Hostname: page-component-cd9895bd7-jn8rn Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-12-16T21:01:24.904Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

The cultural evolution of prosocial religions

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  02 December 2014

Ara Norenzayan
Affiliation:
Department of Psychology, University of British Columbia, Vancouver, BC V6T 1Z4, Canadaara@psych.ubc.cahttp://www.psych.ubc.ca/~ara/
Azim F. Shariff
Affiliation:
Department of Psychology, University of Oregon, Eugene, OR 97403shariff@uoregon.eduhttp://sharifflab.com/
Will M. Gervais
Affiliation:
Department of Psychology, University of Kentucky, Lexington, KY 40506will.gervais@uky.eduhttps://psychology.as.uky.edu/users/wmge223
Aiyana K. Willard
Affiliation:
Department of Psychology, University of Texas at Austin, Austin, TX 78712aiyana@psych.ubc.cawww.aiyanawillard.com
Rita A. McNamara
Affiliation:
Department of Psychology, University of British Columbia, Vancouver, BC V6T 1Z4, Canadaramcnama@psych.ubc.cahttp://rita.psych.ubc.ca
Edward Slingerland
Affiliation:
Department of Asian Studies, University of British Columbia, Vancouver, BC V6T 1Z2, Canadaedward.slingerland@gmail.comhttp://faculty.arts.ubc/eslingerland
Joseph Henrich
Affiliation:
Departments of Psychology and Economics, University of British Columbia, Vancouver, BC V6T 1Z4, Canadajoseph.henrich@gmail.comhttp://www.psych.ubc.ca/~henrich/ Department of Human Evolutionary Biology, Harvard University, Cambridge, MA 02138
Rights & Permissions [Opens in a new window]

Abstract

We develop a cultural evolutionary theory of the origins of prosocial religions and apply it to resolve two puzzles in human psychology and cultural history: (1) the rise of large-scale cooperation among strangers and, simultaneously, (2) the spread of prosocial religions in the last 10–12 millennia. We argue that these two developments were importantly linked and mutually energizing. We explain how a package of culturally evolved religious beliefs and practices characterized by increasingly potent, moralizing, supernatural agents, credible displays of faith, and other psychologically active elements conducive to social solidarity promoted high fertility rates and large-scale cooperation with co-religionists, often contributing to success in intergroup competition and conflict. In turn, prosocial religious beliefs and practices spread and aggregated as these successful groups expanded, or were copied by less successful groups. This synthesis is grounded in the idea that although religious beliefs and practices originally arose as nonadaptive by-products of innate cognitive functions, particular cultural variants were then selected for their prosocial effects in a long-term, cultural evolutionary process. This framework (1) reconciles key aspects of the adaptationist and by-product approaches to the origins of religion, (2) explains a variety of empirical observations that have not received adequate attention, and (3) generates novel predictions. Converging lines of evidence drawn from diverse disciplines provide empirical support while at the same time encouraging new research directions and opening up new questions for exploration and debate.

Type
Target Article
Copyright
Copyright © Cambridge University Press 2016 

1. Introduction: Two related puzzles

The vast majority of humans today live in large-scale, anonymous societies. This is a remarkable and puzzling fact because, prior to roughly 12,000 years ago,Footnote 1 most people lived in relatively small-scale tribal societies (Johnson & Earle Reference Johnson and Earle2000), which themselves had emerged from even smaller-scale primate troops (Chapais Reference Chapais2008). This dramatic scaling up appears to be linked to changes that occurred after the stabilization of global climates at the beginning of the Holocene, when food production began to gradually replace hunting and foraging, and the scale of human societies started to expand (Richerson et al. Reference Richerson, Boyd and Bettinger2001). Even the earliest cities and towns in the Middle East, not to mention today's vast metropolises with tens of millions of people, contrast sharply with the networks of foraging bands that have characterized most of the human lineage's evolutionary history (Hill et al. Reference Hill, Walker, Božičević, Eder, Headland, Hewlett, Hurtado, Marlowe, Wiessner and Wood2011).

The rise of stable, large, cooperative societies is one of the great puzzles of human history, because the free-rider problem intensifies as groups expand. Proto-moral sentiments that are rooted in kin selection and reciprocal altruism have ancient evolutionary origins in the primate lineage (de Waal Reference de Waal2008), and disapproval of antisocial behavior emerges even in preverbal babies (Bloom Reference Bloom2013; Hamlin et al. Reference Hamlin, Wynn and Bloom2007). However, neither kin selection nor reciprocal altruism (including partner-choice mechanisms) can explain the rise of large, cooperative, anonymous societies (Chudek & Henrich Reference Chudek and Henrich2011; Chudek et al. Reference Chudek, Zhao, Henrich, Joyce, Sterelny and Calcott2013). Genealogical relatedness decreases geometrically with increasing group size, and strategies based on direct or indirect reciprocity fail in expanding groups (Boyd & Richerson Reference Boyd and Richerson1988) or as reputational information becomes increasingly noisy or unavailable (Panchanathan & Boyd Reference Panchanathan and Boyd2003). Without additional mechanisms to galvanize cooperation, groups collapse, fission, or feud, as has been shown repeatedly in small-scale societies (Forge Reference Forge, Ucko, Tringham and Dimbelby1972; Tuzin Reference Tuzin2001). Our first puzzle, then, is how some groups, made up of individuals equipped with varying temperaments and motivations, which evolved and calibrated for life in relatively small-scale ancestral societies, were able to dramatically expand their size and scale of cooperation while sustaining mutually beneficial exchange. How was this feat possible on a time scale of thousands of years, a rate too slow to be driven by demographic growth processes and too fast for substantial genetic evolution?Footnote 2

Consider our second puzzle. Over the same time period, prosocial religions emerged and spread worldwide, to the point that the overwhelming majority of believers today are the cultural descendants of a very few such religions. These religions elicit deep devotions and extravagant rituals, often directed at Big Gods: powerful, morally concerned deities who are believed to monitor human behavior. These gods are believed to deliver rewards and punishments according to how well people meet the particular, often local, behavioral standards, including engaging in costly actions that benefit others. Whereas there is little dispute that foraging societies possess beliefs in supernatural agents, these spirits and deities are quite different from those of world religions, with only limited powers and circumscribed concerns about human morality. It appears that interrelated religious elements that sustain faith in Big Gods have spread globally along with the expansion of complex, large-scale human societies. This has occurred despite their rarity in small-scale societies or during most of our species' evolutionary history (Norenzayan Reference Norenzayan2013; Swanson Reference Swanson1960).

Connecting these two puzzles, we argue that cultural evolution, driven by the escalating intergroup competition particularly associated with settled societies, promoted the selection and assembly of suites of religious beliefs and practices that characterize modern prosocial religions. Prosocial religions have contributed to large-scale cooperation, but they are only one among several likely causes. Religious elements are not a necessary condition for cooperation or moral behavior of any scale (Bloom Reference Bloom2012; Norenzayan Reference Norenzayan2014). There are several other cultural evolutionary paths to large-scale cooperation, including institutions, norms, and practices unrelated to prosocial religions. These include political decision making (e.g., inherited leadership positions), social organization (e.g., segmentary lineage systems), property rights, division of labor (e.g., castes), and exchange and markets. The causal effects of religious elements can interact with all of these domains and institutions, and this causality can run in both directions, in a feedback loop between prosocial religions and an expanded cooperative sphere.

This cultural evolutionary process selects for any psychological traits, norms, or practices that (1) reduce competition among individuals and families within social groups; (2) sustain or increase group solidarity; and (3) facilitate differential success in competition and conflict between social groups by increasing cooperation in warfare, defense, demographic expansion, or economic ventures. This success can then lead to the differential spread of particular religious elements, as more successful groups are copied by less successful groups, experience physical or cultural immigration, expand demographically through higher rates of reproduction, or expand through conquest and assimilation. It was this cultural evolutionary process that increasingly intertwined the “supernatural” with the “moral” and the “prosocial.” For this reason, we refer to these culturally selected and now dominant clusters of elements as prosocial religions. Footnote 3

We have been developing the converging lines of this argument over several years in several places (e.g., Atran & Henrich Reference Atran and Henrich2010; Henrich Reference Henrich2009; Norenzayan Reference Norenzayan2013; Norenzayan & Shariff Reference Norenzayan and Shariff2008; Slingerland et al. Reference Slingerland, Henrich, Norenzayan, Richerson and Christiansen2013). Here, we synthesize and update this prior work and further develop several empirical, theoretical, and conceptual aspects of it. Empirically, we discuss the historical and ethnographic evidence at greater depth and lay out the findings from a new meta-analysis of religious priming studies that specify underlying psychological processes and boundary conditions. Theoretically, we discuss in greater detail one key part of the process that we hypothesize gave rise to prosocial religions: cultural group selection. We also integrate sacred values into our framework, review alternative scenarios linking some religious elements with large-scale societies, and tackle counterarguments. Overall, we bring together evidence from available historical and ethnographic observation with experimental studies that address several interrelated topics, including signaling, ritual, religious priming, cognitive foundations of religion, behavioral economics, cooperation, and cultural learning.

This account paves the way for a cognitive–evolutionary synthesis, consolidating several key insights. These include (1) how innate cognitive mechanisms gave rise, as a by-product, to supernatural mental representations (Atran & Norenzayan Reference Atran and Norenzayan2004; Barrett Reference Barrett2000; Boyer Reference Boyer2001; Lawson & McCauley Reference Lawson and McCauley1990; McCauley Reference McCauley2011); (2) how natural selection shaped cognitive abilities for cultural learning, making humans a culture-dependent species with divergent cultural evolutionary trajectories (Richerson & Boyd Reference Richerson and Boyd2005); and (3) how intergroup competition shaped cultural evolution, giving rise to cultural group selection and gene–culture coevolution (Chudek & Henrich Reference Chudek and Henrich2011; Henrich Reference Henrich2004). We hypothesize that by building on these foundations, cultural evolution has harnessed a variety of proximate psychological mechanisms to shape and consolidate human beliefs, actions, and commitments that converge in increasingly prosocial religions. The result is an account that recognizes, synthesizes, and extends earlier and contemporary insights about the social functions of religious elements (Durkheim Reference Durkheim1915; Haidt Reference Haidt2012; Rappaport Reference Rappaport1999; Sosis & Alcorta Reference Sosis and Alcorta2003; Wilson Reference Wilson2003).

We begin with the idea that religious elements arose as a nonadaptive evolutionary by-product of ordinary cognitive functions (Atran & Norenzayan Reference Atran and Norenzayan2004; Barrett Reference Barrett2004; Bloom Reference Bloom2004; Boyer Reference Boyer1994). However, we move beyond cognitive by-product approaches by tackling historical trajectories and cross-cultural trends in religious beliefs and behaviors, particularly dominant elements of modern religions that are hard to explain in the absence of cultural evolutionary processes and selective cultural transmission. We argue that although religious representations are rooted in innate aspects of cognition, only some of the possible cultural variants then spread at the expense of other variants because of their effects on success in intergroup competition.

Drawing on contributions from adaptationist approaches to religion (Bering Reference Bering2006; Reference Bering2011; Bulbulia Reference Bulbulia, Bulbulia, Richard, Genet, Harris, Wynan and Genet2008; Cronk Reference Cronk1994; Johnson & Bering Reference Johnson and Bering2006; Johnson Reference Johnson and Levin2009; Sosis & Alcorta Reference Sosis and Alcorta2003; Sosis & Bulbulia Reference Sosis and Bulbulia2011), we take seriously the important role that religious elements appear to play in shaping the lives of individuals and societies, and we recognize that there are crucial linkages among rituals, belief in supernatural monitors, and cooperation that these approaches have illuminated across diverse environmental and cultural contexts. Our contribution builds on evolved psychological mechanisms, but it also explores in great detail the cultural learning dynamics and the historical processes that shape religions and rituals in both adaptive and maladaptive ways. We therefore argue that our framework reconciles key aspects and insights from the adaptationist and by-product approaches. It also tackles a range of empirical observations, including some that have not been adequately addressed, and generates novel predictions ripe for investigation. As such, we present this synthesis as an invitation for a conversation and debate about core issues in the evolutionary study of religion.

2. Theoretical foundations

Our synthesis rests on four conceptual foundations: (1) the reliable development of cognitive mechanisms that constrain and influence the transmission of religious beliefs; (2) evolved social instincts that drive concerns about third-party monitoring, which in turn facilitate belief in and response to supernatural monitoring; (3) cultural learning mechanisms that guide the spread of specific religious contents and behaviors; and (4) intergroup competition that influences the cultural evolution of religious beliefs and practices.

2.1. Reliably developing cognitive biases for religion

The cognitive science of religion has begun to show that religious beliefs are rooted in a suite of core cognitive faculties that reliably develop in individuals across populations and historical periods (Atran & Norenzayan Reference Atran and Norenzayan2004; Barrett Reference Barrett2004; Bloom Reference Bloom2012; Boyer Reference Boyer2001; Guthrie Reference Guthrie1993; Kirkpatrick Reference Kirkpatrick1999; Lawson & McCauley Reference Lawson and McCauley1990). As such, “religions” are best seen as constrained amalgams of beliefs and behaviors that are rooted in core cognitive tendencies. Examples of particular interest here are (1) mentalizing (Bering Reference Bering2011; Frith & Frith Reference Frith and Frith2003; Waytz et al. Reference Waytz, Gray, Epley and Wegner2010), (2) teleological thinking (Kelemen Reference Kelemen2004), and (3) mind–body dualism (Bloom Reference Bloom2007; Chudek et al. Reference Chudek, MacNamara, Birch, Bloom and Henrich2015). Consistent with these hypotheses, individual differences in these tendencies partly explain the degree to which people believe in God, in paranormal events, and in life's meaning and purpose (Willard & Norenzayan Reference Willard and Norenzayan2013).

These cognitive tendencies can be harnessed by cultural evolution (they provide potential raw material) in constructing particular elements of religions or other aspects of culture. However, cultural evolution need not harness all or any of these cognitive tendencies. Our argument is that some of them have been drafted by cultural evolution in more recent millennia to underpin particular supernatural beliefs, such as an afterlife contingent on proper behavior in this life, because those beliefs promoted success in intergroup competition, although none of those cognitive processes are solely or uniquely involved in religion.

Most relevant to prosocial religions is the evolved capacity for mentalizing (Epley & Waytz Reference Epley, Waytz, Fiske, Gilbert and Lindsay2010; Frith & Frith Reference Frith and Frith2003), which makes possible the cultural recruitment of supernatural agent beliefs (Gervais Reference Gervais2013). Mentalizing, also known as “theory of mind,” allows people to detect and infer the existence and content of other minds. It also supplies the cognitive basis for the pervasive belief in disembodied supernatural agents such as gods and spirits. Believers treat gods as beings who possess humanlike goals, beliefs, and desires (Barrett & Keil Reference Barrett and Keil1996; Bering Reference Bering2011; Bloom & Weisberg Reference Bloom and Weisberg2007; Epley et al. Reference Epley, Waytz and Cacioppo2007; Guthrie Reference Guthrie1993). This mentalizing capacity enables them to believe they interact with gods, who are thought to respond to existential anxieties, such as anxieties about death and randomness (Atran & Norenzayan Reference Atran and Norenzayan2004), and engage in social monitoring (Norenzayan & Shariff Reference Norenzayan and Shariff2008). Consistent with the by-product argument that religious thinking recruits ordinary capacities for mind perception, thinking about or praying to God activates brain regions associated with theory of mind (Kapogiannis et al. Reference Kapogiannis, Barbey, Su, Zamboni, Krueger and Grafman2009; Schjoedt et al. Reference Schjoedt, Stødkilde-Jørgensen, Geertz and Roepstorff2009); and reduced mentalizing tendencies or abilities, as found in the autistic spectrum, predicts reduced belief in God (Norenzayan et al. Reference Norenzayan, Gervais and Trzesniewski2012). Conversely, schizotypal tendencies that include promiscuous anthropomorphizing are associated with “hyper-religiosity” (Crespi & Badcock Reference Crespi and Badcock2008; Willard & Norenzayan Reference Willard and Norenzayan2015).

2.2. Social instincts and third-party monitoring

Humans likely evolved in a social world governed by community-wide norms or shared standards in which the community conducted surveillance for norm violations and sanctioning (Chudek & Henrich Reference Chudek and Henrich2011; Chudek et al. Reference Chudek, Zhao, Henrich, Joyce, Sterelny and Calcott2013). This reputational aspect of our norm psychology means that humans are sensitive to cues of social monitoring (Bering & Johnson Reference Bering and Johnson2005), attend keenly to social expectations and public observation (Fehr & Fischbacher Reference Fehr and Fischbacher2003), and anticipate a world governed by social rules with sanctions for norm violations (Chudek & Henrich Reference Chudek and Henrich2011; Fehr et al. Reference Fehr, Fischbacher and Gächter2002). Relevant empirical work indicates that sometimes exposure to even subtle cues, such as drawings of eyes, can increase compliance to norms related to fairness and not stealing (Haley & Fessler Reference Haley and Fessler2005; Rigdon et al. Reference Rigdon, Ishii, Watabe and Kitayama2009; Zhong et al. Reference Zhong, Bohns and Gino2010; but see Fehr & Schneider Reference Fehr and Schneider2010), even in naturalistic settings (Bateson et al. Reference Bateson, Nettle and Roberts2006). If the presence of human watchers encourages norm compliance, then it is not surprising that the suggestion of morally concerned supernatural watchers – with greater surveillance capacities and powers to punish – might expand norm compliance beyond that associated with mere human watchers and earthly sanctions (e.g., Bering Reference Bering2011). We argue that intergroup competition (discussed subsequently) exploits this feature of human social psychology, among others, to preferentially select belief systems with interventionist supernatural agents concerned about certain kinds of behaviors.

2.3. Cultural learning and the origins of faith

Humans are a cultural species (Boyd et al. Reference Boyd, Richerson and Henrich2011b). More than in any other species, human cultural learning generates vast bodies of know-how and complex practices that adaptively accumulate over generations (Tomasello Reference Tomasello2001). To have adaptive benefits, cultural learning involves placing faith in the products of this process and often overriding our innate intuitions or individual experiences (Beck Reference Beck1992; Henrich Reference Henrich2015). Children and adults from diverse societies accurately imitate adults' seemingly unnecessary behaviors (they “over-imitate”), even when they are capable of disregarding them (Lyons et al. Reference Lyons, Young and Keil2007; Nielsen & Tomaselli Reference Nielsen and Tomaselli2010). This willingness to rely on faith in cultural traditions – over personal experience or intuition – has profound implications for explaining key features of religions (Atran & Henrich Reference Atran and Henrich2010).

Much theoretical and empirical work suggests that, when deciding to place faith in cultural information over other sources, learners rely on a variety of cues that include the following:

  1. 1. Content-based mechanisms, which lead to the selective retention and transmission of some mental representations over others because of differences in their content (Boyer Reference Boyer2001; Sperber Reference Sperber1996). For example, emotionally evocative and socially relevant ideas are more memorable and, therefore, culturally contagious (Heath et al. Reference Heath, Bell and Sternberg2001; Stubbersfield et al. Reference Stubbersfield, Tehrani and Flynn2015; see also Broesch et al. Reference Broesch, Henrich and Barrett2014).

