumptions. The first one relates to whether I observe all relevant empirical differences between Western and non-Western applicants. Although this seems plausible, even if the estimate of differential treatment is biased, I can validly estimate the effect of the reform because of the difference-in-difference design as long as this potential bias is constant during the studied period. Furthermore, in relation to the latter, various validity checks, including a placebo test and test for differences in application patterns, support that the common trend assumption is valid in the current setup though it is not possible to examine prereform trends.

Obviously, equal treatment and allowing all applicants to enroll in their preferred high school are not the only goals to achieve in public service delivery. The introduction of funding based on the number of users also introduces incentives for unintended behavior by the providers such as focusing on quantity rather than quality in the educational production. We would only expect the incentives for such behavior to increase with increased reliance on pay-per-user funding, and these potential adverse effects, which might be substantial, should, of course, be kept in mind. In addition, it might, for example, also be important to ensure a geographical spread and a diverse composition of users across providers. Balancing these considerations also ultimately remains a political question.

Whether the political solution to discrimination will be feasible in other settings is of course an empirical question. Importantly, the study covers the full population of applicants for a public high school during the studied period, so the conclusions seem safe within this context. Even though the proposed theoretical model is based on few assumptions, the question of whether we will see similar patterns in other settings where pay-per-user funding is applied and minority users are perceived as more costly to serve remains to be answered by future research. The examined mode of funding has been used across various areas of service (schools, high schools, colleges, hospitals, and eldercare to name a few). Therefore, the number of settings in which this question can be examined is high. Importantly, although many different services are provided based on such funding schemes, it is rarely (if ever) the case for important services, such as the police, and obviously not in areas of society where the solutions are completely based on the market. Also, an important extension of the proposed model would be to include determinants of demand for specific providers in a choice and competition system, as the effect of changing the incentives differs markedly under excess supply versus excess of demand conditions. Furthermore, the reform did not completely root out the differential intake rate, suggesting that other measures might be needed. This calls for future studies seeking to replicate whether similar effects can be found in other countries and service areas; it also calls for future studies looking into other policy instruments that might root out discriminatory behavior where other funding systems are applied. The present study supports the idea of looking for ways to root out discriminatory behavior rather than the biases that cause the behavior (Spencer, Charbonneau, and Glaser Reference Spencer, Charbonneau and Glaser2016). Thus, the task is to look for potentially sustainable ways of avoiding discriminatory behavior rather than remove its roots.

SUPPLEMENTARY MATERIALS

To view supplementary material for this article, please visit http://doi.org/10.1017/S0003055422000648.

DATA AVAILABILITY STATEMENT

Research documentation that supports the findings of this study is openly available at the American Political Science Review Dataverse: https://doi.org/10.7910/DVN/TNQ7EI. Limitations on data availability are discussed in the supplementary materials.

ACKNOWLEDGMENTS

I would like to acknowledge the support for this project from TrygFonden’s Centre for Child Research, Department of Economics and Business Economics, Aarhus University. Thanks to the Centre for Integrated Register-Based Research, CIRRAU, Aarhus University, for making the data analysis possible. A special thanks to Hans Henrik Sievertsen, Christian Bøtcher Jacobsen, Simon Calmar Andersen, The Public Administration Section, Department of Political Science, Aarhus University, four anonymous reviewers, and the editor for helpful comments on earlier versions of the manuscript.

FUNDING STATEMENT

This research was funded by TrygFonden’s Centre for Child Research, Department of Economics and Business Economics, Aarhus University.

CONFLICT OF INTEREST

The author declares no ethical issues or conflicts of interest in this research.

ETHICAL STANDARDS

The author affirms this research did not involve human subjects.

Footnotes

1 The students can also choose to apply for two more specialized high school programs focused on either business and economics or technology and science. These programs function under slightly different government regimes, and because the reform in question did not affect these programs, the focus is on the general program (STX).

2 The middle school or high school can also ask the student to sit for an academic test before it makes a decision.

3 A few schools were specifically not allowed to buy their buildings until ongoing construction or renovation work was finished.

4 Table A.2 in the supplementary materials shows the coefficients based on logistic regression (Model 1) and with covariates (Model 2), estimated as a conditional logistic model with fixed effects at the high school level (Model 3) and at the middle school level (Model 4). All coefficients are significant and in the same direction as they are in the linear probability models. However, taking fixed effects into account in a logistic regression framework is challenging, as the size of the fixed effects is unknown and assumptions need to be made about their size to obtain partial marginal effects (Wooldridge Reference Wooldridge2010, 622). Also, it is not possible to estimate the effects with both levels of fixed effects and covariates.

