Hostname: page-component-586b7cd67f-t7fkt Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-11-23T21:12:29.577Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Activist–Leader Relations and the Structure of Political Parties: ‘Exchange’ Models and Vote-Seeking Behaviour in Parties

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  27 January 2009

Abstract

This article examines how party organization affects, and is itself affected by, the objectives pursued by parties in liberal democracies; it focuses on vote-seeking behaviour by parties. It argues that it is a mistake to model activist–leader relations in the past as having been primarily the product of particular kinds of ‘exchanges’ between leaders and activists in a party. Such models limit our understanding of intra-party relations in four important respects – by focusing exclusively on the idea of ‘exchange’ and not examining the role of ‘gifts’; by not considering the role of solidary incentives; by omitting an analysis of loyalty; and by not taking account of the role of habit. However, the article also argues that ‘exchange’ is becoming now a far more significant element in intra-party relations and that this development will constrain party leaders and influence the goals pursued by parties. Greater reliance on exchange between leaders and activists may lead to parties becoming generally more policy-seeking in their behaviour and also to their becoming less manageable than in the past.

Type
Articles
Copyright
Copyright © Cambridge University Press 1992

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

References

1 For example, Kitschelt, Herbert, ‘New Social Movements and the Decline of Party Organization’, in Dalton, Russell J. and Kuechler, Manfred, eds, Challenging the Political Order (Cambridge: Polity Press, 1990), p. 206.Google Scholar

2 Downs, Anthony, An Economic Theory of Democracy (New York: Harper & Row, 1957).Google Scholar

3 Wright, William E., ‘Comparative Party Models: Rational-Efficient and Party Democracy”, in Wright, , ed., A Comparative Study of Party Organization (Columbus, Ohio: Charles E. Merrill, 1971)Google Scholar; Schlesinger, Joseph A., ‘The Primary Goals of Political Parties: A Clarification of Positive Theory’, American Political Science Review, 69 (1975), 840–9CrossRefGoogle Scholar; Strøm, Kaare, ‘A Behavioral Theory of Competitive Political Parties’, American Journal of Political Science, 34 (1990), 565–98.CrossRefGoogle Scholar

4 An early account of these developments was provided by Epstein, Leon D., Political Parties in Western Democracies (London: Pall Mall, 1967)Google Scholar. A decade or so later, when writing a new introduction to this classic study, Epstein expressed the view that the impact of these changes on European parties may have been rather less than he had suggested originally.

5 A capital-intensive party is one which relies on linkage to potential voters by methods which do not involve personal contact or the extensive use of human labour. Computer-generated direct mail, television advertisements and the utilization of opinion polls are all examples of this kind of linkage.

6 Ware, Alan, The Breakdown of Democratic Party Organization, 1940–1980 (Oxford: Clarendon Press, 1985), pp. 186–7.Google Scholar

7 Franks, C. E. S., The Parliament of Canada (Toronto: University of Toronto Press, 1987), pp. 73–4.CrossRefGoogle Scholar

8 Noelle-Neumann, Elizabeth, The Spiral of Silence (Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 1984), p. 5.Google Scholar

9 Paterson, William E., ‘West Germany: Between Party Apparatus and Basis Democracy’ in Ware, Alan, ed., Political Parties (Oxford: Basil Blackwell, 1987), p. 163.Google Scholar

10 Wright, Vincent, The Government and Politics of France, 3rd edn (London: Unwin Hyman, 1989), p. 200.Google Scholar

11 Strøm, , ‘A Behavioral Theory’, p. 575Google Scholar; Clark, Peter B. and Wilson, James Q., ‘Incentive Systems: A Theory of Organization’, Administrative Science Quarterly, 6 (1961), 129–66.CrossRefGoogle Scholar

12 But see Arrow, K. J., ‘Gifts and Exchanges’, Philosophy and Public Affairs, 1 (1972), 343–62Google Scholar; Hammond, P. J., ‘Charity: Altruism or Egoism’ (Colchester, University of Essex, Department of Economics mimeo, 1972)Google Scholar; Phelps, Edmund S., ed., Altruism, Morality and Economic Theory (New York: Russell Sage Foundation, 1975)Google Scholar; Collard, D., Altruism and Economy: A Study in Non-Selfish Economics (Oxford: Martin Robertson, 1978)Google Scholar; Kurz, M., ‘Altruism as an Outcome of Social Interaction’, American Economic Review, 68 (1978), 216–22Google Scholar; Kolm, Serge-Christophe, La Bonne Economie (Paris: Presses Universitaires de France, 1984).Google Scholar

13 Barry, Brian, Sociologists, Economists and Democracy (London: Collier-Macmillan, 1970), pp. 1516.Google Scholar

14 In the case of blood donations, donors and receivers do not know who the other is, although normally the receiver will know he or she has received blood, and in Britain at least, would probably be aware that blood would have been donated (and not sold) by someone. The classic study of the interaction of gifts and exchanges in relation to blood is Titmuss, Richard, The Gift Relationship (London: Allen and Unwin, 1970).Google Scholar

15 Nor is this the only ‘intermediate’ form as Heath's analysis of presents and favours indicates; Heath, Anthony, Rational Choice and Social Exchange (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1976), pp. 145–51.Google Scholar

16 Most usually what is done with a gift does matter. Thus Heath argues that Titmuss's account of blood donation is wrong in conceiving it as a ‘free gift’: ‘While the recipient may not have to make a return, he is nevertheless not free to do with the donation whatever he pleases. It does not belong to him in quite the same way that goods purchased in a cash transaction are the buyer's’ (Heath, , Rational Choice and Social Exchange, p. 153).Google Scholar