  2. 2. Context-based mechanisms (or model-based cultural learning biases), which arise from evolved psychological mechanisms that encourage learners to attend to and learn from particular individuals (cultural models) based on cues such as skill, success, prestige, self-similarity (Henrich & Gil-White Reference Henrich and Gil-White2001), and trait frequency (Perreault et al. Reference Perreault, Moya and Boyd2012; Rendell et al. Reference Rendell, Fogarty, Hoppitt, Morgan, Webster and Laland2011).

  3. 3. Credibility-enhancing displays (CREDs), or learners' sensitivity to cues that a cultural model is genuinely committed to his or her stated or advertised beliefs. If models engage in behaviors that would be unlikely if they privately held opposing beliefs, learners are more likely to trust the sincerity of the models and, as a result, adopt their beliefsFootnote 4 (Henrich Reference Henrich2009; see also Harris Reference Harris2012; Sperber et al. Reference Sperber, Clément, Heintz, Mascaro, Mercier, Origgi and Wilson2010).

All three classes of learning mechanisms are crucial to understanding how religious beliefs and practices are transmitted and stabilized, why certain rituals and devotions can substantially influence cultural transmission, and why some elements of religions are recurrent and others culturally variable (Gervais et al. Reference Gervais, Willard, Norenzayan and Henrich2011b). To date, content-based mechanisms have been the main focus and the source of much progress in the cognitive science of religion. This includes work on minimally counterintuitive concepts (Boyer & Ramble Reference Boyer and Ramble2001; but see Purzycki & Willard, Reference Purzycki and Willardin press), folk notions of mind–body dualism (Bloom Reference Bloom2004), and hyperactive agency detection (Barrett Reference Barrett2004). We argue, however, that context-based cultural learning and CREDs are equally important if we wish to construct a comprehensive account of the differential spread of religious beliefs and behaviors. For example, because people are biased to preferentially acquire religious beliefs and practices from the plurality and from prestigious models in their communities, identical or similar god concepts can be the object of deep commitment in one historical period but then a fictional character in another (Gervais & Henrich Reference Gervais and Henrich2010; Gervais et al. Reference Gervais, Willard, Norenzayan and Henrich2011b). Also, CREDs help us explain why religious ideas backed up by credible displays of commitment (such as fasts, sexual abstinence, and painful rituals) are more persuasive and more likely to spread. In turn, we see why such extravagant displays are commonly found in prosocial religions and tied to deepening commitment to supernatural agents. Moreover, core intuitions about supernatural beings and ritual-behavior complexes, once in place, coexist with other ordinary intuitions and causal schemata in everyday life (Legare et al. Reference Legare, Evans, Rosengren and Harris2012).

2.4. The cultural group selection of prosocial religions

We propose that prosocial religions are shaped by cultural group selection, a class of cultural evolutionary processes that considers the impact of intergroup competition on cultural evolutionary outcomes. These processes have been studied extensively and have a long intellectual history (Boyd & Richerson Reference Boyd, Richerson and Mansbridge1990; Darwin Reference Darwin1871; Hayek Reference Hayek and Bartley1988; Khaldun Reference Khaldun and Rosenthal1958). Intergroup competition has potentially been shaping cultural evolution over much of our species' evolutionary history, altering the genetic selection pressures molding the foundations of our sociality (Henrich Reference Henrich2015; Richerson & Boyd Reference Richerson and Boyd1999). However, as the origins of agriculture made large, settled, populations economically possible across diverse regions during the last 12 millennia, a regime of intensive intergroup competition ensued that increased the size and complexity of human societies (Alexander Reference Alexander1987; Bowles Reference Bowles2008; Carneiro Reference Carneiro1970; Currie & Mace Reference Currie and Mace2009; Otterbein Reference Otterbein1970; Turchin Reference Turchin2003; Turchin et al. Reference Turchin, Currie, Turner and Gavrilets2013).

A class of evolutionary models has revealed broad conditions under which cultural group selection can influence the trajectory of cultural evolution. Intergroup competition can operate through violent conflict, but also through differential migration into more successful groups, biased copying of practices and beliefs among groups, and differential extinction rates without any actual conflict (Richerson et al., Reference Richerson, Hillis, Newson, Baldini, Frost, Bell, Demps, Mathew, Newton, Narr, Ross, Smaldino, Waring and Zeffermanin press). These models show that the conditions under which intergroup competition substantially influences cultural evolution are much broader than for genetic evolution (Boyd et al. Reference Boyd, Gintis and Richerson2003; Reference Boyd, Richerson and Henrich2011a; Guzman et al. Reference Guzman, Rodriguez-Sickert and Rowthorn2007; Henrich & Boyd Reference Henrich and Boyd2001; Smaldino Reference Smaldino2014). This is in part because cultural evolution can sustain behavioral variation among groups, which drives the evolutionary process to a degree that genetic evolution does not (Bell et al. Reference Bell, Richerson and McElreath2009; Henrich Reference Henrich2012; Richerson et al., Reference Richerson, Hillis, Newson, Baldini, Frost, Bell, Demps, Mathew, Newton, Narr, Ross, Smaldino, Waring and Zeffermanin press).

Empirically, there are several converging lines of evidence supporting the importance of intergroup competition, including data from laboratory studies (Gurerk et al. Reference Gürerk, Irlenbusch and Rockenbach2006; Saaksvuori et al. Reference Saaksvuori, Mappes and Puurtinen2011), archaeology (Flannery & Marcus Reference Flannery and Marcus2000; Spencer & Redmond Reference Spencer and Redmond2001), history (Turchin Reference Turchin2003; Turchin et al. Reference Turchin, Currie, Turner and Gavrilets2013), and ethnographic or ethnohistorical studies (Atran Reference Atran2002; Boyd Reference Boyd2001; Currie & Mace Reference Currie and Mace2009; Kelly Reference Kelly1985; Soltis et al. Reference Soltis, Boyd and Richerson1995; Wiessner & Tumu Reference Wiessner and Tumu1998). See Richerson et al. (Reference Richerson, Hillis, Newson, Baldini, Frost, Bell, Demps, Mathew, Newton, Narr, Ross, Smaldino, Waring and Zeffermanin press) for a recent review, and Henrich (Reference Henrich2015) for the importance of intergroup competition among hunter–gatherers.

Although these studies provide evidence of the competitive process in action, experimental evidence reveals that larger and more economically successful groups have stronger prosocial norms: a pattern consistent with cultural group selection models. For example, in a global sample of roughly a dozen diverse populations, individuals from larger ethnolinguistic groups and larger communities were more willing to incur a cost to punish unfair offers in experimental games (Henrich et al. Reference Henrich, Ensimger, McElreath, Barr, Barrett, Bolyanatz, Cardenas, Gurven, Gwako, Henrich, Lesorogol, Marlowe, Tracer and Ziker2010a; Reference Henrich, Ensminger, Barr, McElreath, Ensminger and Henrich2014), a result that held after controlling for a range of economic and demographic variables (see also Marlowe et al. Reference Marlowe, Berbesque, Barr, Barrett, Bolyanatz, Cardenas, Ensminger, Gurven, Gwako, Henrich, Henrich, Lesorogol, McElreath and Tracer2008). Even among Hadza foragers, larger camps are more often prosocial in economic games (Marlowe Reference Marlowe, Henrich, Boyd, Bowles, Camerer, Fehr and Gintis2004). Similarly, in a detailed study in Tanzania, Paciotti and Hadley (Reference Paciotti and Hadley2003) compared the economic game playing of two ethnolinguistic groups living side by side, the Pimbwe and the Sukuma. The institutionally more complex Sukuma had been rapidly expanding their territory over several generations, and they played much more prosocially in the Ultimatum Game than did the Pimbwe. Cross-nationally, experimental work also reveals a negative correlation between gross domestic product (GDP) per capita and both people's motivations to punish cooperators in a public goods game (stifling cooperation) and their willingness to cheat to favor themselves or their local “in” group (Hermann et al. Reference Herrmann, Thoni and Gächter2008; Hruschka et al. Reference Hruschka, Efferson, Jiang, Falletta-Cowden, Sigurdsson, McNamara, Sands, Munira, Slingerland and Henrich2014).

Broadly speaking, therefore, cultural group selection favors complexes of culturally transmitted traits – beliefs, values, practices, rituals, and devotions – that (1) reduce competition and variation within social groups (sustaining or increasing social cohesion) and (2) enhance success in competition with other social groups, by increasing factors such as group size, cooperative intensity, fertility, economic output, and bravery in warfare. Thus, any cultural traits – connected to the supernatural or not – that directly or indirectly promoted parochial prosociality in expanded groups (Bowles Reference Bowles2006; Choi & Bowles Reference Choi and Bowles2007) could be favored. The issue at hand is whether the crucible of intensive cultural group selection that emerged with the origins of agriculture shaped the beliefs, commitments, institutions, and practices associated with religions in predictable ways over the last 12 millennia.Footnote 5

2.5. The theoretical synthesis

We build on these four foundations to construct a synthetic view of modern world religions. We begin from the premise that religious beliefs and behaviors originated as evolutionary by-products of ordinary cognitive tendencies, built on reliably developing panhuman cognitive templates. Some subset of these cultural variants happened to have incidental effects on within-group prosociality by increasing cooperation, solidarity, and group size. Such variants may have spread first, allowing groups to expand and economically succeed, or they may have spread in the wake of a group's successful expansion, subsequently adding sustainability to a group's cultural success. Competition among cultural groups, operating over millennia, gradually aggregated these elements into cultural packages (“religions”) that were increasingly likely to include the following:

  1. 1. Belief in, and commitment to, powerful, all-knowing, and morally concerned supernatural agents who are believed to monitor social interactions and to reward and sanction behaviors in ways that contribute to the cultural success of the group, including practices that effectively transmit the faith. Rhetorically, we call these “Big Gods,” but we alert readers that we are referring to a multidimensional continuum of supernatural agents in which Big Gods occupy a particular corner of the space. By outsourcing some monitoring and punishing duties to these supernatural agents, prosocial religions reduce monitoring costs and facilitate collective action, which allows groups to sustain in-group cooperation and harmony while expanding in size.

  2. 2. Ritual and devotional practices that effectively elevate prosocial sentiments, galvanize solidarity, and transmit and signal deep faith. These practices exploit human psychology in a host of different ways, including synchrony to build in-group solidarity, CREDs and signals (e.g., sacrifices, painful initiations, celibacy, fasting), and other cultural learning biases (conformity, prestige, and age) to more effectively transmit commitment to others.

  3. 3. Additional beliefs and practices that exploit aspects of psychology to galvanize group cohesion and increase success. These include fictive kinship for coreligionists; in-group (“ethnic”) markers to spark tribal psychology, exclude the less committed, and mark religious boundaries; pronatalist norms that increase fertility rates; practices that increase self-control and the suppression of self-interest; and seeing a divine origin in certain beliefs and practices, transforming them into “sacred” values that are nonnegotiable.

2.6. Hypotheses

Here we list some specific hypotheses that follow from the present theoretical framework.

  1. 1. Big Gods spread because they contributed to the expansion of cooperative groups. Historically, they coevolved gradually with larger and increasingly more complex societies. In turn, larger and more complex societies might have been more likely to transmit and sustain belief in such gods, creating autocatalytic processes that energized each other. One consequence of this process is that group size and long-term stability should positively correlate with the prevalence of Big Gods.

  2. 2. All things being equal, commitment to Big Gods should produce more norm compliance in difficult-to-monitor situations, relative to belief in supernatural agents that are unable or unwilling to omnisciently monitor and punish.

  3. 3. Religious behavior that signals genuine devotion to the same or similar gods would be expected to induce greater cooperation and trust among religious members. Conversely, a lack of any devotion to any moralizing deities (i.e., atheism or amoral supernatural agents) should trigger distrust.

  4. 4. These cultural packages include rituals and devotions that exploit costly and extravagant displays to deepen commitment to Big Gods, as well as other solidarity and self-control-building cultural technologies (e.g., synchrony, repetition) and cultural learning biases (e.g., prestige) that more effectively transmit the belief system.

  5. 5. Cultural groups with this particular constellation of beliefs, norms, and behaviors (i.e., prosocial religious groups) should enjoy a relative cultural survival advantage, especially when intergroup competition over resources and adherents is fierce.

In the sections that follow, we confront these hypotheses with the available empirical data.

To address these hypotheses, we first draw on a combination of ethnographic, historical, and archaeological data to show exactly how different modern prosocial religions are from the religions of small-scale societies, and likely from those of our Paleolithic ancestors. This difference is important, because much theorizing by psychologists about the origins of religion often presumes that modern gods are culturally typical gods rather than being the products of a particular cultural evolutionary trajectory. Second, we examine the relationship between commitment to modern world religions and prosocial behavior by reviewing correlational data from surveys and behavioral studies, as well as experimental findings from religious priming studies to address causality. Third, we examine religion's role in building intragroup trust, as well as commitment mechanisms that galvanize social solidarity and transmit faith. Fourth, we evaluate evidence for the cultural group selection of prosocial religions. Finally, we situate this framework within existing evolutionary perspectives, address counter-explanations and alternative cultural evolutionary scenarios, discuss secularization, and conclude with outstanding questions and future directions.

3. Big Gods and ritual forms emerge and support large-scale societies

The anthropological record indicates that, in moving from the smallest scale human societies to the largest and most complex societies, the following empirical patterns emerge: (1) beliefs in Big Gods change from being relatively rare to being increasingly common, as these supernatural agents gain more power, knowledge, and concern about morality; (2) morality and supernatural beliefs move from being mostly disconnected to being increasingly intertwined; (3) rituals become increasingly organized, repetitious, and regular; (4) supernatural punishments are increasingly focused on violations of group beneficial norms (e.g., prohibiting theft from coreligionists, including those who are strangers, or demanding faith-deepening sacrifices); and (5) the potency of supernatural punishment and reward increases for key social norms (e.g., salvation, karma, hell, and heaven). These patterns are supported by both ethnographic and historical evidence.

3.1. Anthropological evidence

Quantitative and qualitative reviews of the anthropological record suggest that the gods of small-scale societies, especially those found in the foraging societies often associated with life in the Paleolithic, are typically cognitively constrained and have limited or no concern with human affairs or moral transgressions (Boehm Reference Boehm, Bulbulia, Sosis, Harris, Genet, Genet and Wyman2008; Boyer Reference Boyer2001; Swanson Reference Swanson1960; Wright Reference Wright2009). For example, among the much studied hunter-gatherers of the Kalahari region, Marshall (Reference Marshall1962) wrote, “Man's wrong-doing against man is not left to Gao!na's [the relevant god's] punishment nor is it considered to be his concern. Man corrects or avenges such wrong-doings himself in his social context”Footnote 6 (p. 245). Although some of these gods are pleased with rituals or sacrifices offered to them, they play a small or no part in the elaborate cooperative lives of foraging societies, and they rarely concern themselves with norm violations, including how community members treat each other or strangers. However, as the size and complexity of societies increase, more powerful, interventionist, and moralizing gods begin to appear. Quantitative analyses of the available anthropological databases, including the Standard Cross Cultural Sample (SCCS), which provides data for 167 societies, selected to reduce historical relationships, and the Ethnographic Atlas (724 societies), show positive correlations between the prevalence of Big Gods and societal size, complexity, population density, and external threats (Roes Reference Roes1995; Roes & Raymond Reference Roes and Raymond2003; Reference Roes and Raymond2009). These quantitative data also show that powerful moralizing gods appear in <10% of the smallest-scale human societies but become widespread in large-scale societies (see Fig. 1). This empirical finding dates back to Swanson (Reference Swanson1960), and despite critiques (Underhill Reference Underhill1975) and the statistical control of potential confounding variables (e.g., missionary activity, population density, economic inequality, geographic regions), the basic finding still holds.

Figure 1. Increasing prevalence of Big Gods as a function of social group size in the Standard Cross Cultural Sample (reprinted from Evolution and Human Behavior, Roes, F. L. & Raymond, M., Vol. 24, issue 2, Belief in moralizing gods, pp. 126–35, copyright 2003, with permission from Elsevier.).

Other researchers have arrived at similar conclusions. Stark (Reference Stark2001), for example, found that only 23.9% of 427 preindustrial societies in the Ethnographic Atlas (Murdock Reference Murdock1981) possess a god that was active in human affairs and was specifically supportive of human morality. Johnson's (Reference Johnson2005) analysis supports earlier results, and it also reveals correlations linking the presence of powerful moralizing gods to variables related to exchange, policing, and cooperation in larger, more complex societies (see also Sanderson & Roberts Reference Sanderson and Roberts2008). Such gods are also more prevalent in societies with water scarcity, another key threat to group survival (Snarey Reference Snarey1996). In a different analysis, Peoples and Marlowe (Reference Peoples and Marlowe2012) found several statistically independent predictors of Big Gods: (1) society size, (2) agricultural mode of subsistence, and (3) animal husbandry. Botero et al. (Reference Botero, Gardner, Kirby, Bulbulia, Gavin and Gray2014) arrived at similar conclusions. Using high-resolution bioclimactic data, and after controlling for the potential nonindependence among societies, they found that, in addition to the previously examined predictors, societies with greater exposure to ecological duress are more likely to have a cultural belief in powerful moralizing gods. More stratified societies are also more likely to support such Big Gods, but this effect sometimes drops out in the presence of mode of subsistence and community size. Nevertheless, it has been hypothesized that one way that prosocial religions maintain social cohesion in expanding groups is by legitimizing authority, inequality, and hierarchical relations (e.g., Peoples & Marlowe Reference Peoples and Marlowe2012; Turchin Reference Turchin2011). In the absence of much intergroup competition, those factors can lead to exploitation by the elite. However, under intergroup competition, cultural evolution may favor such legitimizing beliefs to both sustain solidarity and reinforce command and control during crises. Overall, far from being a reliably developing product of evolved human cognition, the modern popularity of Big Gods is a historical and anthropological puzzle (Tylor Reference Tylor1871), and one that requires explanation.

We emphasize that, although these analyses typically impose a dichotomy on the ethnographic data, our theoretical approach treats them as a continuum, and it focuses on how intergroup competition influences the selection of cultural elements. For example, although most chiefdoms in Oceania do not possess what would be coded as a “moralizing high god,” there are ethnographic reasons to suspect that elements of mana and tapu, and supernatural punishment, may have been influenced by intergroup competition. These elements may have helped stabilize political leadership and may have kept people adhering to increasingly costly social norms. Archaeological and historical evidence, for example, indicates that the spread of divine kingship, spurred by interisland competition, was crucial for the emergence of a state in Hawaii (Kirch Reference Kirch2010). In the Fijian chiefdoms that we study ethnographically and experimentally, the strength of villagers' beliefs in punishing ancestor gods increases in-group biases in economic games (McNamara et al. Reference McNamara, Norenzayan and Henrich2016).