5 When clustering at the middle school level, all main variables across all model specifications are significant at the 0.001 level. Clustering at the allocation committee level also provides results that are significant across models, though the difference-in-difference estimate in the most restricted Models 5 and 6 are only significant at p < 0.10.

6 The raw data contain 116,108 first-priority applications for a specific high school. A total of 670 observations are dropped due to missing information on which school they apply from. Another 62 observations are dropped because they lack background information. In total, missing observations constitute less than 1% of the population. No further data restrictions are imposed. Table A.1 in the supplementary materials summarizes the attrition.

7 Non-Western descent refers to people not originating from the 27 EU countries, Great Britain, Iceland, Norway, Switzerland, the European microstates, Canada, USA, Australia, or New Zealand.

8 However, using the distinction between Danish and non-Danish applicants produces similar results (see Table A.14 in the supplementary materials).

9 The slightly fewer applicants for oversubscribed schools also show that the increased enrollment was not met by a larger increase in demand, which would lead to different expectations, as argued in the theory section.

10 Interestingly the difference between non-Western and Western applicants’ nonenrollment rate during the postreform period is reduced to approximately 2–3 percentage points among the providers with excess demand but closer to 6–7 percentage points among the providers with excess surplus. Although these numbers are estimated relatively inaccurately, they indicate that the remaining differential treatment during the postreform period can be attributed to the providers who previously had an excess of supply. See Tables A.7 and A.8 in the supplementary materials.

11 Another way to test this is by looking at the effects for the surplus schools that gained the most seats by the reform. However, this analysis might be affected by posttreatment bias because the decision to increase the number of seats was taken after the reform. Still Tables A.11 and A.12 in the supplementary materials show the effects among the surplus schools that gained above and below the median number of seats in the first year after the reform.

12 Completion is defined as graduating from high school of enrollment three years after enrollment. Dropping out, not graduating on time, or graduating from another high school counts as noncompletion. The analysis is restricted to students enrolled during 2007 and 2008 (the years before the reform).

13 Another possible mechanism could be through differential use of academic tests before making the enrollment decision after the reform. However, the data needed to examine this were not available.