17 Strøm, , ‘A Behavioral Theory of Competitive Political Parties’, p. 577.Google Scholar

18 Bulpitt, Jim, ‘English Local Politics: The Collapse of the Ancien Regime?’ (paper presented to the Annual Conference of the Political Studies Association, 1976).Google Scholar

19 King, Desmond S., The New Right (London: Macmillan, 1987), chap. 2.Google Scholar

20 Kitschelt, , ‘New Social Movements and the Decline of Party Organization’, p. 190.Google Scholar

21 Clark, and Wilson, , ‘Incentive Systems: A Theory of Organization’.Google Scholar

22 For example, see Wilson's, James Q. account of club politics, The Amateur Democrat (Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 1962)Google Scholar. In fact, solidaristic incentives seem to have been important in the growth of the club movement; see Ware, , The Breakdown of Democratic Party Organization, p. 77.Google Scholar

23 Miller, Susanne and Potthoff, Heinrich, A History of German Social Democracy (Leamington Spa: Berg, 1986), p. 47.Google Scholar

24 Sometimes alcoholic drinks were less important in recruiting members than more ‘wholesome’ activities. As Pugh notes of the Primrose Leagues, their reputation is more accurately based on tea-and-buns than on beer-and-skittles; Pugh, Martin, The Tories and the People (Oxford: Basil Blackwell, 1985), p. 32.Google Scholar

25 Strøm, , ‘A Behavioral Theory of Competitive Political Parties’, p. 576.Google Scholar

26 Wilson, , The Amateur Democrat.Google Scholar

27 Haus, Charles, The New Left in France: The Unified Socialist Party (Westport, Conn.: Greenwood Press, 1978), p. 93.Google Scholar

28 ‘A national crisis like the Boer War might produce good audiences but the clubs, once revered by Gladstone and Bradlaugh, were by then generally non-political or apathetic. Most clubs gave a hearing impartially to pro-war and pro-Boer speakers, but refused to take sides’, Perkin, Harold, The Rise of Professional Society (London: Routledge, 1989), p. 110.CrossRefGoogle Scholar

29 Barry, Brian, ‘Exit, Voice and Loyalty’, British Journal of Political Science, 4 (1974), 79107CrossRefGoogle Scholar; Hirschman, Albert O., Exit, Voice, and Loyalty (Cambridge, Mass.: Harvard University Press, 1970).Google Scholar

30 Pugh, , The Tories and the People, 1880–1935, p. 41.Google Scholar

31 There were some exceptions – the Italian Communist party, for example, continued to provide well-attended summer camps and festivals long after most other parties in Western Europe had been unable to sustain popular interest in socializing with fellow party members.

32 Ware, , The Breakdown of Democratic Party Organization, p. 77.Google Scholar

33 Campbell, Angus et al. , The American Voter (New York: John Wiley, 1960)Google Scholar and Elections and the Political Order (New York: John Wiley, 1966).Google Scholar

34 On the extensive role of patronage in Canadian party politics (at the federal level) before this, see Stewart, Gordon T., The Origins of Canadian Politics (Vancouver: University of British Columbia Press, 1986).Google Scholar

35 However, arguably, the 1988 general election, in which the ‘free trade’ issue was prominent, constituted an important exception to the lack of significant policy differences between the Liberals and the Progressive Conservatives.

36 Galipeau, Claude, ‘Political Parties, Interest Groups, and New Social Movements: Toward New Representation?’, in Gagnon, Alan G. and Tanguay, A. Brian, eds, Canadian Parties in Transition (Scarborough, Ont.: Nelson, 1989), p. 416.Google Scholar

37 Until recently the major parties were not actively involved in Canadian municipal elections – the main exceptions being the early efforts of the Co-operative Commonwealth Federation to elect councillors in some of the western cities; Tindal, C. R. and Tindal, S. Nobes, Local Government in Canada, 2nd edn (Toronto: McGraw-Hill Ryerson, 1984), p. 153.Google Scholar

38 Perlin, George, The Tory Syndrome (Kingston: McGill-Queen's University Press), p. 134.Google Scholar

39 Data from Kornberg, Allan, Smith, Joel and Clarke, Harold D., Citizen Politicians – Canada (Durham, NC: Carolina Academic Press, 1979)Google Scholar, cited in Mishler, William and Clarke, Harold D., ‘Political Participation in Canada’, in Whittington, Michael S. and Williams, Glen, eds, Canadian Politics in the 1990s (Scarborough, Ont.: Nelson, 1990), p. 163Google Scholar; and Clarke, Harold D., LeDuc, Lawrence, Jenson, Jane and Pammett, Jon H., Political Choice in Canada (Toronto: McGraw-Hill Ryerson, 1979), p. 86.Google Scholar

40 McMenemy, John, ‘Getting to Know the Parties by the Company We Keep: Local Sources of Party Imagery’, in Gagnon, and Tanguay, , Canadian Parties in Transition, pp. 312–14.Google Scholar

41 Ware, , The Breakdown of Democratic Party Organization, pp. 140–1.Google Scholar

42 Moreover, in organizations which do not have a permanent existence, there is the further problem that there is no mechanism for segregating into different activities those who do not adjust well to each other. This point emerged in an in-depth study of a constituency campaign in Britain; Holt, Robert T. and Turner, John E., Political Parties in Action (New York: Free Press, 1968), p. 131.Google Scholar

43 Panebianco, Angelo, Political Parties: Organization and Power (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1988), p. 139.Google Scholar

44 Strøm, , ‘A Behavioral Theory’, pp. 592–3.Google Scholar

45 The Reagan Administration adopted a similar strategy. It placed political appointees in some positions in the administration which had previously been occupied by career civil servants.