Organized rituals also follow a parallel pattern across societies. In an analysis using the Human Relations Area Files, Atkinson and Whitehouse (Reference Atkinson and Whitehouse2011) found that “doctrinal” rituals – the high-frequency, low-arousal rituals commonly found in modern world religions (Whitehouse Reference Whitehouse2004) – are associated with greater belief in Big Gods, reliance on agriculture, and societal complexity. We argue that, among other important roles, doctrinal rituals galvanize faith and deepen commitments to large, anonymous communities governed by these powerful gods.

3.2. Archaeological and historical evidence

These comparative anthropological insights converge with archaeological and historical evidence, suggesting that both Big Gods and routinized rituals and related practices coevolved with large, complex human societies, along with increasing reliance on food production.

3.2.1. Archaeological evidence

Although supernatural beliefs are hard to infer archaeologically, and such evidence should, therefore, be interpreted with caution, the material record in Mesoamerica indicates that rituals became more formal, elaborate, and costly as societies developed from foraging bands into chiefdoms and states (Marcus & Flannery Reference Marcus and Flannery2004). In Mexico before 4000 BP, for example, foraging societies relied on informal, unscheduled rituals just as modern foragers do (Lee Reference Lee1979). With the establishment of multivillage chiefdoms (4000–3000 BP), rituals expanded and distinct religious specialists emerged. After state formation in Mexico (2500 BP), key rituals were performed by a class of full-time priests using religious calendars and occupying temples built at immense costs. The same is also true of the earliest state-level societies of Mesopotamia after 5500 BP and India after 4500 BP. We find similar patterns in predynastic Egypt (6000–5000 BP) and China (4500–3500 BP), as well as in other North American chiefdoms. In China, for example, the beginning of the Bronze Age (ca. 1500 BCE) is accompanied by a radical elaboration in tomb architecture and burial practices of elites, indicating the emergence of highly centralized and stratified polities bound together by costly public religious ceremonies (Thote Reference Thote, Lagerwey and Kalinowski2009). Similar evidence for this can be found in Çatalhöyük, a 9500 BP Neolithic site in southern Anatolia (see Whitehouse & Hodder Reference Whitehouse, Hodder and Hodder2010).

3.2.2. Historical evidence

Once the written record begins, establishing links among large-scale cooperation, ritual elaboration, Big Gods, and morality becomes more tractable. To date, most of the historical work related to this topic focuses on the Abrahamic faiths. Wright (Reference Wright2009) provides a summary of textual evidence that reveals the gradual evolution of the Abrahamic god from a rather limited, whimsical, tribal war god – a subordinate in the Canaanite Pantheon – to the unitary, supreme, moralizing deity of two of the world's largest religious communities. We see the same dynamics at work in other major literate societies.

For example, although China has sometimes been portrayed as lacking moralizing gods, or even religion at all (Ames & Rosemont Reference Ames and Rosemont2009; Granet Reference Granet1934), scholars in recent years have begun systematically correcting that misconception (Clark & Winslett Reference Clark and Winslett2011; Slingerland Reference Slingerland2013). Although there are important ongoing debates about the importance of supernatural surveillance relative to other mechanisms (e.g., Sarkissian Reference Sarkissian2015), in the earliest Chinese societies for which written records exist, the worshipped pantheon includes both the actual ancestors of the royal line and a variety of nature gods and cultural heroes, all under the dominion of a supreme deity, the “Lord on High” (shangdi) or Heaven (tian). This Lord on High/Heaven was a Big God in our sense, wielding supreme power over the natural world, intervening at will in the affairs of humans, and intensely concerned with prosocial values. The ability of the royal family to rule was a direct result of its possessing the “Mandate” (lit. “order” or “charge”) of Heaven, the possession of which was – at least by 1000 BCE or thereabouts – seen as being linked to moral behavior and proper observance of costly sacrificial and other ritual duties.

Surveillance by morally concerned supernatural agents also appears as a prominent theme in early China. Even from the sparse records from the Shang Dynasty, it is apparent that the uniquely broad power of the Lord on High to command a variety of events in the world led the Shang kings to feel a particular urgency about placating Him with proper ritual offerings. When the Zhou polity began to fragment into a variety of independent, and often conflicting, states (770–256 BCE), supernatural surveillance and the threat of supernatural sanctions remained at the heart of interstate diplomacy and internal political and legal relations (Poo Reference Poo2009). Finally, the written record reveals an increasingly clear connection in early China between morality and religious commitments. The outlines of moral behavior had been dictated by Heaven and encoded in a set of social norms, and a failure to adhere to these norms – either in outward behavior or in one's inner life – was to invite supernatural punishment (Eno Reference Eno, Lagerwey and Kalinowski2009).

Similarly, although the highly organized Greek city states and Imperial Rome are sometimes portrayed as possessing only amoral and fickle deities (e.g., see Baumard & Boyer Reference Baumard and Boyer2013), modern scholarship is increasingly rejecting this picture as the result of later Christian apologists' desire to distance the new Christian religion from “paganism.” The gods of the Greek city-states received costly sacrifices, were the subject of elaborate rituals, and played an active role in enforcing oaths and supporting public morality (Mikalson Reference Mikalson2010, pp. 150–68). Although Roman religion did not have sacred scriptures or an explicit moral code that was considered to be the word of the gods, the deities of imperial Rome were seen by the populace as the guardians of what was right and virtuous (Rives Reference Rives2007, pp. 50–52, 105–31), and the gods were central enough to the public sphere that even the spatial layouts of Roman cities were created around temples dedicated to the major gods (Rives Reference Rives2007, pp. 110–11).

One of the challenges of large-scale societies involves the trust necessary for many forms of exchange and credit, particularly long-distance trade (Greif Reference Greif2006). Not surprisingly, several Roman gods played a pivotal role in regulating marketplaces and in overseeing economic transactions. Cults dedicated to Mercury and Hercules in second- and first-century-BCE Delos – an important maritime trade center – emphasized public oaths certified by supernatural surveillance and divine punishment to overcome cooperation dilemmas in long-distance trade relations (Rauh Reference Rauh1993). In earlier periods, Greek, Roman, Sumerian, and Egyptian gods were also deeply involved in regulating the economic and public spheres. In surveying the Mediterranean region, Silver, for example, wrote, “The economic role of the gods found important expression in their function as protectors of honest business practices. Some deities openly combated opportunism (self-interest pursued with guile) and lowered transaction costs by actively inculcating and enforcing professional standards” (Silver Reference Silver1995, p. 5). The gods also concerned themselves with public morality more broadly. In ancient Egypt, “The two components of the general concept of religion, and at the same time the central functions of kingship, are (1) ethics and the dispensing of justice (the creation of solidarity and abundance in the social sphere through dispensing justice, care, and provisions) and (2) religion in the narrower sense, pacifying the gods and maintaining adequate contact with them, as well as provisioning the dead” (Assmann Reference Assmann2001, p. 5).

The so-called karmic religions (Hinduism, Buddhism, Jainism) also reflect historical convergences between religion and public morality, although the precise psychological mechanisms are not as well understood as for the Abrahamic religions. Obeyesekere (Reference Obeyesekere2002) observes that the notion of rebirth is present in many small-scale societies – but disconnected from morality. Gradually, rebirth connects with the idea of ethical causation across lifetimes, and begins to influence the cooperative sphere. In a seminal field study with modern Hindu samples, participation and observation of extreme Hindu rituals such as the Kavadi, practiced among devotees of the Tamil war god Murugan, increased prosocial behavior (Xygalatas et al. Reference Xygalatas, Mitkidis, Fischer, Reddish, Skewes, Geertz, Roepstorff and Bulbulia2013). A Hindu religious environment was also shown to induce greater prosocial behavior in a common resource pool game (Xygalatas Reference Xygalatas2013). Karmic religions are, therefore, also compatible with the prosocial religious elements in the present framework, although cultural evolution may be harnessing a somewhat different psychology, a question that is ripe for experimental research.

3.2.3. The “Axial Age.”

The “Axial Age” refers to the period between 800 and 200 BCE that marked the birth of “genuine” public morality, individuality, and interior spirituality (Jaspers Reference Jaspers and Bullock1953). Since Jaspers, a common view of the historical record has been that there is a vast cultural chasm between pre–Axial Age amoral religions – demanding mere external ritual observance from their adherents –and Axial Age moral religions, a view some in the cognitive science of religion (e.g., Baumard & Boyer Reference Baumard and Boyer2013) have echoed. This interpretation is historically questionable on several fronts. To begin with, it fails to recognize the gradual nature of cultural evolution: Chiefdoms and early states predating the Axial Age by thousands of years had anthropomorphized deities that intervened in social relations, although their moral scope and powers to punish and reward were substantially narrower and more tribal than those of later, Axial gods. This is also true in contemporary Fijian chiefdom societies, as we noted in section 3.1. More plausibly, then, there has been a coevolution of two gradual historical processes: the broadening of the gods' powers and their moral concern, and an expansion of the cooperative sphere.

Moreover, the sheer length of this supposedly crucial historical period should itself raise suspicions about its usefulness as an explanatory category. The transition to prosocial religions emerges at very different time periods in various parts of the globe. Islam, for example, is a classic example of what we are calling a prosocial religion, both in terms of its doctrinal and ritualistic features and its apparent role in forging the disparate, warring tribes in the Arabian Peninsula into a unified, world historical force. Islam did not get its start until the sixth century CE, a full 800 years after the close of the “Axial Age.”

Finally, there is ample historical evidence that elements of “pre–Axial Age” religions were supportive of public morality. In ancient Egyptian religion, for example, moral behavior was seen as part of Maat, the supernaturally grounded “right order” of the world. One of the Coffin Texts of the Middle Kingdom, “Apology of the Creator God,” written between 2181 and 2055 BCE, includes a passage where said Creator God takes credit for having created morality – and laments that people seem disinclined to follow his moral mandates.Footnote 7 Similarly, Hammurabi's code, a Babylonian text from around 1772 BCE, is a well-preserved document of a divinely inspired moral system, capitalizing on fear of Marduk, patron god of Babylon, and the powers of Shamash, god of justice: “When (my god) Marduk had given me the mission to keep my people in order and make my country take the right road, I installed in this country justice and fairness in order to bring well-being to my people” (Bottéro Reference Bottéro2001, pp. 168; for more on moralizing Mesopotamian gods, see Bellah Reference Bellah2011, pp. 221–24).

There are important open questions that require deeper analysis, regarding both the ethnographic and historical records. In moving this debate forward, it is important to recognize two crucial points that flow from a cultural evolutionary analysis. One is that our hypotheses are probabilistic, which allows for multiple causal pathways, including the possibility that in some societies prosocial religions played a minor or no role, or that their role emerged late in the process. Two, the historical trajectories of Big Gods, let alone the suite of elements we call prosocial religions, are not an all-or-nothing phenomenon. There is room for transitional gods that are knowledgeable about certain domains but not others and morally concerned in some respects but not others. As we noted, chiefdoms, in both the ethnographic and the historical records, appear to fit this intermediate pattern, and they are implicated in the expansion of the social scale. Their gods are more powerful and moralizing than those of foragers, although not as full-fledged as the Big Gods of states and empires (Bellah Reference Bellah2011).

Overall, these ethnographic, historical, and archaeological patterns are consistent with the idea that the religious elements we have highlighted have spread over human history and have replaced many alternatives. We could have found no pattern, or the opposite pattern; for example, most hunter–gatherers might have had big, moralizing gods. Therefore, in this sense, an empirical test was passed, at least provisionally. However, none of this evidence establishes causality, or that any of our key religious elements can cause people to behave prosocially. At least some of these historical and ethnographic data are also consistent with the alternative hypothesis that bigger and more prosocial societies simply projected bigger and more prosocial gods in their own image, or that bigger gods hitched a ride along with other institutional forms. In the final section, we return to the issue and explore the merits of alternative scenarios, but, next, we turn to the issue of the direction of causality postulated in this theory and explore whether adherence to the religious elements discussed previously directly increased prosociality.

4. Religion and prosocial behavior: Psychological evidence

If certain religious elements can promote prosociality, then we should be able to study these effects using a variety of tools from the cognitive and social sciences. We review here both correlational and experimental evidence in light of the abovementioned hypotheses.

4.1. Correlating religious involvement and prosocial behavior

Several lines of evidence now link participation in world religions with prosociality. A large sociological survey literature shows that religious engagement is related to greater reports of charitable giving and voluntarism (e.g., Brooks Reference Brooks2006; Putnam & Campbell Reference Putnam and Campbell2010). However, these findings are mostly confined to the American context and are based on self-reports, limiting generalizability, and inferences to actual behavior.

To avoid the problems of self-report, several studies now show a linkage between prosocial religions and the predicted forms of prosociality using economic games. In an investigation spanning 15 societies from around the globe, including populations of foragers, pastoralists, and horticulturalists, Henrich et al. (Reference Henrich, Ensimger, McElreath, Barr, Barrett, Bolyanatz, Cardenas, Gurven, Gwako, Henrich, Lesorogol, Marlowe, Tracer and Ziker2010a; Reference Henrich, Heine and Norenzayan2010b) found an association between world religion (Christianity or Islam) and prosocial behavior in two well-known economic games, the Dictator and Ultimatum Games. Unlike other studies, this one specifically validated the idea that participation in religions with Big Gods, CREDs, and related practices elicits more prosocial behavior in anonymous contexts than does participation in local or traditional religions, controlling for a host of economic and demographic variables. Interestingly, results of this and follow-up studies suggest that commitment to Big Gods is most likely to matter when the situation contains no credible threat of “earthly punishment” in the form of third-party monitoring (Laurin et al. Reference Laurin, Shariff, Henrich and Kay2012b). Those effects of participation in a world religion disappear when a secular third-party punisher is introduced.

Other behavioral studies have also found reliable associations between various indicators of religiosity and prosociality, albeit under limited conditions. A study employing a common-pool resource game, which allowed researchers to compare levels of cooperation between secular and religious kibbutzim in Israel, showed higher cooperation in the religious kibbutzim than in the secular ones; the effect was driven by highly religious men who engaged in daily and communal prayer and took the least amount of money from the common pool (Sosis & Ruffle Reference Sosis and Ruffle2003). Soler (Reference Soler2012) found similar cooperative effects of religious participation among members of an Afro-Brazilian religious group: Controlling for various sociodemographic variables, individuals who displayed higher levels of religious commitment behaved more generously in a public goods game and also reported more instances of provided and received cooperation within their religious community (for a similar finding in a Muslim sample in India, see Ahmed Reference Ahmed2009).

Although these studies are provocative, it should be noted that similar studies conducted with Western, educated, industrialized, rich, and democratic (WEIRD) samples (Henrich et al. Reference Henrich, Heine and Norenzayan2010b) have found that individual differences in religious commitment typically fail to predict prosocial behavior (e.g., Batson et al. Reference Batson, Schoenrade and Ventis1993; Randolph-Seng & Nielsen Reference Randolph-Seng and Nielsen2007; Shariff & Norenzayan Reference Shariff and Norenzayan2007). This inconsistency may arise from several factors, but one important consideration is that among groups with high trust levels toward secular institutions (the police, courts, governments) – such as the WEIRD students of so many studies – the effect of these institutions crowds out the influence of religion. In this sense, the strong secular mechanisms that have emerged recently in some societies can replace the functions of prosocial religions, an issue to which we return. Or, undergraduates may not have solidified their religious commitments. Either way, psychologists' narrow focus on WEIRD undergraduates may have caused them to miss these important moderating contexts.

In summary, behavioral studies have found associations between religious commitment and prosocial tendencies (for reviews, see Norenzayan & Shariff Reference Norenzayan and Shariff2008; Norenzayan et al. Reference Norenzayan, Henrich, Slingerland, Richerson and Christiansen2013), especially when secular institutions are weak, reputational concerns are heightened, and the targets of prosociality are in-group members (coreligionists). However, causal inference in these studies is limited by their reliance on correlational designs. If religious devotion is predictive of prosocial behavior in some contexts, then we cannot conclusively rule out the idea that having a prosocial disposition causes one to be religious – or that a third variable, such as dispositional empathy or guilt-proneness, causes both prosocial and religious tendencies. To address this issue, we consult a growing experimental literature that induces religious thinking and subsequently measures prosocial behavior.

4.2. Religious priming increases fairness, cooperation, and costly punishment while decreasing cheating

If religious beliefs have a causal effect on prosocial tendencies, then experimentally induced religious thoughts should increase prosocial behavior. Findings support this prediction. Religious reminders reduce cheating, curb selfish behavior, increase fairness toward strangers, and promote cooperation in anonymous settings for samples drawn from societies shaped by prosocial religions, primarily Abrahamic ones (for a recent review, see Norenzayan et al. Reference Norenzayan, Henrich, Slingerland, Richerson and Christiansen2013). Figure 2 shows the results of a recent meta-analysis (25 studies, 4,825 participants) from this literature (Shariff et al., Reference Shariff and Norenzayanin press), which shows that, overall, religious priming reliably increases prosocial behavior. The effect remains robust (though somewhat reduced) after estimating and adjusting for the prevalence of studies with null findings that are less likely to appear in the published literature.

Figure 2. A meta-analysis of religious priming studies shows that religious reminders increase prosocial behavior, with an average effect size of Hedges'g=0.27, 95% CI: 0.15 to 0.40 (from Shariff et al. Reference Shariff and Norenzayanin press, with permission from Sage). Error bars are 95% CI of effect sizes.Footnote 8

Crucially, analyses looking at religious priming effects on a broad range of psychological outcomes (93 studies and 11,653 participants) showed that these effects are moderated by prior religious belief. That is, religious priming effects are reliable for strong believers, but they vanish for nonbelievers (Shariff et al., Reference Shariff and Norenzayanin press). This suggests either that nonbelievers are not responsive to religious reminders, or that there is large variability among nonbelievers with regard to their responsiveness to religious primes. This is important, because it indicates that exogenous religious primes interact with endogenous religious beliefs. Religious priming is shaped by cultural conditioning, and it is not merely the result of low-level associations (in addition, it could be interpreted to mean that religious primes are most effective when they are self-relevant, as is often the case in the priming literature, e.g., Wheeler et al. Reference Wheeler, DeMarree and Petty2007).

The experimental and correlational literatures also reveal several important points about the psychological mechanisms involved.

  1. 1. Supernatural punishment and supernatural benevolence have divergent effects on prosocial behavior. In laboratory experiments, greater belief that God is punishing is more strongly associated with reductions in moral transgressions such as cheating, whereas greater belief that God is benevolent, if anything, has the opposite effect, increasing cheating (Shariff & Norenzayan Reference Shariff and Norenzayan2011). Similarly, at the national level, greater belief in hell relative to heaven is predictive of lower national crime rates such as burglary, holding constant a wide range of socioeconomic factors and the dominant religious denomination (Shariff & Rhemtulla Reference Shariff and Rhemtulla2012).

  2. 2. Gods are believed to monitor norm violations. Reaction time analyses suggest that believers intuit that God has knowledge about norm-violating behaviors more than they believe that God has knowledge about other behaviors (Purzycki et al. Reference Purzycki, Finkel, Shaver, Wales, Cohen and Sosis2012).

  3. 3. Religious priming increases believers' perceptions of being under social surveillance (Gervais & Norenzayan Reference Gervais and Norenzayan2012a).