References

REFERENCES

Abadie, Alberto, Athey, Susan, Imbens, Guido W., and Wooldridge, Jeffrey. 2017. “When Should You Adjust Standard Errors for Clustering?” National Bureau of Economic Research Working Paper 24003.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Andersen, Simon Calmar, and Guul, Thorbjørn Sejr. 2019. “Reducing Minority Discrimination at the Front Line—Combined Survey and Field Experimental Evidence.” Journal of Public Administration Research and Theory 29 (3): 429–44.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Becker, Gary Stanley. 1957. The Economics of Discrimination. Chicago, IL: University of Chicago Press.Google Scholar
Bertrand, Marianne, Chugh, Dolly, and Mullainathan, Sendhil. 2005. “Implicit Discrimination.” The American Economic Review 95 (2): 9498.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bertrand, Marianne, and Duflo, Esther. 2016. “Field Experiments on Discrimination.” National Bureau of Economic Research Working Paper 22014.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Blöchliger, Hansjörg. 2008. “Market Mechanisms in Public Service Provision.” OECD Economics Department Working Papers No. 626.Google Scholar
Boyne, George. 1995. “Population Size and Economies of Scale in Local Government.” Policy & Politics 23 (3): 213–22.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Burgess, Simon, Propper, Carol, and Wilson, Deborah. 2007. “The Impact of School Choice in England.” Policy Studies 28 (2): 129–43.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Chubb, John E., and Moe, Terry M.. 1988. “Politics, Markets, and the Organization of Schools.” American Political Science Review 82 (4): 1065–87.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Danish Parliament. 2010. Lov om ændring af lov om almene boliger m.v. https://www.ft.dk/ripdf/samling/20101/lovforslag/l60/20101_l60_som_fremsat.pdf.Google Scholar
Dinesen, Peter Thisted, Dahl, Malthe, and Schiøler, Mikkel. 2021. “When Are Legislators Responsive to Ethnic Minorities? Testing the Role of Electoral Incentives and Candidate Selection for Mitigating Ethnocentric Responsiveness.” American Political Science Review 115 (2): 450–66.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Dinesen, Peter Thisted, and Sønderskov, Kim Mannemar. 2015. “Ethnic Diversity and Social Trust: Evidence from the Micro-Context.” American Sociological Review 80 (3): 550–73.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Einstein, Katherine Levine, and Glick, David M.. 2017. “Does Race Affect Access to Government Services? An Experiment Exploring Street-Level Bureaucrats and Access to Public Housing.” American Journal of Political Science 61 (1): 100–16.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Fang, Albert H., Guess, Andrew M., and Humphreys, Macartan. 2018. “Can the Government Deter Discrimination? Evidence from a Randomized Intervention in New York City.” The Journal of Politics 81 (1): 127–41.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Finance Committee, Danish Parliament. 2009. Finansudvalget 2008-09, Aktstk 191. https://www.ft.dk/samling/20081/aktstykke/aktstk.191/aktstykke/642029/715302.pdf.Google Scholar
Green-Pedersen, Christoffer, and Krogstrup, Jesper. 2008. “Immigration as a Political Issue in Denmark and Sweden.” European Journal of Political Research 47 (5): 610–34.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Guul, Thorbjørn Sejr. 2022. “Replication Data for: Political Solutions to Discriminatory Behavior.” Harvard Dataverse. Dataset. https://doi.org/10.7910/DVN/TNQ7EI.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hemker, Johannes, and Rink, Anselm. 2017. “Multiple Dimensions of Bureaucratic Discrimination: Evidence from German Welfare Offices.” American Journal of Political Science 61 (4): 786803.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kalla, Joshua L., and Broockman, David E.. 2020. “Reducing Exclusionary Attitudes through Interpersonal Conversation: Evidence from Three Field Experiments.” American Political Science Review 114 (2): 410–25.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ladd, Helen F., and Fiske, Edward B.. 2001. “The Uneven Playing Field of School Choice: Evidence from New Zealand.” Journal of Policy Analysis and Management 20 (1): 4363.3.0.CO;2-4>CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Le Grand, Julian. 1991. “The Theory of Government Failure.” British Journal of Political Science 21 (4): 423–42.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lipsky, Michael. 2010. Street-Level Bureaucracy, 30th Ann . Ed.: Dilemmas of the Individual in Public Service. New York: Russell Sage Foundation.Google Scholar
Lubienski, Christopher, Gulosino, Charisse, and Weitzel, Peter. 2009. “School Choice and Competitive Incentives: Mapping the Distribution of Educational Opportunities across Local Education Markets.” American Journal of Education 115 (4): 601–47.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Olsen, Asmus Leth, Kyhse-Andersen, Jonas Høgh, and Moynihan, Donald. 2022. “The Unequal Distribution of Opportunity: A National Audit Study of Bureaucratic Discrimination in Primary School Access.” American Journal of Political Science 66 (3): 587603.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Paluck, Elizabeth Levy, and Green, Donald P.. 2009. “Prejudice Reduction: What Works? A Review and Assessment of Research and Practice.” Annual Review of Psychology 60:339–67.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Paluck, Elizabeth Levy, Green, Seth A., and Green, Donald P.. 2019. “The Contact Hypothesis Re-Evaluated.” Behavioural Public Policy 3 (2): 129–58.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Pedersen, Mogens Jin, Stritch, Justin M., and Thuesen, Frederik. 2018. “Punishment on the Frontlines of Public Service Delivery: Client Ethnicity and Caseworker Sanctioning Decisions in a Scandinavian Welfare State.” Journal of Public Administration Research and Theory 28 (3): 339–54.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Pfaff, Steven, Crabtree, Charles, Kern, Holger L., and Holbein, John B.. 2021. “Do Street-Level Bureaucrats Discriminate Based on Religion? A Large-Scale Correspondence Experiment among American Public School Principals.” Public Administration Review 81 (2): 244–59.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Phelps, Edmund S. 1972. “The Statistical Theory of Racism and Sexism.” The American Economic Review 62 (4): 659–61.Google Scholar
Pluss. 2012. Analyse af fordelingsudvalgenes rolle og praksis. Technical Report, Prepared for the Danish Ministry of Education.Google Scholar
Reny, Tyler T., and Newman, Benjamin J.. 2021. “The Opinion-Mobilizing Effect of Social Protest against Police Violence: Evidence from the 2020 George Floyd Protests.” American Political Science Review 115 (4): 14991507.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Schneider, Anne, and Ingram, Helen. 1993. “Social Construction of Target Populations: Implications for Politics and Policy.” American Political Science Review 87 (2): 334–47.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Schneider, Silke L. 2008. “Anti-Immigrant Attitudes in Europe: Outgroup Size and Perceived Ethnic Threat.” European Sociological Review 24 (1): 5367.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Schram, Sanford F., Soss, Joe, Fording, Richard C., and Houser, Linda. 2009. “Deciding to Discipline: Race, Choice, and Punishment at the Frontlines of Welfare Reform.” American Sociological Review 74 (3): 398422.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Soss, Joe. 1999. “Lessons of Welfare: Policy Design, Political Learning, and Political Action.” American Political Science Review 93 (2): 363–80.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Spencer, Katherine B., Charbonneau, Amanda K., and Glaser, Jack. 2016. “Implicit Bias and Policing.” Social and Personality Psychology Compass 10 (1): 5063.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Tiebout, Charles M. 1956. “A Pure Theory of Local Expenditures.” Journal of Political Economy 64 (5): 416–24.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Vedung, Evert. 2011. “Policy Instrument Typologies and Theories.” In Carrots, Sticks, and Sermons: Policy Instruments and Their Evaluation, eds. Bemelmans-Videc, Marie-Louise, Rist, Ray C., and Vedung, Evert, 21–58. New Brunswick, NJ: Transaction Publishers.Google Scholar
Villadsen, Anders R., and Wulff, Jesper N.. 2017. “Is the Public Sector a Fairer Employer? Ethnic Employment Discrimination in the Public and Private Sectors.” Academy of Management Discoveries 4 (4): 429–48.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Weber, Max. 1947. The Theory of Social and Economic Organization. New York: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
White, Ariel R., Nathan, Noah L., and Faller, Julie K.. 2015. “What Do I Need to Vote? Bureaucratic Discretion and Discrimination by Local Election Officials.” American Political Science Review 109 (1): 129–42.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Wooldridge, Jeffrey M. 2010. Econometric Analysis of Cross Section and Panel Data, 2nd ed. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.Google Scholar
Ziller, Conrad, and Helbling, Marc. 2019. “Antidiscrimination Laws, Policy Knowledge and Political Support.” British Journal of Political Science 49 (3): 1027–44.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Figure 0