  4. 4. Belief in a punishing god is associated with less punishing behavior toward free-riders, because participants believe that they can offload punishing duties to God (Laurin et al. Reference Laurin, Shariff, Henrich and Kay2012b). Here, people are doing the opposite of what they think God is doing.

Together, these findings suggest a role linking beliefs in morally concerned, punitive, supernatural monitors to increases in prosocial behavior. These findings contradict the idea that already prosocial individuals spontaneously imagine conceptions of prosocial deities, or with explanations that suggest that religious priming brings to mind cultural stereotypes linking religion with benevolence, which in turn encourage benevolent behaviors such as generosity (Norenzayan et al. Reference Norenzayan, Henrich, Slingerland, Richerson and Christiansen2013). Finally, our framework predicts cultural variability in religious priming; these effects should diminish in cultural contexts, typically in smaller-scale groups, where religious elements and norm compliance are largely disconnected, and the gods have limited omniscience and are morally indifferent. This hypothesis remains open to investigation.

4.3. Prosocial religions encourage self-control

Participation in prosocial religions cultivates a variety of self-regulatory mechanisms, including self-control, goal pursuit, and self-monitoring: all processes that may also partly explain religion's capacity to suppress selfishness in the interest of the group and promote longevity and health (McCullough & Willoughby Reference McCullough and Willoughby2009). Although most of the supporting evidence is correlational (e.g., Carter et al. Reference Carter, McCullough, Kim-Spoon, Corrales and Blake2012), recent experimental studies suggest a causal direction. In a series of experiments (Rounding et al. Reference Rounding, Lee, Jacobson and Ji2012; see also Laurin et al. Reference Laurin, Kay and Fitzsimons2012a), religious primes were found to increase an individual's willingness to endure unpleasant experiences (e.g., drinking juice mixed with vinegar) and delay gratification (e.g., by agreeing to wait for a week to receive $6 instead of being paid $5 immediately). In addition, religious reminders increased persistence on a difficult task when self-control resources were depleted (Rounding et al. Reference Rounding, Lee, Jacobson and Ji2012). Other experimental findings (e.g., Inzlicht & Tullett Reference Inzlicht and Tullett2010) corroborate these observations, showing that implicit religious reminders enhance the exercising of self-control processes, by, for example, suppressing neurophysiological responses to cognitive error. Self-control is closely related to prosociality, because cooperating or complying with various norms often requires forgoing immediate returns in exchange for some future benefits, group benefits, or afterlife rewards.

Many ritual and devotional practices may have culturally evolved in part by increasing self-control (see below) and performance. For example, Legare and Souza (Reference Legare and Souza2012; Reference Legare and Souza2014) have explored how the elements found in widespread rituals, including repetitions, multiple-step complexity, and supernatural connections, tap aspects of our intuitive causal cognition to increase their perceived efficacy. Believing one is equipped with efficacious rituals may foster self-regulation, persistence, and discipline by increasing individuals' confidence in their own success. Ritually enhanced self-efficacy improves performance (Damisch et al. Reference Damisch, Stoberock and Mussweiler2010).

5. Galvanizing group solidarity

Belief-ritual complexes take shape as cultural evolution increasingly exploits a variety of psychological mechanisms to ratchet up internal harmony, cooperation, and social cohesion. In this way, prosocial religions bind anonymous individuals into moral communities (Graham & Haidt Reference Graham and Haidt2010; Haidt & Kesebir Reference Haidt, Kesebir, Fiske and Gilbert2010), without prosocial religious elements being necessary for moral capacities or vice versa (Norenzayan Reference Norenzayan2014). Although many important open questions remain, here we focus on several that appear critical and that have received some attention.

5.1. Transmitting commitment: Why extravagant displays deepen faith and promote solidarity

The extravagance of some religious rituals has long puzzled evolutionary scientists. These performances demand sacrifices of time, effort, and resources. They include rites of terror, various restrictions on behavior (sex, poverty vows), painful initiations (tattooing, walking on hot stones), diet (fasts and food taboos), and lifestyle restrictions (strict marriage rules, dress codes). Why are extravagant displays of faith commonly found in prosocial religions?

The answer to this question could be found in the way that cultural learning biases operate. Belief can be easily faked, which would allow cultural models to manipulate learners by propagating “beliefs” that they did not sincerely hold. One evolutionary solution to this dilemma is for cultural learners to be biased toward acquiring beliefs that are backed up by deeds that would not be performed if the model's beliefs were not genuine (as well as related strategies for “epistemic vigilance,” see Sperber et al. Reference Sperber, Clément, Heintz, Mascaro, Mercier, Origgi and Wilson2010). Although limited, existing experimental work on cultural learning indicates that CREDs play an important role in the transmission of belief or commitment in multiple domains where cultural influence matters, not just in religious contexts (for review see Henrich Reference Henrich2009; for more recent evidence, see Lanman Reference Lanman2012; Willard et al. Reference Willard, Norenzayan and Henrich2015). In prosocial religions, CREDs are of particular importance, given that faith spreads by cultural influence, and that religious hypocrites can undermine group cohesion. The idea here is that cultural evolution exploited the evolved inclination to attend to CREDs as a mechanism to deepen religious faith and commitment, and thereby promote cooperation.

Religious displays of self-sacrifice are often seen in influential religious leaders, who then transmit these beliefs to their followers. For example, when male priests of the Phrygian goddess Cybele performed ritualized public self-castrations, they sparked cultural epidemics of Cybele religious revival in the early Roman Empire that often competed with the spread of Christianity (Burkert Reference Burkert1982). Similarly, early Christian saints, by their willing martyrdom, became potent models that encouraged the cultural spread of Christian beliefs (Stark Reference Stark1996). When religious leaders' actions credibly communicate their underlying belief and commitments, their actions in turn energize witnesses and help their beliefs to spread in a group, after which commitment deepens. If, on the other hand, they are not willing to make a significant demonstration of their commitment, then observers – even children – withhold their own commitment to those beliefs. Supporting this idea, Lanman (Reference Lanman2012) reports that in Scandinavia children are less likely to adopt the beliefs of their religious parents if those parents do not display religious CREDs. Conversely, both children and adults, exposed to both religious propositions (implicit or explicit) and CREDs, acquire a deeper commitment or belief in them than they would otherwise.

Once people believe, they are more likely to perform similar displays themselves, which offers another explanation of why extravagant behaviors are culturally infectious in prosocial religious groups. Moreover, CREDs often come in the form of altruistic giving to other in-group members, further ratcheting up the level of in-group cooperation in prosocial religious groups. For example, Xygalatas et al. (Reference Xygalatas, Mitkidis, Fischer, Reddish, Skewes, Geertz, Roepstorff and Bulbulia2013) investigated the prosocial effects of participation in, and witnessing of, the Kavadi, an extreme set of devotional rituals for Murugan, the Tamil god of war, among Hindus in Mauritius. The act of witnessing this intense, pain-inducing set of rituals increased anonymous donations to the temple as much as participating did. Donation sizes correlated with perceptions of the pain involved. This suggests that extreme ritual worship such as this one is likely to be a CRED-like phenomenon in addition to any signaling functions that it carries.

Although reliance on CREDs evolved for adaptive reasons originally unrelated to religion, their exploitation by prosocial religions helps explain why (1) religious participants, and especially religious leaders, must engage in sacrifices (e.g., vows of poverty and chastity make leaders more effective transmitters of faith and commitment); (2) martyrdom emerges prominently in religious narratives and actions; and (3) Big Gods are believed to demand extravagant sacrifices and worship, thereby causing CREDs, which in turn deepen faith in these Big Gods.

Finally, cultural evolution may have shaped the rituals of prosocial religions for the effective transmission of standardized religious beliefs and doctrines across large populations. Following Whitehouse's formulation (2004), we propose that cultural evolution may have increasingly favored the “doctrinal mode” of ritual, in which some subset of rituals becomes high frequency, low arousal, highly repetitious, and obligatory. The idea is that these types of repetitious rituals may cue norm psychology and increase the transmission fidelity of certain religious ideas (Herrmann et al. Reference Herrmann, Legare, Harris and Whitehouse2013; Kenward et al. Reference Kenward, Karlsson and Persson2010), thereby helping to maintain religious uniformity in large populations, not only among those individuals attending the ritual (more on this subsequently), but also across a larger imagined community of coreligionists.

5.2. Synchrony and fictive kinship

Prosocial religions often harness collective rituals that are characterized by shared, synchronous arousal, a phenomenon Durkheim (Reference Durkheim1915) termed collective effervescence. Historians have suggested that this synchronous arousal was the key to understanding the military innovation of close-order drill, which increased unit solidarity (McNeill Reference McNeill1982; Reference McNeill1995). Recent empirical work shows that the experience of synchrony increases feelings of affiliation (Hove & Risen Reference Hove and Risen2009; also see Paladino et al. Reference Paladino, Mazzurega, Pavani and Schubert2010; Valdesolo et al. Reference Valdesolo, Ouyang and DeSteno2010) and facilitates feelings of fusion with the group, which may in turn encourage acts of sacrifice for the group (Swann et al. Reference Swann, Gomez, Seyle, Morales and Huici2009). One study found that joint music-making promotes prosocial behavior even among 4-year-olds (Kirschner & Tomasello Reference Kirschner and Tomasello2010). Experimental work has also shown that participation in synchronous song and dance results in greater trust, greater feelings of “being on the same team,” and more cooperation in economic games (Wiltermuth & Heath Reference Wiltermuth and Heath2009). Even witnessing fire-walking puts the heart-rate rhythms of friends and relatives in sync with those of the walkers (Konvalinka et al. Reference Konvalinka, Xygalatas, Bulbulia, Schjoedt, Jegindo and Wallot2011). As noted earlier, synchronous rituals may also affect self-regulation: Rowing synchronously with team members leads to higher levels of pain tolerance (Cohen et al. Reference Cohen, Ejsmond-Frey, Knight and Dunbar2010), which should improve team performance.

Many have observed that the prosocial religious groups that often unite people across ethnic, linguistic, and geographic boundaries evoke kinship in referring to each other (Atran & Henrich Reference Atran and Henrich2010; Nesse Reference Nesse1999). Christians often describe themselves as belonging to a “brotherhood,” a common term that often applies today to the global fraternity (ikhwan) of Islam (Atran & Norenzayan Reference Atran and Norenzayan2004). In fifth-century BCE China, Confucius famously observed that anyone in the world sharing his moral and religious commitments should be viewed as a “brother” (Analects 12.5; Slingerland Reference Slingerland2003, p. 127), and throughout Chinese imperial history the emperor was known as the “Son of Heaven” and viewed as the both the mother and father of the populace.

There is little experimental work exploring the psychology behind fictive kinship and its relation to religious solidarity. We suggest two possible hypotheses. One is that kinship psychology partly contributes to the deep trust and commitment that is characteristic of global religious communities. Alternatively, it could be that the use of kinship metaphors helps establish the social norms for how one is supposed to treat coreligionists, which allows participants to readily learn proper behavior and to judge and sanction norm violators (Chudek & Henrich Reference Chudek and Henrich2011). Either way, we hypothesize that cultural evolution exploits this feature in innate social psychology, rather than it being an automatic misfiring of psychology evolved for survival in ancestral environments.

5.3. Signaling religious commitment and expanding the social circle while marking group boundaries and fueling intergroup conflict

Through ritual practices and devotions, cultural evolutionary processes often exploit signaling to differentiate those with high levels of religious commitment from those without (Bulbulia Reference Bulbulia2004; Sosis & Alcorta Reference Sosis and Alcorta2003). Empirically, sociological analyses are consistent with the idea that groups that impose behavioral restrictions or taboos have members that are more committed (Iannaccone Reference Iannaccone1994). Controlling for relevant sociodemographic variables, “strict” Protestant and Jewish denominations (Jehovah's Witnesses, Orthodox) show higher levels of church and synagogue attendance, respectively, and make larger monetary contributions to their religious communities (despite lower average income levels) than do less strict ones (Methodists, Reform). Work by Ginges et al. (Reference Ginges, Hansen and Norenzayan2009) affirms that there is a link between ritual participation and parochial altruism; that is, commitment to a combination of in-group cooperation and out-group aggression. Both extensive survey data and experimental findings from Palestinians and Jewish Israelis in the West Bank and Gaza show that religious participation (as measured by attendance) predicts more support for suicide attacks against out-groups, independent of religious devotion (as measured by prayer) and a wide range of other factors. These findings by themselves do not conclusively demonstrate that measures of strictness or sacrifice predict community survival and growth (an issue that we explore later). They do, however, demonstrate that group commitment is associated with the ritual participation commonly found in prosocial religions.

One of the pillars on which we build our argument is the hypothesis that human minds are reliably equipped with a set of social instincts related to kinship, reciprocity, status, and reputation. In addition, these social instincts are bundled together with tribal instincts for life in groups based on a social identity cued by shared customs, taboos, languages, and practices (Henrich & Henrich Reference Henrich and Henrich2007; Richerson & Boyd Reference Richerson and Boyd1999). Our hypotheses suggest that cultural evolution harnessed these social, and particularly tribal, instincts to stretch and expand the social sphere of people to include all coreligionists, even when they lived well beyond the sphere of ethnic identity, reputation, or repeat interaction. Prosocial religions accomplish this in myriad ways, including norms that mark group boundaries, and sacralize inequality and vertical relationships within expanding groups, beliefs that describe a group-based primordial essence, or rituals that instill the relevant essence in new initiates. Common boundary markers that spark tribal psychology include distinctive dress, ornamentation, tattooing, bodily mutilation, and food taboos. These behaviors can act as boundary markers, signals of commitment, and CREDs that transmit commitment to learners.

One critical boundary marking in prosocial religions that is of particular interest is distrust of atheists (Gervais & Norenzayan Reference Gervais, Norenzayan, Clarke, Powell and Savulescu2013; Gervais et al. Reference Gervais, Shariff and Norenzayan2011a). For atheists, belief is a personal matter on a metaphysical issue. For believers, lack of commitment to supernatural surveillance is a public threat to cooperation and social trust (Gervais et al. Reference Gervais, Shariff and Norenzayan2011a; Norenzayan Reference Norenzayan2013). Although several factors are implicated in this prejudice, converging evidence shows that one key driver of religious distrust of atheists is the intuition that people behave better if they are under supernatural surveillance (Gervais & Norenzayan Reference Gervais, Norenzayan, Clarke, Powell and Savulescu2013). These boundary-setting processes highlight the parochial aspect of religiously motivated prosocial behavior. They also illustrate that the solidarity-building potential of prosocial religions has a dark side. This potential can reify political and economic inequality within cooperative but hierarchically organized groups (Peoples & Marlowe Reference Peoples and Marlowe2012; Turchin Reference Turchin2011), often contributing to exploitation by those who hold power; and it can turn toxic for people who are seen to fall outside of the imagined moral boundaries (such as perceived religious out-groups). Thus, in the present framework, intragroup cooperation can readily feed into intergroup antagonism, especially when social groups are already in a state of real or imagined conflict. This is a topic of great interest in our age, for understanding the conditions under which prosocial religions become accessories to intergroup intolerance, conflict, and violence (see for example, Atran & Ginges Reference Atran and Ginges2012; Haidt Reference Haidt2012; Neuberg et al. Reference Neuberg, Warner, Berlin, Hill, Johnson, Filip-Crawford, Millsap, Thomas, Winkelman, Broome and Taylor2014; Norenzayan Reference Norenzayan2013).

5.4. Metaphysical grounding and sacred values

Our approach suggests that cultural evolution anchors certain kinds of norms or beliefs – those favoring success in intergroup competition – to a kind of metaphysical bedrock (Durkheim Reference Durkheim1915; Rappaport Reference Rappaport1999), such as the desires of a widely accepted and omnipotent deity. Some scholars have argued that distinctively moral norms have a necessary connection to metaphysical beliefs (e.g., Taylor Reference Taylor1989). This suggests that key features of norms such as authority independence, universal applicability, and emotional salience become more widespread in large-scale societies influenced by Big Gods and in their secular successors but are likely to be less important or unknown in small-scale societies (Huebner et al. Reference Huebner, Lee and Hauser2010). It is also apparent that such moral norms, or “sacred values,” are distinctive in being uniquely resistant to cost–benefit trade-offs (Atran Reference Atran2010a; Ginges et al. Reference Ginges, Atran, Medin and Shikaki2007; Haidt Reference Haidt2012).

We hypothesize that metaphysically grounded, group-beneficial norms that carry powerful affective force and punitive sentiments play an important role in insulating within-group cooperation from potential defection (see also Atran Reference Atran2010a). Moreover, in larger-scale cooperative societies, especially those involving social classes and multiple ethnic groups, subgroups or coalitions will have incentives to push social norms in directions that favor their subgroup, sometimes at the expense of the overall group. If norms are grounded metaphysically, however, self-interested individuals or subgroups pushing to alter norms face a substantial obstacle.

The spread of normative monogamy may provide an illustrative case of self-interest being curtailed by metaphysically rooted norms. The anthropological record indicates that approximately 85% of societies have permitted men to take more than one wife (polygynous marriage), and both empirical and evolutionary considerations suggest that large absolute differences in wealth should favor more polygynous marriages. However, monogamous marriage spread across Europe, and more recently around the globe, even as absolute wealth differences expanded. Much evidence now suggests that cultural evolution has favored the norms and institutions of modern monogamous marriage because of their group-beneficial effects. In suppressing intrasexual competition and reducing the size of the pool of unmarried men, normative monogamy reduces crime rates, including rape and murder (Henrich et al. Reference Henrich, Boyd and Richerson2012). Historically, Christianity overcame the obstacle presented by elite male interests (kings and nobles) by making monogamy sacred and divinely ordained, and thereby making polygamy not just counternormative but heretical. Similarly, Islam, although not enforcing strict monogamy, adopted practices that nevertheless inhibited polygyny, again backed by sacred authority (Henrich et al. Reference Henrich, Boyd and Richerson2012). A king or chief may be motivated to change secular laws to suit his immediate needs, but challenging divinely ordained sacred commands is another matter.

In summary, and to emphasize a key point, none of the psychological mechanisms harnessed by cultural evolution in the above described account are unique to religion or to prosocial religions. Extravagant displays can be found in a variety of domains in which social influence is important, such as in marketing, education, and warfare. Synchrony is widely used, especially in military drill. Fictive kinship is the central organizing principle of the kinship systems that characterize small-scale societies. Many sacred values, such as the notion of the existence of fundamental human rights, are found in secular societies, even among atheists (Atran Reference Atran2010a; Taylor Reference Taylor1989; Haidt Reference Haidt2012). What makes prosocial religions interesting and distinctive is the way that cultural evolution has packaged and interwoven a converging set of mechanisms with commitments to Big Gods and other supernatural beliefs.