Figure 1. Theoretical Models for the Relationship between User Demand, Pay Per User, Cost Per User, and Quantity of Provided Units of Service under a Choice and Competition Funding SystemNote: The y-axis indicates price and the x-axis indicates quantity. D1 and D2 indicate different levels of fixed demand. P1 and P2 indicate fixed levels of pay per user. “Supply Cap” indicates a fixed cap for the supply quantity. The diagonal line illustrates the increasing marginal cost per user. Panel A depicts a situation with complete supply-side flexibility, and Panel B depicts a situation where a supply cap is introduced.

Figure 1

Table 1. Pay Per User in High School, 2009–2010

Figure 2

Table 2. Descriptive Statistics Prereform and Postreform

Figure 3

Figure 2. Descriptives for First-Priority Enrollment Rates and Enrolled StudentsNote: Panel A represents raw rates of enrollment in first-priority high schools by the minority status during the period 2009–2012. The vertical lines represent 95% confidence intervals. Panel B depicts the average number of students enrolled in high schools during the period 2007–2012 (gray line, right y-axis) and share of non-Western students enrolled (black line, left y-axis). The vertical dashed line indicates the timing of the reform.

Figure 4

Table 3. Enrolled in First-Priority High School, Non-Western Applicant and Reform

Figure 5

Figure 3. Predicted Enrollment Rates by Minority Status Prereform and Postreform and Difference-in-Difference EstimatesNote: Panel A shows predicted enrollment rates by minority status prereform and postreform based on Table 3, Model 6. Differences and difference-in-difference estimates are above the horizontal bracket. The vertical lines represent 95% confidence intervals. Panel B shows difference-in-difference estimates for different specifications based on Model 6 in Table 3 above and Model 6 in Tables A.6, A.7, A.8, A.9, and A.10 in the supplementary materials. The horizontal lines represent 95% confidence intervals. All estimates are based on standard errors clustered at the high school level.*p < 0.05, **p < 0.01, ***p < 0.001.

Figure 6

Table 4. High School Completion for Enrolled Students

Supplementary material: Link
Link
Supplementary material: PDF

Guul supplementary material

Guul supplementary material

Download Guul supplementary material(PDF)
PDF 162.3 KB
Submit a response

Comments

No Comments have been published for this article.