6. The cultural group selection of religious groups

We now turn to the final argument: Cultural evolution, driven by intergroup competition (including warfare), over historical time favored those amalgams of beliefs, norms, and rituals (belief–ritual complexes) that most effectively increased internal solidarity, elevated in-group cooperation in expanding groups, and promoted success in outcompeting or absorbing rival groups. Because fully documented and quantified cases of long-term historical processes are currently hard to find, we proceed by sketching two converging lines of evidence. First, we highlight ethnographic and historical evidence of cultural group selection in action, in which certain belief–ritual packages spread as a result of the differential survival or success of groups. These cases do not conclusively demonstrate all of the relevant causal interconnections, but they do establish a prima facie case that certain rituals and beliefs spread via intergroup competition. Second, to illuminate the causal processes that link the adoption of certain religious beliefs to group success, we examine demographic and economic evidence suggesting that prosocial religions favor faster reproduction and greater economic success.

6.1. Ethnographic and historical cases

Historical and ethnographic evidence from a variety of sources indicates that particular belief–ritual combinations do spread by cultural group selection. As noted, even before the emergence of large-scale societies, intergroup competition would have favored solidarity-inducing rituals (Henrich Reference Henrich2015). This process can be seen in an ethnohistorical study of the evolution of various belief–ritual complexes in the highlands of New Guinea. Central to the emergence of these ritually galvanized ideological systems, which the authors describe as promoting “identity, welfare, and unity” within larger and larger groups over time, is the cultural transmission of these belief–ritual complexes, or elements of them, both within and across linguistic boundaries (Wiessner & Tumu Reference Wiessner and Tumu1998, pp. 195–96).

Elsewhere in New Guinea, Tuzin has examined the historical co-emergence of a strong group ideology, an intricate form of social organization, a complex ritual system, and a high degree of cooperation and solidarity. In a region where villages often break down when they grow to more than 300 or so people, this study of the Ilahita Arapesh reveals how an interlocking segmented moiety system, galvanized by the rehearsal of a secret ritual system called the Tambara, permitted 1,500 people to live together with high levels of cooperation and solidarity, and thereby survive in a very competitive regional environment that has long included both military and economic threats (Tuzin Reference Tuzin1976; Reference Tuzin2001). The basic elements of the belief–ritual complex, which the Ilahita Arapesh elaborated and improved upon, were first imitated from a highly successful and aggressively expanding group called the Abelam in the 1870s or thereabouts. Their acquisition and modification of the Abelam system probably permitted Ilahita's inhabitants to resist being driven out, and it has since permitted both military and economic success.

This contextually rich ethnohistorical study fits with recent cross-cultural analyses of small-scale preindustrial societies showing that greater participation in intergroup warfare (but not within-group violence or intensity of mating competition) predicts more extreme rites for males (Sosis et al. Reference Sosis, Kress and Boster2007). Whether these rites are commitment signals or CREDS (or both), the findings suggest that increases in intergroup competition favor rituals and devotions that more effectively galvanize commitment, solidarity, and cooperation. Groups with these practices increase their odds of surviving, expanding, and being imitated by other groups.

Cultural group selection also operates when individuals preferentially adopt or “convert” to certain cultural packages, based on the success of those groups (Boyd & Richerson Reference Boyd and Richerson2009). In her study of the spread of Islam into Africa, Ensminger (Reference Ensminger1997) discussed how Islamic CREDs – abstaining from alcohol, avoiding pre- and extramarital sex, not consuming blood or pork, and fasting – transmitted greater trust and shared rules of exchange and the use of credit institutions among converted Muslims. This facilitated more trade and greater economic success. The Orma (Kenyan agro-pastoralists), and presumably other African groups, began adopting the religious beliefs along with the associated institutions and rituals. Ensminger (Reference Ensminger1997) suggests that these Islamic groups not only attracted followers faster than other groups, but also succeeded at times in imposing Islam on conquered groups: another form of cultural group selection that influences the distribution of religious representations.

Finally, at least one quantitative investigation has directly tested the prediction that religious cultural groups, particularly those incorporating extravagant displays, enjoy an advantage in group stability over time over cultural groups that do not (Sosis Reference Sosis2000; Sosis & Alcorta Reference Sosis and Alcorta2003). Sosis compared the group longevity of nineteenth century American religious and secular communes. Facing various internal and external threats to group stability, communes that were unable to solve collective action problems were unlikely to survive and prosper. For every year considered over a 120-year span, religious communes were found to outlast secular ones by an average factor of four (Fig. 3). Moreover, religious communes were less likely than secular ones to dissolve in any given year as a result of internal conflict or economic hardship. A subsequent analysis of 83 of these religious and secular communes (Sosis & Bressler Reference Sosis and Bressler2003) found that religious communes imposed more than twice as many restrictions (including food taboos and fasts, and constraints on material possessions, marriage, sex, and communication with the outside world), and the number of restrictions predicted religious commune longevity (R 2=0.38), even after controlling for population size, income, and founding year. It is important to note that these are differences in the longevity of the cultural groups (not the individuals within the groups) over a historical time spanning only a few generations.

Figure 3. Religious communes outlast secular ones over time (from Sosis, R., Cross-Cultural Research (vol. 34), pp. 70–87, copyright © 2000. Reprinted by permission of SAGE Publications.).

6.2. Prosocial religions influence reproductive and economic success

Cultural group selection can work through a variety of mechanisms. Here, we highlight evidence indicating that the beliefs and practices of prosocial religions generate greater reproductive and economic success. Greater reproduction means a faster rate of production of culture-bearing coreligionists, because children, all else being equal, tend to acquire the religious beliefs of their families and communities. All else being equal, economic productivity also matters because of the obvious advantages it offers in intergroup competition, and because economically less-successful groups often copy more-successful ones.

Prosocial religions are often pro-natalist in orientation: They tend to favor higher fertility rates (Blume Reference Blume, Voland and Schiefenhövel2009; Kaufmann Reference Kaufmann2010; Norris & Inglehart Reference Norris and Inglehart2004). This association is both strong and robust across diverse populations. For example, individual-level data from 82 countries reveals a linear relationship between the frequency of religious worship and number of children, with those who worship more than once a week averaging 2.5 children compared with 1.7 (below replacement) for those who never worship. Blume (Reference Blume, Voland and Schiefenhövel2009) has examined the Swiss census of 2000 and found that, even after controlling for education and income, Christians, Hindus, Muslims, and Jews all outbred the religiously unaffiliated. A study comparing the fertility rates of Orthodox or atheist European Jews found that the atheists had the lowest birthrate, averaging approximately 1.5 children per woman, whereas the religious Jews averaged nearly 3, with the Haredim in Israel averaging 6–8 children per woman (Kaufmann Reference Kaufmann2010).

At the group level, societies that are more religious have higher population replacement levels than secular societies, even when countries are matched on national income and education levels (Norris & Inglehart Reference Norris and Inglehart2004). Time series analyses indicate that, as religiosity declines in a society over time (as has occurred in Europe in the second half of the twentieth century), so do fertility rates. According to Blume (Reference Blume, Voland and Schiefenhövel2009), it is hard to find overwhelmingly secular societies today that are reproducing above replacement levels, despite strong government incentives in welfare state countries such as France and Germany. Religious positions on women's rights, contraception, sexual orientation, and abortion can be seen in this same light. What are called “family values” in the United States can be best understood as a set of values conducive to producing larger families.

Of course, not all religions encourage reproductive success; consider the celibate Shakers. However, in the argument we have outlined, those religious groups with beliefs and practices that promote rapid population growth would be, all else being equal, expected to outcompete their rivals (whether religious or secular) and take a larger share of the religious market. Exactly how prosocial religions have these effects is an open question. Nevertheless, we think that cultural evolutionary processes play a major role in this reproductive advantage, just as they do in their effects on cooperation. Fertility rates of second-generation immigrants to the United States can be predicted from the average fertility rates of the home countries of their parents, indicating just how powerful a grip culture can have on reproduction (Fernandez & Fogli Reference Fernandez and Fogli2009). The rapid declines in fertility – often in just a few generations –following secularization also suggest that these effects are likely to be, in an important sense, culturally transmitted.

Elements of prosocial religions can also influence the economic performance of groups, which facilitates their cultural success. For example, using panel data from 81 countries, McCleary and Barro (Reference McCleary and Barro2006) showed that countries with stronger beliefs in a consequential afterlife (e.g., heaven and hell), experience faster economic growth rates, controlling for life expectancy, education, the rule of law, fertility rate, and ratio of investment to GDP. Belief in hell, in particular, is found to be a strong predictor of commitment to teaching thrift to children. However, consistent with the secularization trend, greater GDP per capita in turn leads to a subsequent decline in religious beliefs. These effects on economic growth are based on both longitudinal evidence and on extensive statistical controls (Barro & McCleary Reference Barro and McCleary2003). With appropriate caveats, then, these analyses encourage the hypothesis that religious beliefs have effects on economic outcomes. Other correlational analyses show that belief in a personal god and in the afterlife, as well as ritual participation, independently predict harsher judgment of key moral transgressions, including cheating on taxes, accepting a bribe, adultery, and lying (Atkinson & Bourrat Reference Atkinson and Bourrat2011).

7. Implications, counterarguments, and concluding remarks

7.1. Synthesizing existing views on the evolution of religion

Despite recent progress, the evolutionary study of religion is in its infancy, and important gaps remain in our knowledge and much work needs to be done to reach a more complete understanding. The theoretical framework presented here synthesizes key elements of the two most influential evolutionary approaches to religion to date: the by-product and adaptationist approaches. We note that both approaches have their merits and have generated rich theorizing and empirical literatures that have moved the field forward. Our framework builds directly on the by-product perspective that religious representations are made possible and facilitated by reliably developing features of human cognition that were not naturally selected for the production of the religious beliefs or behaviors that they now underpin. However, by embedding these ideas within a framework that considers more fully both genetic and cultural inheritance, we can account for a number of key phenomena not explicitly addressed by the cognitive by-product account.

Two examples illustrate this point. First, although the by-product account helps explain how people come to mentally represent supernatural agents, it is silent about one of the most critical features of (some) religions, that of deep faith or commitment to particular gods. This is captured by the “Zeus Problem” (Gervais & Henrich Reference Gervais and Henrich2010), which asks how people in one place and time can acquire belief in, and commitment to, a particular religious representation, whereas people in another place or time do not, even when exposed to identical representation.Footnote 9 We argue that understanding the origin of faith requires explaining not only the cognitive mechanisms that allow people to mentally represent, remember, and transmit religious ideas, but, equally crucially, how people passionately and selectively commit to only a subset of all intuitively conceivable deities. We hypothesize that cultural learning biases, such as CREDs (Henrich Reference Henrich2009), are a crucial part of the explanation. In this view, if cultural learning cues are altered, significant shifts occur in the particular deities people believe in without altering their content. Second, most by-product approaches have not explicitly dealt with the body of empirical evidence showing that some religious elements spread by having prosocial effects.Footnote 10 In contrast, we offer an argument compatible with central aspects of the cognitive by-product view, but one that goes further and explains why some, but not most, “thinkable” cultural variants have powerful downstream social effects.

The current framework also accounts for a set of important phenomena that two distinct adaptationist theories of religion address: costly signaling approaches and the supernatural punishment hypothesis. Both perspectives accommodate the idea that the cognitions underlying religious beliefs and behaviors may have been evolutionary by-products, but both highlight their adaptive role (Bering Reference Bering2006; Sosis Reference Sosis2009). The costly signaling approach, grounded in behavioral ecology, argues that extravagant religious displays are naturally selected for life in cooperative groups, allowing individuals to reliably signal their degree of cooperation or their group commitment to solve the free-rider problem (Bulbulia Reference Bulbulia2004; Reference Bulbulia, Bulbulia, Richard, Genet, Harris, Wynan and Genet2008; Irons Reference Irons and Nesse2001; Sosis & Alcorta Reference Sosis and Alcorta2003). This approach is compatible with cultural variability and cultural evolutionary logic, and recent work in this perspective has begun to integrate costly signaling accounts with models that take into account intergroup competition and cultural evolutionary changes (e.g., Sosis & Bulbulia Reference Sosis and Bulbulia2011; Wildman & Sosis Reference Wildman and Sosis2011). We have built a foundation that further promotes such synthesis by incorporating insights from this approach in two ways. First, by emphasizing CREDs as well as signaling, we account for both the cultural contagion generated by these extravagant displays and what they communicate to others about the actor's commitments. Second, by embedding signaling approaches within a cultural evolutionary framework (Henrich Reference Henrich2009), we can explain why people might acquire religious beliefs with varying degrees of commitment, as well as why individuals are more susceptible to acquiring religious beliefs that are backed up by credible displays. Our view also positions specific signals within a cultural evolutionary process that assembles practices and beliefs to exploit signaling logic over historical time.Footnote 11

Another adaptationist account that has garnered interest is the supernatural punishment hypothesis (SPH) (e.g., Bering Reference Bering2006; Reference Bering2011; Johnson Reference Johnson and Levin2009), which argues that a fear of a moralizing god is a naturally selected genetic adaptation targeting moral self-constraint or error management. Although our framework and the SPH share many similarities, and draw from some of the same body of evidence, they also differ in interesting ways. Whereas we argue that fear of moralizing gods and other supernatural punishment beliefs were culturally selected in individuals and groups, the SPH argues that they are a genetic adaptation favored by within-group genetic selection, whose function is to restrain individuals from defection because of the social punishment they personally risk if caught (Johnson Reference Johnson and Levin2009; Johnson & Bering Reference Johnson and Bering2006; Schloss & Murray Reference Schloss and Murray2011). The cultural evolutionary framework and the supernatural punishment hypothesis in principle can be compatible, and we encourage debate on this possibility. However, our interpretation of the current ethnographic evidence raises two key challenges for this hypothesis. One is that the available evidence shows that in small-scale societies, and especially among foragers, gods have limited omniscience and little or no moral concern. Two, gods become more moralizing and interventionist as societies scale up and anonymity invades relationships, where the likelihood of escaping social sanctions for defection is greater, not smaller (for further discussion and critique, see Norenzayan Reference Norenzayan2013; Shariff et al. Reference Shariff, Norenzayan, Henrich, Schaller, Norenzayan, Heine, Yamaguishi and Kameda2010). The framework we present here preserves the important insights and evidence from this hypothesis but also accommodates what would otherwise be empirical anomalies.

Our framework also circumvents what we argue are unproductive definitional debates about “religion.” Within religious studies, there is no widely accepted definition of what constitutes religion, or even if the term itself usefully picks out a coherent category of beliefs or behaviors (Saler Reference Saler2009; Stausberg Reference Stausberg2010). In our view, the concept of religion merely provides a pithy rhetorical prop to cue readers to the kinds of interrelated phenomena that require explanation. The religious package is a statistical pattern governed by specific hypotheses, rather than a predefined concept with necessary or sufficient features. There is, therefore, no expectation of a single overarching definition of religion or clear semantic boundaries, because the package of traits that gets labeled “religion,” although containing recurrent elements, culturally mutates in a predictable fashion, taking different shapes in different groups and at different historical times (Norenzayan Reference Norenzayan2013; for a similar but distinct account, see Taves Reference Taves2009).

7.2. Counterarguments and alternative cultural evolutionary scenarios

Now that we have situated a cultural evolutionary framework in the broader debates about the evolution of religion, we evaluate the merits of alternative scenarios and counterarguments in light of the evidence. One obvious possibility we return to is reverse causation: the idea that prosocial religions are a consequence, rather than a cause, of social complexity and large-scale cooperation. To sharpen this alternative account, we consider two versions of the question. The broad version is that the causality is bidirectional: Prosocial religions are both a cause and a reflection of large-scale cooperation. In other words, they are best characterized as a mutually galvanizing feedback-loop. This is of course compatible with the hypothesis that prosocial religious elements contributed to the expansion of the cooperative sphere. The narrower version is that prosocial religions may be causally inert and only a by-product of large-scale cooperation (e.g., see Baumard & Boyer Reference Baumard and Boyer2013).

We argue that this by-product-only account is difficult to reconcile with the breadth of the evidence for at least three reasons. First, we note that the religious priming data, supported by a meta-analysis, contradicts this alternative claim. Second, in the 15-culture experimental study conducted by Henrich et al. (Reference Henrich, Ensimger, McElreath, Barr, Barrett, Bolyanatz, Cardenas, Gurven, Gwako, Henrich, Lesorogol, Marlowe, Tracer and Ziker2010a; Reference Henrich, Heine and Norenzayan2010b), in which adherence to world religions (relative to local religions) predicted more prosocial behavior in economic games, this effect remained even after controlling for community size (as well as other variables implicated in religion and prosociality). If both prosocial religions and prosocial tendencies were merely a consequence of societal scale, statistically controlling for community size, market integration, income, education, and wealth would eliminate the association between world religion and prosocial behavior. The data did not support that. Third, the cross-cultural ethnographic patterns we discussed earlier pose a different kind of challenge to this account. There are multiple, statistically independent predictors of the prevalence of Big Gods (e.g., Botero et al. Reference Botero, Gardner, Kirby, Bulbulia, Gavin and Gray2014; Peoples & Marlowe Reference Peoples and Marlowe2012). The by-product-only hypothesis would have to offer piecewise and special case explanations; that is, different accounts would have to be conjured up for why people who live in large, anonymous societies, practicing animal husbandry, engaged in agriculture, and exposed to ecological duress such as water scarcity, imagine Big Gods more than do people in other societies that lack these conditions. The causal hypothesis, in contrast, is backed up by experimental evidence, and it also offers a unified explanation for these cross-cultural patterns, as each of these socioecological conditions poses serious collective action problems to which prosocial religions with Big Gods contribute solutions (e.g., Botero et al. Reference Botero, Gardner, Kirby, Bulbulia, Gavin and Gray2014; Peoples & Marlowe Reference Peoples and Marlowe2012).

Another cultural evolutionary scenario is that prosocial religions proliferated only after other mechanisms produced a set of conditions in which prosocial religions increasingly became a target of cultural evolutionary pressures. That is, prosocial religions may not have played an original role in enabling the rise of large-scale cooperative societies, but rather, they may have been a consequence. Once prosocial religions took shape, they then contributed to maintaining and expanding large-scale cooperation.Footnote 12 Because the framework we have outlined does not specify a fixed temporal sequence, this scenario is a viable alternative given the available ethnographic, historical, and experimental evidence. We suspect that history will show some cases in which religious elements spread first, and then societies expanded, and other cases in which the societies expanded, and then the religious elements spread and in turn sustained and broadened the expansion. These alternative historical scenarios are ripe for research.

7.3. From religious belief to disbelief

The widespread occurrence of at least some forms of atheismFootnote 13 presents an interesting challenge for any evolutionary explanation of religion. Religion, by some evolutionary accounts, is either a suite of adaptive strategies built into evolved psychology, or it is a direct projection from reliably developing, species-specific, cognitive capacities onto the world. We take up this challenge in the framework presented here and offer an account of secularization. By combining insights from the by-product approach with cultural evolution, we suggest that psychologically real atheism is possible, even if some cognitive biases – all else being equal – push people toward religious belief. Our framework suggests that religious belief – as a joint product of cognitive biases, core existential motivations concerning mortality as well as control and meaning, and cultural learning strategies – may produce distinct psychological pathways that jointly or in isolation lead to disbelief (Norenzayan & Gervais Reference Norenzayan and Gervais2013).

Therefore, rather than seeing “atheism” as a single phenomenon, our model treats it as a blanket term for several pathways to disbelief, including (1) mindblind atheism associated with deficits in mentalizing; (2) InCREDulous atheism, caused by the lack of witnessing extravagant displays of religious commitment; (3) apatheism or indifference to religion induced by the absence of existential threats or material hardship; and (4) analytic atheism, in which analytic cognitive processes override or block the cognitive intuitions that anchor religious beliefs.Footnote 14

Finally, because this framework tackles both recurrent features of prosocial religions, and historical and cultural changes over time, it gives center stage to questions about the conditions that give rise to secularization. We argue that, whereas multiple pathways likely stabilized large cooperative social groups, religiously driven prosociality was one powerful force. In most of humanity's past, and for many societies even today, the secular mechanisms and institutions that sustain prosociality, were – and often remain – rare or unreliable. Our analysis accommodates the fact that religiosity systematically varies depending on the social conditions that exist in particular populations at particular times. Religious prosociality was once one of the most effective ways to foster exchange among strangers or organize them for cooperative endeavors. However, the recent spread of secular institutions since the industrial revolutions – including democratic political institutions, policing authorities, and effective contract-enforcing mechanisms – has ushered in widespread large-scale prosociality without gods.

Our framework, therefore, provides an account of how secular societies climbed the ladder of prosocial religion and then kicked it away. Prosocial religions may have buttressed a cultural bridge between the small-scale human societies that dominated much of our evolutionary history and the complex secular societies of the modern world. However, with the emergence of strong secular institutions that promote public trust and existential security (Norris & Inglehart Reference Norris and Inglehart2004), the selective forces that spread and sustained these belief–ritual packages began to ebb. This may have led first to a downgrading of concepts such as hell and God's wrath, which would have weakened the forces sustaining prosocial religions, and then gradually to the loss of religious faith itself. Conversely, prosocial religions continue to thrive where existential threats, such as natural disasters, material insecurity, and inefficient rule of law, remain rampant (e.g., Bentzen Reference Bentzen2013; Norris & Inglehart Reference Norris and Inglehart2004; Sibley & Bulbulia Reference Sibley and Bulbulia2012).

It appears that God and government are both culturally and psychologically interchangeable. Experimentally induced reminders of secular moral authority had as much effect on generous behavior in an economic game as reminders of God (Shariff & Norenzayan Reference Shariff and Norenzayan2007). The effect of participation in a world religion on punishing of selfish behavior disappears when a third-party punisher is introduced into the game (Henrich et al. Reference Henrich, Ensimger, McElreath, Barr, Barrett, Bolyanatz, Cardenas, Gurven, Gwako, Henrich, Lesorogol, Marlowe, Tracer and Ziker2010a), also suggesting some psychological interchangeability between supernatural and secular sources of monitoring and punishment. Cross-national surveys show that greater trust in government stability and control undermines religion (Norris & Inglehart Reference Norris and Inglehart2004) and reduces distrust of atheists among believers (Gervais & Norenzayan Reference Gervais and Norenzayan2012b; Norenzayan & Gervais Reference Norenzayan and Gervais2015). Moreover, experimental manipulations or naturally occurring events (e.g., electoral instability) that lower faith in one of these external control systems (God or the government) lead to subsequent increases in faith in the other (Kay et al. Reference Kay, Gaucher, Napier, Callan and Laurin2008). There are signs that some societies with strong institutions and stable life conditions have passed a threshold, no longer leaning on prosocial religious elements to sustain large-scale prosociality. Some of the most cooperative and trusting societies, such as those in Scandinavia, are also the least religious (Zuckerman Reference Zuckerman2008).

7.4. Conclusion

It is far from clear whether secularization will outpace prosocial religions. Worldwide evidence shows that societies, as they experience the emergence of strong secular institutions that reduce existential insecurity and ensure the rule of law, become more secular (Norris & Inglehart Reference Norris and Inglehart2004). However, prosocial religions continue to convey a reproductive advantage (Blume Reference Blume, Voland and Schiefenhövel2009; Norris & Inglehart Reference Norris and Inglehart2004), which means that religious societies are still growing faster than secular ones, countervailing the great inroads made by secularization. As a result, the majority of the world's population remains religious (Norris & Inglehart Reference Norris and Inglehart2004), and the vast majority of adherents belong to the prosocial religions. This tension between demographics and economics – along with the corresponding interplays and rivalries among various competing prosocial religions, and the tension between religiosity and secularity – remains a defining feature of modernity (Taylor Reference Taylor2007) and one that will continue to shape the world in the coming century.

ACKNOWLEDGMENTS

The writing of this article was supported by the Cultural Evolution of Religion Research Consortium (CERC) at the University of British Columbia, funded by a generous partnership grant, “The Evolution of Religion and Morality” [895–2011–1009], from the Social Sciences and Humanities Research Council of Canada. AN thanks the James McKeen Cattell Fund for a Sabbatical Fellowship. JH thanks the Canadian Institute for Advanced Research. Colin Xu provided technical assistance.

Footnotes

1. We consider 12,000 years a convenient starting point for when the first human groups in the Middle East began to scale up (cf. Diamond Reference Diamond1997a). However, this process unfolded at different times in different regions, and there were fluctuations in the size and social complexity of human groups even in the Pleistocene.

2. Richerson et al. (Reference Richerson, Boyd and Bettinger2001) show why demographic growth cannot account for this expansion. Note that some evolutionary researchers do not see this as a puzzle, arguing that our “hunter–gatherer psychology” (e.g., kin and reciprocity psychology) in the absence of any cultural evolution simply “misfires” to create a ready path to large-scale cooperation (Burnham & Johnson Reference Burnham and Johnson2005; Dawkins Reference Dawkins2006). The limitations of this argument have been discussed elsewhere (Chudek et al. Reference Chudek, Zhao, Henrich, Joyce, Sterelny and Calcott2013).

3. We label these evolutionarily modern religious groups “prosocial” to emphasize the fact that they encourage prosocial behavior among their adherents. It should be noted that we see this prosociality as a form of parochial altruism (e.g., Bowles Reference Bowles2006); that is, preferentially applied toward in-group members, and when real or perceived intergroup threat is present, coupled with hostility toward out-groups. Moreover, we do not claim that these elements are unique to religious groups. We see no natural partition between “religious” and “cultural” representations; rather, what is distinctive and impactful is the convergence of these elements and their cultural evolution in historical time. Finally, we emphasize that our explanatory focus is on “natural religion”: the lived folk religious beliefs and behaviors among ordinary believers, not the theological doctrines or texts found in some groups (McCauley Reference McCauley2011).

4. In this category we include aspects of epistemic vigilance (Sperber et al. Reference Sperber, Clément, Heintz, Mascaro, Mercier, Origgi and Wilson2010). Also, we include here cultural transmission of belief or commitment based on hard-to-fake emotional or physiological cues, such as involuntary crying and shaking. Other scholars have considered such behaviors in the context of signaling models (Bulbulia Reference Bulbulia, Bulbulia, Richard, Genet, Harris, Wynan and Genet2008; Frank Reference Frank1988; Schloss Reference Schloss, Bulbulia, Richard, Genet, Harris, Wynan and Genet2007; Slingerland Reference Slingerland2014).

5. In discussing the varying cultural survival rates of religious ideas, traditions, and groups, we take care not to conflate cultural success with moral superiority: a version of the well-known is-ought fallacy (i.e., what is, is good).

6. Also see Marlowe (Reference Marlowe2010) for similar observations of Hadza foragers, and for recent quantitative evidence among Tyvan pastoralists in Siberia, see Purzycki (Reference Purzycki2011) and Purzycki (Reference Purzycki2013).

7. Schneider, personal communication. Coffin Text spell 1130; see discussion in Enmarch (Reference Enmarch, Dieleman and Wendrich2008), and compare with Assmann (Reference Assmann2001) and Lazaridis (Reference Lazaridis, Frood and Wendrich2008).

8. After this target article was accepted for publication, we became aware of a preregistered study (Gomes & McCullough, Reference Gomes and McCulloughin press) that found no effect of religious reminders on dictator game offers. (For a commentary on this study, see Shariff & Norenzayan, Reference Shariff, Willard, Andersen and Norenzayanin press). When we re-analyzed the above meta-analysis, focusing on prosocial behaviors with this null finding included (n = 5,475), the mean effect size was g = 0.25, p<0.0001, 95% CI = (0.13, 0.37). A subset of 11 of these studies that distinguished effect sizes based on prior religious belief revealed once again a reliable effect for believers (g = 0.38, p = .002) but not for nonbelievers (g = 0.12, p = .31).

9. The related Mickey Mouse Problem asks why people do not worship the minimally counterintuitive agents in cartoons, myths, and folk tales (Atran & Norenzayan Reference Atran and Norenzayan2004; cf. Barrett Reference Barrett2008).

10. Baumard and Boyer (Reference Baumard and Boyer2013) propose to explain prosocial religions as cultural reflections of evolved moral intuitions, such as proportionality and fairness, and argue against the idea that some religions spread by having prosocial effects. However, as we explain in section 7.2, it is unclear to us how this “by-product only” account explains the full range of observations: historical, cross-cultural, and experimental.

11. We note that formal models of signaling typically produce many different stable equilibria, only some of which are signaling equilibria and even fewer of which involve any prosocial behavior. Cultural group selection provides a mechanism by which these more group-beneficial signaling equilibria can spread, and at the same time permits us to account for the immense diversity of signaling systems across human societies and their change over historical time (Henrich Reference Henrich2009). Once individuals come to differ in their degrees of commitment to a religious doctrine, signals of various kinds can allow them to assort (honestly) according to their degree of commitment. We think cultural evolution has harnessed both CREDs and signaling mechanisms.

12. We thank an anonymous reviewer for this suggestion.

13. For worldwide prevalence of atheists, see Zuckerman (Reference Zuckerman and Martin2007).

14. For a review, see Norenzayan and Gervais (Reference Norenzayan and Gervais2013) and Norenzayan (Reference Norenzayan2013). See also similar arguments concerning different forms of disbelief and the importance of cultural and linguistic environment to religious disbelief (Banerjee & Bloom Reference Banerjee and Bloom2013; Bulbulia Reference Bulbulia, Wildman and McNamara2012; Geertz & Markusson Reference Geertz and Markusson2010; Lanman Reference Lanman2012; McCauley Reference McCauley2011).

References

Ahmed, A. M. (2009) Are religious people more prosocial? A quasi-experimental study with madrasah pupils in a rural community in India. Journal for the Scientific Study of Religion 48:368–74.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Alexander, R. (1987) The biology of moral systems. Aldine De Gruyter.Google Scholar
Ames, H. & Rosemont, R. T. (2009) The Chinese classic of family reverence: A philosophical translation of the Xiaojing. University of Hawaii Press.Google Scholar
Assmann, J. (2001) The search for God in ancient Egypt. Cornell University Press.Google Scholar
Atkinson, Q. D. & Bourrat, P. (2011) Beliefs about God, the afterlife and morality support the role of supernatural policing in human cooperation. Evolution and Human Behavior 32:4149.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Atkinson, Q. D. & Whitehouse, H. (2011) The cultural morphospace of ritual form: Examining modes of religiosity cross-culturally. Evolution and Human Behavior 32:5062.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Atran, S. (2002) In gods we trust: The evolutionary landscape of religion. Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Atran, S. (2010a) Talking to the enemy: Faith, brotherhood and the (un)making of terrorists. Harper-Collins.Google Scholar
Atran, S. & Ginges, J. (2012) Religious and sacred imperatives in human conflict. Science 336:855–57.Google Scholar
Atran, S. & Henrich, J. (2010) The evolution of religion: How cognitive by-products, adaptive learning heuristics, ritual displays, and group competition generate deep commitments to prosocial religions. Biological Theory: Integrating Development, Evolution, and Cognition 5:1830.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Atran, S. & Norenzayan, A. (2004) Religion's evolutionary landscape: Counterintuition, commitment, compassion, communion. Behavioral and Brain Sciences 27:713–70.Google Scholar
Banerjee, K. & Bloom, P. (2013) Would Tarzan believe in God? Trends in Cognitive Sciences 17:78.Google Scholar
Barrett, J. L. (2000) Exploring the natural foundations of religion. Trends in Cognitive Science 4:2934.Google Scholar
Barrett, J. L. (2004) Why would anyone believe in God? AltaMira Press.Google Scholar
Barrett, J. L. (2008) Why Santa Claus is not a god. Journal of Cognition and Culture 8:149–61.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Barrett, J. L. & Keil, F. C. (1996) Conceptualizing a nonnatural entity: Anthropomorphism in god concepts. Cognitive Psychology 31:219–47.Google Scholar
Barro, R. J. & McCleary, R. M. (2003) Religion and economic growth across countries. American Sociological Review 68:760–81.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bateson, M., Nettle, D. & Roberts, G. (2006) Cues of being watched enhance cooperation in a real-world setting. Biology Letters 2:412–14.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Batson, C. D., Schoenrade, P. & Ventis, W. L. (1993) Religion and the individual: A social-psychological perspective. Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Baumard, N. & Boyer, P. (2013) Explaining moral religions. Trends in Cognitive Sciences 17:272–80.Google Scholar
Beck, W. (1992) Aboriginal preparation of cycads seeds in Australia. Economic Botany 46:133–47.Google Scholar
Bell, A. V., Richerson, P. & McElreath, R. (2009) Culture rather than genes provides greater scope for the evolution of large-scale human prosociality. Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences of the United States of America 106:17671–74.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Bellah, R. N. (2011) Religion in human evolution: From the Paleolithic to the Axial Age. Harvard University Press.Google Scholar
Bentzen, J. S. (2013) Origins of religiousness: The role of natural disasters. Discussion Paper No. 13-02. Department of Economics, University of Copenhagen, Copenhagen, Denmark. Available at: http://papers.ssrn.com/sol3/papers.cfm?abstract_id=2221859.Google Scholar
Bering, J. (2011) The belief instinct: The psychology of souls, destiny, and the meaning of life. Norton.Google Scholar
Bering, J. M. (2006) The folk psychology of souls. Behavioral and Brain Sciences 29:453–98.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Bering, J. M. & Johnson, D. D. P. (2005) “O lord you perceive my thoughts from afar”: Recursiveness and the evolution of supernatural agency. Journal of Cognition and Culture 5:118–42.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bloom, P. (2004) Descartes' baby. Basic Books.Google Scholar
Bloom, P. (2007) Religion is natural. Developmental Science 10:147–51.Google Scholar
Bloom, P. (2012) Religion, morality, evolution. Annual Review of Psychology 63:179–99. doi: 10.1146/annurev-psych-120710-100334.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Bloom, P. (2013) Just babies: The origins of good and evil. Crown.Google Scholar
Bloom, P. & Weisberg, D. S. (2007) Childhood origins of adult resistance to science. Science 316:996–97.Google Scholar
Blume, M. (2009) The reproductive benefits of religious affiliation. In: The biological evolution of religious mind and behavior, ed. Voland, E. & Schiefenhövel, W., pp. 117–26. Springer-Verlag.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Boehm, C. (2008) A biocultural evolutionary exploration of supernatural sanctioning. In: Evolution of religion: Studies, theories, and critiques, ed. Bulbulia, J., Sosis, R., Harris, E., Genet, R., Genet, C. & Wyman, K., pp. 143–52. Collins Foundation Press.Google Scholar
Botero, C. A., Gardner, B., Kirby, K. R., Bulbulia, J., Gavin, M. C. & Gray, R. D. (2014) The ecology of religious beliefs. PNAS 111(47):16784–89.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Bottéro, J. (2001) Religion in ancient Mesopotamia. University of Chicago Press.Google Scholar
Bowles, S. (2006) Group competition, reproductive leveling, and the evolution of human altruism. Science 314:1569–72.Google Scholar
Bowles, S. (2008) Conflict: Altruism's midwife. Science 456:326–27.Google Scholar
Boyd, D. (2001) Life without pigs: Recent subsistence changes among the Irakia Awa, Papua New Guinea. Human Ecology 29:259–81.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Boyd, R., Gintis, H. & Richerson, P. J. (2003) The evolution of altruistic punishment. Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences of the United States of America 100:3531–35.Google Scholar
Boyd, R. & Richerson, P. J. (1988) The evolution of reciprocity in sizable groups. Journal of Theoretical Biology 132:337–56.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Boyd, R. & Richerson, P. J. (1990a) Culture and cooperation. In: Beyond self-interest, ed. Mansbridge, J., pp. 111–33. University of Chicago Press.Google Scholar
Boyd, R. & Richerson, P. J. (2009) Voting with your feet: Payoff biased migration and the evolution of group beneficial behavior. Journal of Theoretical Biology 257:331–39.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Boyd, R., Richerson, P. J. & Henrich, J. (2011a) Rapid cultural adaptation can facilitate the evolution of large-scale cooperation. Behavioral Ecology and Sociobiology 65:431–44.Google Scholar
Boyd, R., Richerson, P. J. & Henrich, J. (2011b) The cultural niche: Why social learning is essential for human adaptation. Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences of the United States of America 108:10918–25.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Boyer, P. (1994) The naturalness of religious ideas: A cognitive theory of religion. University of California Press.Google Scholar
Boyer, P. (2001) Religion explained. The evolutionary origins of religious thought. Basic Books.Google Scholar
Boyer, P. & Ramble, C. (2001) Cognitive templates for religious concepts: Cross-cultural evidence for recall of counter-intuitive representations. Cognitive Science 25:535–64.Google Scholar
Broesch, J., Henrich, J. & Barrett, H. C. (2014) Adaptive content biases in learning about animals across the lifecourse. Human Nature 25:181–99.Google Scholar
Brooks, A. C. (2006) Who really cares: The surprising truth about compassionate conservatism. Basic Books.Google Scholar
Bulbulia, J. (2004) Religious costs as adaptations that signal altruistic intention. Evolution and Cognition 10:938.Google Scholar
Bulbulia, J. (2008) Free love: Religious solidarity on the cheap. In: The evolution of religion: Studies, theories and critiques, ed. Bulbulia, J., Richard, S., Genet, R., Harris, E., Wynan, K. & Genet, C., pp. 153–60. Collins Foundation Press.Google Scholar
Bulbulia, J. (2012) Ennuitheism. In: Science and the world's religions, Volume 3: Religions and controversies, ed. Wildman, W. & McNamara, P., pp. 165–94. Greenwood Publishing Group.Google Scholar
Burkert, W. (1982) Ancient mystery cults. Harvard University Press.Google Scholar
Burnham, T. & Johnson, D. D. P. (2005) The evolutionary and biological logic of human cooperation. Analyse & Kritik 27:113–35.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Carneiro, R. L. (1970) A theory of the origin of the state. Science 169:733–38.Google Scholar
Carter, E. C., McCullough, M. E., Kim-Spoon, J., Corrales, C. & Blake, A. (2012) Religious people discount the future less. Evolution and Human Behavior 33:224–31.Google Scholar
Chapais, B. (2008) Primeval kinship: How pair-bonding gave birth to human society. Harvard University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Choi, J. K. & Bowles, S. (2007) The coevolution of parochial altruism and war. Science 318:636–40.Google Scholar
Chudek, M. & Henrich, J. (2011) Culture-gene coevolution, norm-psychology and the emergence of human prosociality. Trends in Cognitive Sciences 15:218–26.Google Scholar
Chudek, M., MacNamara, R., Birch, S. A., Bloom, P. & Henrich, J. (2015) Developmental and cross-cultural evidence for intuitive dualism. Unpublished manuscript.Google Scholar
Chudek, M., Zhao, W. & Henrich, J. (2013) Culture-gene coevolution, large-scale cooperation and the shaping of human social psychology. In: Signaling, commitment, and emotion, ed. Joyce, R., Sterelny, K. & Calcott, B., pp. 425–57. MIT Press.Google Scholar
Clark, K. J. & Winslett, J. T. (2011) The evolutionary psychology of Chinese religion: Pre-qin high gods as punishers and rewarders. Journal of the American Academy of Religion 79:928–60.Google Scholar
Cohen, E. E. A., Ejsmond-Frey, R., Knight, N. & Dunbar, R. I. M. (2010) Rowers' high: Behavioural synchrony is correlated with elevated pain thresholds. Biology Letters 6:106108.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Crespi, B. J. & Badcock, C. (2008) Psychosis and autism as diametrical disorders of the social brain. Behavioral and Brain Sciences 31:284320.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Cronk, L. (1994) Evolutionary theories of morality and the manipulative use of signals. Zygon 29:81101.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Currie, T. E. & Mace, R. (2009) Political complexity predicts the spread of ethnolinguistic groups. Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences 106:7339–44.Google Scholar
Damisch, L., Stoberock, B. & Mussweiler, T. (2010) Keep your fingers crossed! How superstition improves performance. Psychological Science 21:1014–20.Google Scholar
Darwin, C. (1871) The descent of man. D. Appleton and Company.Google Scholar
Dawkins, R. (2006) The god delusion. Mariner Books.Google Scholar
de Waal, F. (2008) Putting the altruism back into altruism: The evolution of empathy. Annual Review of Psychology 59:279300.Google Scholar
Diamond, J. (1997a) Guns, germs, and steel: The fates of human societies. Norton.Google Scholar
Durkheim, E. (1915) The elementary forms of the religious life. New York Free Press.Google Scholar
Enmarch, R. (2008) Theodicy. In: UCLA encyclopedia of Egyptology, ed. Dieleman, J. & Wendrich, W., pp. 17. UCLA.Google Scholar
Eno, R. (2009) Shang state religion and the pantheon of the Oracle texts. In: Early Chinese religion: Part one: Shang through Han (1250 BC–22 AD), ed. Lagerwey, J. & Kalinowski, M., pp. 41102. Brill.Google Scholar
Ensminger, J. (1997) Transaction costs and Islam: Explaining conversion in Africa. Journal of Institutional and Theoretical Economics 153:428.Google Scholar
Epley, N. & Waytz, A. (2010) Mind perception. In: The handbook of social psychology, fifth edition, ed. Fiske, S. T., Gilbert, D. T., & Lindsay, G., pp. 498541. Wiley.Google Scholar
Epley, N., Waytz, A. & Cacioppo, J. T. (2007) On seeing human: A three-factor theory of anthropomorphism. Psychological Review 114:864–86.Google Scholar
Fehr, E. & Fischbacher, U. (2003) The nature of human altruism. Nature 425:785–91.Google Scholar
Fehr, E., Fischbacher, U. & Gächter, S. (2002) Strong reciprocity, human cooperation and the enforcement of social norms. Human Nature 13:125.Google Scholar
Fehr, E. & Schneider, F. (2010) Eyes are on us, but nobody cares: Are eye cues relevant for strong reciprocity? Proceedings of the Royal Society B: Biological Sciences 277:1315–23.Google Scholar
Fernandez, R. & Fogli, A. (2009) Culture: An empirical investigation of beliefs, work, and fertility. American Economic Journal: Macroeconomics 1:146–77.Google Scholar
Flannery, K. V. & Marcus, J. (2000) Formative Mexican chiefdoms and the myth of the “Mother Culture.” Journal of Anthropological Archaeology 19:137.Google Scholar
Forge, A. (1972) Normative factors in the settlement size of neolithic cultivators (New Guinea). In: Man, settlement, and urbanisation, ed. Ucko, P., Tringham, R. & Dimbelby, G., pp. 363–76. Duckworth.Google Scholar
Frank, R. H. (1988) Passions within reason. Norton.Google Scholar
Frith, U. & Frith, C. D. (2003) Development and neurophysiology of mentalizing. Philosophical Transactions of the Royal Society of London. Series B: Biological Sciences 358:459–73. doi: 10.1098/rstb.2002.1218.Google Scholar
Geertz, A. W. & Markusson, G. I. (2010) Religion is natural, atheism is not: On why everybody is both right and wrong. Religion 40:152–65.Google Scholar
Gervais, W. M. (2013) Perceiving minds and gods: How mind perception enables, constrains, and is triggered by belief in gods. Perspectives on Psychological Science 8:380–94.Google Scholar
Gervais, W. M. & Henrich, J. (2010) The Zeus problem: Why representational content biases cannot explain faith in gods. Journal of Cognition and Culture 10:383–89.Google Scholar
Gervais, W. M. & Norenzayan, A. (2012a) Like a camera in the sky? Thinking about god increases public self-awareness and socially desirable responding. Journal of Experimental Social Psychology 48:298302. doi: 10.1016/j.jesp.2011.09.006.Google Scholar
Gervais, W. M. & Norenzayan, A. (2012b) Reminders of secular authority reduce believers' distrust of atheists. Psychological Science 23:483–91.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Gervais, W. M. & Norenzayan, A. (2013) Religion and the origins of anti-atheist prejudice. In: Intolerance and conflict: A scientific and conceptual investigation, ed. Clarke, S., Powell, R. & Savulescu, J., pp. 126–45. Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Gervais, W. M., Shariff, A. F. & Norenzayan, A. (2011a) Do you believe in atheists? Distrust is central to anti-atheist prejudice. Journal of Personality and Social Psychology 101:1189–206.Google Scholar
Gervais, W. M., Willard, A. K., Norenzayan, A. & Henrich, J. (2011b) The cultural transmission of faith: Why innate intuitions are necessary, but insufficient, to explain religious belief. Religion 41:389410.Google Scholar
Ginges, J., Atran, S., Medin, D. & Shikaki, K. (2007) Sacred bounds on rational resolution of violent political conflict. Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences 104:7357–60.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Ginges, J., Hansen, I. & Norenzayan, A. (2009) Religion and support for suicide attacks. Psychological Science 20:224–30.Google Scholar
Gomes, C. M. & McCullough, M. E. (in press) The effects of implicit religious primes on dictator game allocations: A preregistered replication experiment. Journal of Experimental Psychology: General.Google Scholar
Graham, J. & Haidt, J. (2010) Beyond beliefs: Religions bind individuals into moral communities. Personality and Social Psychology Review 14:140–50.Google Scholar
Granet, M. (1934) La pensée chinoise. La Renaissance du Livre.Google Scholar
Greif, A. (2006) Institutions and the path to the modern economy: Lessons from medieval trade. Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Gürerk, Ö., Irlenbusch, B. & Rockenbach, B. (2006) The competitive advantage of sanctioning institutions. Science 312:108–11.Google Scholar
Guthrie, S. (1993) Faces in the clouds. Oxford University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Guzman, R. A., Rodriguez-Sickert, C. & Rowthorn, R. (2007) When in Rome, do as the Romans do: The coevolution of altruistic punishment, conformist learning, and cooperation. Evolution and Human Behavior 28:112–17.Google Scholar
Haidt, J. (2012) The righteous mind: Why good people are divided by politics and religion. Pantheon Books.Google Scholar
Haidt, J., & Kesebir, S. (2010) Morality. In: Handbook of Social Psychology, fifth edition, ed. Fiske, S., & Gilbert, D., pp. 797832. Wiley.Google Scholar
Haley, K. J. & Fessler, D. M. T. (2005) Nobody's watching? Subtle cues affects generosity in an anonymous economic game. Evolution and Human Behavior 26:245–56.Google Scholar
Hamlin, J. K., Wynn, K. & Bloom, P. (2007) Social evaluation by preverbal infants. Nature 450:557–59.Google Scholar
Harris, P. L. (2012) Trusting what we're told: How children learn from others. Harvard University Press.Google Scholar
Hayek, F. (1988) The fatal conceit. In: The collected works of F.A. Hayek, vol. 1, ed. Bartley, W., pp. 6685. University of Chicago Press.Google Scholar
Heath, C., Bell, C. & Sternberg, E. (2001) Emotional selection in memes: The case of urban legends. Journal of Personality and Social Psychology 81:1028–41.Google Scholar
Henrich, J. (2004) Cultural group selection, coevolutionary processes and large-scale cooperation. Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization 53:325.Google Scholar
Henrich, J. (2009) The evolution of costly displays, cooperation and religion: Credibility enhancing displays and their implications for cultural evolution. Evolution and Human Behavior 30:244–60.Google Scholar
Henrich, J. (2012) Hunter-gatherer cooperation. Nature 481:449–50.Google Scholar
Henrich, J. (2015) The secret of our success: How learning from others drove human evolution, domesticated our species, and made us smart. Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Henrich, J. & Boyd, R. (2001) Why people punish defectors: Weak conformist transmission can stabilize costly enforcement of norms in cooperative dilemmas. Journal of Theoretical Biology 208:7879.Google Scholar
Henrich, J., Boyd, R. & Richerson, P. J. (2012) The puzzle of monogamous marriage. Philosophical Transactions of the Royal Society B: Biological Sciences 367:657–66.Google Scholar
Henrich, J., Ensminger, J., Barr, A. & McElreath, R. (2014) Major empirical results: Markets, religion, community size, and the evolution of fairness and punishment. In: Experimenting with social norms: Fairness and punishment in cross-cultural perspective, ed. Ensminger, J. & Henrich, J., pp. 89148. Russell Sage Foundation.Google Scholar
Henrich, J., Ensimger, J., McElreath, R., Barr, A., Barrett, C., Bolyanatz, A., Cardenas, J., Gurven, M., Gwako, E., Henrich, N., Lesorogol, C., Marlowe, F., Tracer, D. & Ziker, J. (2010a) Markets, religion, community size, and the evolution of fairness and punishment. Science 327:1480–84.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Henrich, J. & Gil-White, F. (2001) The evolution of prestige: Freely conferred deference as a mechanism for enhancing the benefits of cultural transmission. Evolution and Human Behavior 22(3):132, 165–96.Google Scholar
Henrich, J., Heine, S. J. & Norenzayan, A. (2010b) The weirdest people in the world? Behavioral and Brain Sciences 33(2–3):61135.Google Scholar
Henrich, N. & Henrich, J. (2007) Why humans cooperate: A cultural and evolutionary explanation. Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Herrmann, B., Thoni, C. & Gächter, S. (2008) Antisocial punishment across societies. Science 319(5868):1362–67.Google Scholar
Herrmann, P. A., Legare, C. H., Harris, P. L. & Whitehouse, H. (2013) Stick to the script: The effect of witnessing multiple actors on children's imitation. Cognition 129:536–43.Google Scholar
Hill, K. R., Walker, R. S., Božičević, M., Eder, J., Headland, T., Hewlett, B., Hurtado, A. M., Marlowe, F., Wiessner, P. & Wood, B. (2011) Co-residence patterns in Hunter-Gatherer societies show unique human social structure. Science 331:1286–89.Google Scholar
Hove, M. J. & Risen, J. L. (2009) It's all in the timing: Interpersonal synchrony increases affiliation. Social Cognition 27:949–60.Google Scholar
Hruschka, D., Efferson, C., Jiang, T., Falletta-Cowden, A., Sigurdsson, S., McNamara, R., Sands, M., Munira, S., Slingerland, E. & Henrich, J. (2014) Impartial institutions, pathogen stress, and the expanding social network. Human Nature 25:567–79.Google Scholar
Huebner, B., Lee, J. L. & Hauser, M. D. (2010) The moral conventional distinction in mature moral competence. Journal of Cognition and Culture 10:126.Google Scholar
Iannaccone, L. R. (1994) Why strict churches are strong. American Journal of Sociology 99: 1180–11.Google Scholar
Inzlicht, M. & Tullett, A. M. (2010) Reflecting on god: Religious primes can reduce neuropsychological response to errors. Psychological Science 21:1181–90.Google Scholar
Irons, W. (2001) Religion as a hard-to-fake sign of commitment. In: Evolution and the capacity for commitment, ed. Nesse, R., pp. 292309. Russell Sage Foundation.Google Scholar
Jaspers, K. (1953) The origin and goal of history. Trans. Bullock, M.. Yale University Press. (Original work, Vom Urspring und Ziel der Geschichte, published in 1949.)Google Scholar
Johnson, A. W. & Earle, T. (2000) The evolution of human societies, second edition. Stanford University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Johnson, D. D. P. (2005) God's punishment and public goods – a test of the supernatural punishment hypothesis in 186 world cultures. Human Nature 16(4):410–46. doi: 10.1007/s12110-005-1017-0.Google Scholar
Johnson, D. D. P. (2009) The error of god: Error management theory, Religion and the evolution of cooperation. In: Games, groups and the global good, ed. Levin, S. A., pp. 169–80. Springer-Verlag.Google Scholar
Johnson, D. D. P. & Bering, J. M. (2006) Hand of god, mind of man: Punishment and cognition in the evolution of cooperation. Evolutionary Psychology 4:219–33.Google Scholar
Kapogiannis, D., Barbey, A. K., Su, M., Zamboni, G., Krueger, F. & Grafman, J. (2009) Cognitive and neural foundations of religious belief. Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences 106:4876–81.Google Scholar
Kaufmann, E. (2010) Shall the religious inherit the earth?: Demography and politics in the twenty-first century. Profile Books.Google Scholar
Kay, A. C., Gaucher, D., Napier, J. L., Callan, M. J. & Laurin, K. (2008) God and the government: Testing a compensatory control mechanism for the support of external systems. Journal of Personality and Social Psychology 95:1835.Google Scholar
Kelemen, D. (2004) Are children “Intuitive Theists”? Reasoning about purpose and design in nature. Psychological Science 15:295301.Google Scholar
Kelly, R. C. (1985) The Nuer conquest: The structure and development of an expansionist system. University of Michigan Press.Google Scholar
Kenward, B., Karlsson, M. & Persson, J. (2010) Over-imitation is better explained by norm learning than by distorted causal learning. Proceedings of the Royal Society B: Biological Sciences 278:1239–46.Google Scholar
Khaldun, I. (1958) The Muqaddimah: An introduction to history. Trans. Rosenthal, F.. Routledge and Kegan Paul.Google Scholar
Kirch, P. V. (2010) How chiefs became kings: Divine kingship and the rise of archaic states in ancient Hawai'i. University of California Press.Google Scholar
Kirkpatrick, L. A. (1999) Toward an evolutionary psychology of religion and personality. Journal of Personality 67:921–52. doi: 10.1111/1467-6494.00078.Google Scholar
Kirschner, S. & Tomasello, M. (2010) Joint music making promotes prosocial behavior in 4-year-old children. Evolution and Human Behavior 31:354–64.Google Scholar
Konvalinka, I., Xygalatas, D., Bulbulia, J., Schjoedt, U., Jegindo, E. M. & Wallot, S. (2011) Synchronized arousal between performers and related spectators in a fire-walking ritual. Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences 108:8514–19.Google Scholar
Lanman, J. (2012) The importance of religious displays for belief acquisition and secularization. Journal of Contemporary Religion 27:4965.Google Scholar
Laurin, K., Kay, A. C. & Fitzsimons, G. M. (2012a) Divergent effects of activating thoughts of god on self-regulation. Journal of Personality and Social Psychology 102:421.Google Scholar
Laurin, K., Shariff, A. F., Henrich, J. & Kay, A. C. (2012b) Outsourcing punishment to God: Beliefs in divine control reduce earthly punishment. Proceedings of the Royal Society B: Biological Sciences 279:3272–81.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Lawson, E. T. & McCauley, R. N. (1990) Rethinking religion: Connecting cognition and culture. Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Lazaridis, N. (2008) Ethics. In: UCLA encyclopedia of Egyptology, ed. Frood, E. & Wendrich, W.. UCLA.Google Scholar
Lee, R. (1979) The !Kung San: Men, women, and work in a foraging society. Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Legare, C. H., Evans, E. M., Rosengren, K. S. & Harris, P. L. (2012) The coexistence of natural and supernatural explanations across cultures and development. Child Development 83:779–93.Google Scholar
Legare, C. H. & Souza, A. L. (2012) Evaluating ritual efficacy: Evidence from the supernatural. Cognition: 124:115.Google Scholar
Legare, C. H. & Souza, A. L. (2014) Searching for control: Priming randomness increases the evaluation of ritual efficacy. Cognitive science 38:152–61.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Lyons, D. E., Young, A. G. & Keil, F. C. (2007) The hidden structure of overimitation. Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences 104:19751–56.Google Scholar
Marcus, J. & Flannery, K. V. (2004) The coevolution of ritual and society: New C-14 dates from ancient Mexico. Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences of the United States of America 101:18257–61.Google Scholar
Marlowe, F. (2010) The Hadza: Hunter-gatherers of Tanzania. University of California Press.Google Scholar
Marlowe, F., Berbesque, J. C., Barr, A., Barrett, C., Bolyanatz, A., Cardenas, J. C., Ensminger, J., Gurven, M., Gwako, E., Henrich, J., Henrich, N., Lesorogol, C., McElreath, R. & Tracer, D. (2008) More “altruistic” punishment in larger societies. Proceedings of the Royal Society B: Biological Sciences 275:587–90.Google Scholar
Marlowe, F. W. (2004) Dictators and ultimatums in an egalitarian society of hunter-gatherers, the Hadza of Tanzania. In: Foundations of human sociality: Economic experiments and ethnographic evidence from fifteen small-scale societies, ed. Henrich, J., Boyd, R., Bowles, S., Camerer, C., Fehr, E. & Gintis, H., pp. 168–93. Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Marshall, L. (1962) !Kung Bushman religious beliefs. Africa: Journal of the International African Institute 32:221–52.Google Scholar
McCauley, R. N. (2011) Why religion is natural and science is not. Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
McCleary, R. M. & Barro, R. J. (2006) Religion and economy. The Journal of Economic Perspectives 20:4972.Google Scholar
McCullough, M. E. & Willoughby, B. L. B. (2009) Religion, self-regulation, and self-control: Associations, explanations, and implications. Psychological Bulletin 135:6993. doi: 10.1037/a0014213.Google Scholar
McNamara, R. A., Norenzayan, A. & Henrich, J. (2016) Supernatural punishment, in-group biases, and material insecurity: Experiments and ethnography from Yasawa, Fiji. Religion, Brain, and Behavior 6(1):3455.Google Scholar
McNeill, W. H. (1982) Pursuit of power: Technology, armed force, and society since A.D. 1000. University of Chicago Press.Google Scholar
McNeill, W. H. (1995) Keeping together in time. Harvard University Press.Google Scholar
Mikalson, J. (2010) Ancient Greek religion. Blackwell Publishing.Google Scholar
Murdock, G P. (1981) Atlas of world cultures. University of Pittsburgh Press.Google Scholar
Nesse, R. (1999) Evolution of commitment and the origins of religion. Science and Spirit 10:3236.Google Scholar
Neuberg, S. L., Warner, C. Mistler, S. Berlin, A., Hill, E., Johnson, J., Filip-Crawford, G., Millsap, R., Thomas, G. M., Winkelman, M., Broome, B., Taylor, T. & Schober. J. (2014) Religion and intergroup conflict: Findings from the Global Group Relations Project. Psychological Science 25:198206.Google Scholar
Nielsen, M. & Tomaselli, K. (2010) Overimitation in the Kalahari Bushman children and the origins of human cultural cognition. Psychological Science 21:729–36.Google Scholar
Norenzayan, A. (2013) Big Gods: How religion transformed cooperation and conflict. Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Norenzayan, A. (2014) Does religion make people moral? Behaviour 151:365–84.Google Scholar
Norenzayan, A. & Gervais, W. M. (2013) The origins of religious disbelief. Trends in Cognitive Science 17:2025.Google Scholar
Norenzayan, A. & Gervais, W. M. (2015) Secular rule of law erodes believers' political intolerance of atheists. Religion, Brain and Behavior 5:314.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Norenzayan, A., Gervais, W. M. & Trzesniewski, K. H. (2012) Mentalizing deficits constrain belief in a personal God. PLOS ONE 7:e36880. doi: 10.1371/journal.pone.0036880.Google Scholar
Norenzayan, A., Henrich, J. & Slingerland, E. (2013) Religious prosociality: A synthesis. In: Cultural evolution, ed. Richerson, P. & Christiansen, M., pp. 365–78. The MIT Press.Google Scholar
Norenzayan, A. & Shariff, A. F. (2008) The origin and evolution of religious prosociality. Science 322:5862. Available at: http://dx.doi.org/10.1126/science.1158757.Google Scholar
Norris, P. & Inglehart, R. (2004) Sacred and secular: Religion and politics worldwide. Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Obeyesekere, G. (2002) Imagining karma: Ethical transformation in Amerindian, Buddhist, and Greek rebirth. University of California Press.Google Scholar
Otterbein, K. F. (1970) The evolution of war: A cross-cultural study. Human Relations Area Files Press.Google Scholar
Paciotti, B. & Hadley, C. (2003) The ultimatum game in Southwestern Tanzania: Ethnic variation and institutional scope1. Current Anthropology 44:427–32.Google Scholar
Paladino, M. P., Mazzurega, M., Pavani, F. & Schubert, T. W. (2010) Synchronous multisensory stimulation blurs self-other boundaries. Psychological Science 21:1202–207.Google Scholar
Panchanathan, K. & Boyd, R. (2003) A tale of two defectors: The importance of standing for the evolution of indirect reciprocity. Journal of Theoretical Biology 224:115–26.Google Scholar
Peoples, H. C. & Marlowe, F. W. (2012) Subsistence and the evolution of religion. Human Nature 23:253–69. doi:10.1007/s12110-012-9148-6.Google Scholar
Perreault, C., Moya, C. & Boyd, R. (2012) A Bayesian approach to the evolution of social learning. Evolution and Human Behavior 33:449–59.Google Scholar
Poo, M. C. (2009) Rethinking ghosts in world religions. Brill.Google Scholar
Purzycki, B. G. (2011) Tyvan Cher Eezi and the sociological constraints of supernatural agents' minds. Religion, Brain and Behavior 1:3145.Google Scholar
Purzycki, B. G. (2013) The minds of gods: A comparative study of supernatural agency. Cognition 129:163–79.Google Scholar
Purzycki, B. G., Finkel, D. N., Shaver, J., Wales, N., Cohen, A. B. & Sosis, R. (2012) What does God know? Supernatural agents' access to socially strategic and non-strategic information. Cognitive Science 36:846–69.Google Scholar
Purzycki, B. G. & Willard, A. K. (in press) MCI theory: A critical discussion. Religion, Brain and Behavior.Google Scholar
Putnam, R. & Campbell, R. (2010) American grace: How religion divides and unites us. Simon & Schuster.Google Scholar
Randolph-Seng, B. & Nielsen, M. E. (2007) Honesty: One effect of primed religious representations. The International Journal for the Psychology of Religion 17:303–15.Google Scholar
Rappaport, R. A. (1999) Ritual and religion in the making of humanity. Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Rauh, N. K. (1993) The sacred bonds of commerce: Religion, economy, and trade society at Hellenistic Roman Delos, 166–87 B.C. Gieben.Google Scholar
Rendell, L., Fogarty, L., Hoppitt, W. J., Morgan, T. J., Webster, M. M. & Laland, K. N. (2011) Cognitive culture: Theoretical and empirical insights into social learning strategies. Trends in Cognitive Sciences 15:6876.Google Scholar
Richerson, P., Hillis, V., Newson, L., Baldini, R., Frost, K., Bell, A., Demps, K., Mathew, S., Newton, E., Narr, N., Ross, C., Smaldino, P., Waring, T. M. & Zefferman, M. (in press) Cultural group selection plays an essential role in explaining human cooperation: A sketch of the evidence. Behavioral and Brain Sciences 38.Google Scholar
Richerson, P. J. & Boyd, R. (1999) Complex societies – the evolutionary origins of a crude superorganism. Human Nature 10:253–89.Google Scholar
Richerson, P. J. & Boyd, R. (2005) Not by genes alone: How culture transformed human evolution. University of Chicago Press.Google Scholar
Richerson, P. J., Boyd, R. & Bettinger, R. L. (2001) Was agriculture impossible during the Pleistocene but mandatory during the Holocene? A climate change hypothesis. American Antiquity 66:387411.Google Scholar
Rigdon, M., Ishii, K., Watabe, M. & Kitayama, S. (2009) Minimal social cues in the dictator game. Journal of Economic Psychology 30:358–67.Google Scholar
Rives, J. (2007) Religion in the Roman empire. Blackwell Publishing.Google Scholar
Roes, F. L. (1995) The size of societies, stratification, and belief in high gods supportive of human morality. Politics and the Life Sciences 14:7377.Google Scholar
Roes, F. L. & Raymond, M. (2003) Belief in moralizing gods. Evolution and Human Behavior 24(2):126–35. doi:10.1016/S1090-5138(02)00134-4.Google Scholar
Roes, F. L. & Raymond, M. (2009) Moralizing gods and the arms-race hypothesis of human society growth. Open Social Science Journal 2:7073.Google Scholar
Rounding, K., Lee, A., Jacobson, J. & Ji, L.-J. (2012) Religion replenishes self-control. Psychological Science 23:635–42.Google Scholar
Saaksvuori, L., Mappes, T. & Puurtinen, M. (2011) Costly punishment prevails in intergroup conflict. Proceedings of the Royal Society B-Biological Sciences 278:3428–36.Google Scholar
Saler, B. (2009) Reduction, integrated theory, and the study of religion. Religion 39:348–51.Google Scholar
Sanderson, S. K. & Roberts, W. W. (2008) The evolutionary forms of the religious life: A cross-cultural, quantitative analysis. American Anthropologist 110:454–66.Google Scholar
Sarkissian, H. (2015) Supernatural, social, and self-monitoring in the scaling-up of Chinese civilization. Religion, Brain and Behavior 5:323–27.Google Scholar
Schjoedt, U., Stødkilde-Jørgensen, H., Geertz, A. W. & Roepstorff, A. (2009) Highly religious participants recruit areas of social cognition in personal prayer. Social Cognitive and Affective Neuroscience 4:199207.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Schloss, J. P. (2007) He who laughs best: Religious affect as a solution to recursive cooperative defection. In: The evolution of religion: Studies, theories, critiques, ed. Bulbulia, J., Richard, S., Genet, R., Harris, E., Wynan, K. & Genet, C., pp. 205–15. Collins Foundation Press.Google Scholar
Schloss, J. P. & Murray, M. J. (2011) Evolutionary accounts of belief in supernatural punishment: A critical review. Religion, Brain and Behavior 1:4699.Google Scholar
Shariff, A. F. & Norenzayan, A. (2007) God is watching you: Priming god concepts increases prosocial behavior in an anonymous economic game. Psychological Science 18:803809.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Shariff, A. F. & Norenzayan, A. (2011) Mean gods make good people: Different views of god predict cheating behavior. International Journal for the Psychology of Religion 21:8596.Google Scholar
Shariff, A. F. & Norenzayan, A. (in press) A question of reliability or of boundary conditions? Commentary on Gomes & McCullough. Journal of Experimental Psychology: General.Google Scholar
Shariff, A. F., Norenzayan, A. & Henrich, J. (2010) The birth of high gods: How the cultural evolution of supernatural policing agents influenced the emergence of complex, cooperative human societies, paving the way for civilization. In: Evolution, culture and the human mind, ed. Schaller, M., Norenzayan, A., Heine, S. J., Yamaguishi, T. & Kameda, T., pp. 119–36. Erlbaum.Google Scholar
Shariff, A. F. & Rhemtulla, M. (2012) Divergent effects of belief in heaven and hell on national crime rates. PLOS ONE 7:e39048.Google Scholar
Shariff, A. F., Willard, A. K., Andersen, T. & Norenzayan, A. (in press) Religious priming: A meta-analysis with a focus on religious prosociality. Personality and Social Psychology Review.Google Scholar
Sibley, C. G. & Bulbulia, J. (2012) Faith after an earthquake: A longitudinal study of religion and perceived health before and after the 2011 Christchurch, New Zealand earthquake. PLOS ONE 7:e49648. doi:10.1371/journal.pone.0049648.Google Scholar
Silver, M. (1995) Economic structures of antiquity (No. 159). Greenwood Publishing Group.Google Scholar
Slingerland, E. (2003) Confucius: Analects: With selections from traditional commentaries. Hackett.Google Scholar
Slingerland, E. (2013) Body and mind in early China: An integrated humanities-science approach. Journal of the American Academy of Religion 81:655.Google Scholar
Slingerland, E. (2014) Trying not to try: The art and science of spontaneity. Random House.Google Scholar
Slingerland, E., Henrich, J. & Norenzayan, A. (2013) The evolution of prosocial religions. In: Cultural evolution: Society, technology, language and religion, ed. Richerson, P. J. & Christiansen, M. H., pp. 331–44. MIT Press.Google Scholar
Smaldino, P. E. (2014) The cultural evolution of emergent group-level traits. Behavioral and Brain Sciences 37:243–95.Google Scholar
Snarey, J. (1996) The natural environment's impact upon religious ethics: A cross-cultural study. Journal for the Scientific Study of Religion 35(2):8596.Google Scholar
Soler, M. (2012) Costly signaling, ritual and cooperation: Evidence from Candomblé, an Afro-Brazilian religion. Evolution and Human Behavior 33(4):346–56.Google Scholar
Soltis, J., Boyd, R. & Richerson, P. J. (1995) Can group-functional behaviors evolve by cultural group selection? An empirical test. Current Anthropology 36(3):473–94.Google Scholar
Sosis, R. (2000) Religion and intragroup cooperation: Preliminary results of a comparative analysis of utopian communities. Cross-Cultural Research 34:7087.Google Scholar
Sosis, R. (2009) The adaptationist-byproduct debate on the evolution of religion: Five misunderstandings of the adaptationist program. Journal of Cognition and Culture 9:315–32.Google Scholar
Sosis, R. & Alcorta, C. (2003) Signaling, solidarity, and the sacred: The evolution of religious behavior. Evolutionary Anthropology 12:264–74.Google Scholar
Sosis, R. & Bressler, E. (2003) Cooperation and commune longevity: A test of the costly signaling theory of religion. Cross-Cultural Research 37:211–39.Google Scholar
Sosis, R. & Bulbulia, J. (2011) The behavioral ecology of religion: The benefits and costs of one evolutionary approach. Religion 41:341–62.Google Scholar
Sosis, R., Kress, H. & Boster, J. (2007) Scars for war: Evaluating alternative signaling explanations for cross-cultural variance in ritual costs. Evolution and Human Behavior 28:234–47.Google Scholar
Sosis, R. & Ruffle, B. J. (2003) Religious ritual and cooperation: Testing for a relationship on Israeli religious and secular kibbutzim. Current Anthropology 44:713–22.Google Scholar
Spencer, C. & Redmond, E. (2001) Multilevel selection and political evolution in the valley of Oaxaca. Journal of Anthropological Archaeology 20:195229.Google Scholar
Sperber, D. (1996) Explaining culture: A naturalistic approach. Wiley-Blackwell.Google Scholar
Sperber, D., Clément, F., Heintz, C., Mascaro, O., Mercier, H., Origgi, G. & Wilson, D. (2010) Epistemic vigilance. Mind & Language 25:359–93.Google Scholar
Stark, R. (1996) The rise of Christianity: How the obscure, marginal, Jesus movement became the dominant religious force. HarperOne.Google Scholar
Stark, R. (2001) Gods, rituals, and the moral order. Journal for the Scientific Study of Religion 40:619–36.Google Scholar
Stausberg, M. (2010) Prospects in theories of religion. Method and Theory in the Study of Religion 22:223–28.Google Scholar
Stubbersfield, J. M., Tehrani, J. J. & Flynn, E. G. (2015) Serial killers, spiders and cybersex: Social and survival information bias in the transmission of urban legends. British Journal of Psychology 106(2):288307.Google Scholar
Swann, W. B., Gomez, A., Seyle, D. C., Morales, J. F. & Huici, C. (2009) Identity fusion: The interplay of personal and social identities in extreme group behavior. Journal of Personality and Social Psychology 96:9951011.Google Scholar
Swanson, G. E. (1960) The birth of the gods. University of Michigan Press.Google Scholar
Taves, A. (2009) Religious experience reconsidered: A building-block approach to the study of religion and other special things. Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Taylor, C. (1989) Sources of the self: The makings of modern identity. Harvard University Press.Google Scholar
Taylor, C. (2007) A secular age. Belknap Harvard.Google Scholar
Thote, A. (2009) Shang and Zhou funeral practices: interpretation of material vestiges. In: Early Chinese religion: Part one: Shang though Han (1250 BC-22 AD), ed. Lagerwey, J. & Kalinowski, M., pp. 103–42. Brill.Google Scholar
Tomasello, M. (2001) The cultural origins of human cognition. Harvard University Press.Google Scholar
Turchin, P. (2003) Historical dynamics: Why states rise and fall. Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Turchin, P. (2011) Warfare and the evolution of social complexity: A multilevel selection approach. Structure and Dynamics 4:137.Google Scholar
Turchin, P., Currie, T. E., Turner, E. A. L. & Gavrilets, S. (2013) War, space, and the evolution of Old World complex societies. Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences 110:16384–89.Google Scholar
Tuzin, D. (1976) The Ilahita Arapesh. University of California.Google Scholar
Tuzin, D. (2001) Social complexity in the making: A case study among the Arapesh of New Guinea. Routledge.Google Scholar
Tylor, E. D. (1871) Primitive culture: Researches into the development of mythology, philosophy, religion, art, and custom. Gordon Press.Google Scholar
Underhill, R. (1975) Economic and political antecedents of monotheism: A cross-cultural study. American Journal of Sociology 80:841–61.Google Scholar
Valdesolo, P., Ouyang, J. & DeSteno, D. (2010) The rhythm of joint action: Synchrony promotes cooperative ability. Journal of Experimental Social Psychology 46:693–95.Google Scholar
Waytz, A., Gray, K., Epley, N. & Wegner, D. M. (2010) Causes and consequences of mind perception. Trends in Cognitive Sciences 14:383–88. doi: 10.1016/j.tics.2010.05.006.Google Scholar
Wheeler, S. C., DeMarree, K. G., & Petty, R. E. (2007) Understanding the role of the self in prime to behavior effects: The active-self account. Personality and Social Psychology Review 11:234–61.Google Scholar
Whitehouse, H. (2004) Modes of religiosity: A cognitive theory of religious transmission. AltaMira Press.Google Scholar
Whitehouse, H. & Hodder, I. (2010) Modes of religiosity at Çatalhöyük. In: Religion in the emergence of civilization: Çatalhöyük as a case study, ed. Hodder, I., pp. 122–45. Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Wiessner, P. & Tumu, A. (1998) Historical vines. Smithsonian Institution Press.Google Scholar
Wildman, W. J. & Sosis, R. (2011) Stability of groups with costly beliefs and practices. Journal of Artificial Societies and Social Simulation 14:6.Google Scholar
Willard, A., & Norenzayan, A. (2015) Spiritual but not religious: Cognition, schizotypy, and conversion in understanding alternative beliefs. Unpublished manuscript.Google Scholar
Willard, A. K. & Norenzayan, A. (2013) Cognitive biases explain religious belief, paranormal belief, and belief in life's purpose. Cognition 129:379–91. doi: 10.1016/j.cognition.2013.07.016.Google Scholar
Willard, A. K., Norenzayan, A. & Henrich, J. (2015) The effects of credibility enhancing displays on behavior and belief. Unpublished manuscript.Google Scholar
Wilson, D. S. (2003) Darwin's Cathedral: Evolution, religion, and the nature of society. University of Chicago Press.Google Scholar
Wiltermuth, S. S. & Heath, C. (2009) Synchrony and cooperation. Psychological Science 20:15.Google Scholar
Wright, R. (2009) The evolution of god. Little, Brown.Google Scholar
Xygalatas, D. (2013) Effects of religious setting on cooperative behaviour: A case study from Mauritius. Religion, Brain and Behavior 3:91102.Google Scholar
Xygalatas, D., Mitkidis, P., Fischer, R., Reddish, P., Skewes, J., Geertz, A. W., Roepstorff, A. & Bulbulia, J. (2013) Extreme rituals promote prosociality. Psychological Science 24:1602–605.Google Scholar
Zhong, C. B., Bohns, V. B. & Gino, F. (2010) A good lamp is the best police: Darkness increases dishonesty and self-interested behavior. Psychological Science 21:311–14.Google Scholar
Zuckerman, P. (2007) Atheism: Contemporary numbers and patterns. In: The Cambridge companion to atheism, ed. Martin, M., pp. 4765. Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Zuckerman, P. (2008) Society without God. New York University Press.Google Scholar
Figure 0

Figure 1. Increasing prevalence of Big Gods as a function of social group size in the Standard Cross Cultural Sample (reprinted from Evolution and Human Behavior, Roes, F. L. & Raymond, M., Vol. 24, issue 2, Belief in moralizing gods, pp. 126–35, copyright 2003, with permission from Elsevier.).

Figure 1

Figure 2. A meta-analysis of religious priming studies shows that religious reminders increase prosocial behavior, with an average effect size of Hedges'g=0.27, 95% CI: 0.15 to 0.40 (from Shariff et al. in press, with permission from Sage). Error bars are 95% CI of effect sizes.8

Figure 2

Figure 3. Religious communes outlast secular ones over time (from Sosis, R., Cross-Cultural Research (vol. 34), pp. 70–87, copyright © 2000. Reprinted by permission of SAGE Publications.).