Hostname: page-component-745bb68f8f-5r2nc Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2025-01-21T15:05:09.458Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Antitrust and corporate taxation

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  17 January 2025

Jonghoon Lee
Affiliation:
Department of Government, Law & Policy, Arkansas State University, Jonesboro, AR, USA
Amy Pond*
Affiliation:
Department of Political Science, Washington University in St. Louis, St. Louis, MO, USA
*
Corresponding author: Amy Pond; Email: pamy@wustl.edu
Rights & Permissions [Opens in a new window]

Abstract

Although citizens value competitive markets and support small businesses, we observe substantial variation in market concentration. Why do politicians abstain from taking action to reduce concentration? We propose an often overlooked political benefit to concentrated markets: When concentration increases, competition is less pronounced and firms earn larger profits. These profits can be taxed for government revenue or used to reward business-friendly politicians. We expect politicians to impose more lenient competition policies toward firms that provide larger sources of revenue. Moreover, this relationship should be especially strong under authoritarian political institutions, where politicians only weakly value the free market and consumer outcomes and where institutional commitments to unbiased policies are weak. We derive our theoretical claims from a formal model. We draw on both cross-country evidence and evidence from Turkey at the firm and industry level to evaluate our claims. We find that as political institutions become less representative, firms that make higher tax payments tend to control more assets, operate in more concentrated industries, and engage in higher value M&As. Our study points to the weak provision of competition policies as a source of rent-seeking.

Type
Research Article
Creative Commons
Creative Common License - CCCreative Common License - BY
This is an Open Access article, distributed under the terms of the Creative Commons Attribution licence (https://creativecommons.org/licenses/by/4.0/), which permits unrestricted re-use, distribution and reproduction, provided the original article is properly cited.
Copyright
© The Author(s), 2025. Published by Cambridge University Press on behalf of Vinod K. Aggarwal

Although citizens overwhelmingly value competitive markets and support small businesses (Menon and Osgood, Reference Menon and Osgood2024), market power remains concentrated in many countries. Concentrated markets pose economic and political challenges. Concentration may undermine competition and elevate prices (Philippon, Reference Philippon2019). Larger firms also have more political influence (Bombardini, Reference Bombardini2008; Weymouth, Reference Weymouth2012; Betz, Reference Betz2017; Kim, Reference Kim2017). And, because economic and political power often reinforce each other, economic concentration may create a cycle where concentration begets biased policy, which further increases concentration (Zingales, Reference Zingales2017; Callander, Foarta and Sugaya, Reference Callander, Foarta and Sugaya2022, Reference Callander, Foarta and Sugaya2024).

Governments can take many actions to curb concentration. Property rights encourage firms to enter markets, anticipating that their ownership rights will be protected. Antitrust or competition policies are used to limit market concentration and to ensure that new competitors can enter the marketplace. Antitrust typically prohibits anti-competitive behaviors, like monopolization and price setting. Antitrust authorities may also review and block mergers and acquisitions that would surpass certain levels of market concentration, and they may break up large companies. Through these processes, antitrust is designed to maintain competitive markets. In this paper, we question when governments take action to curb concentration and increase competition.

A growing literature explores when politicians strengthen antitrust. Democratic governments should provide more effective antitrust (Weymouth, Reference Weymouth2016; Mitton, Reference Mitton2008), as consumers are thought to have more influence in democracies (Mansfield, Milner and Rosendorff Reference Mansfield, Milner and Peter Rosendorff2000; Nielson, Reference Nielson2003; Kono, Reference Kono2006); democratic politicians value efficient and productive markets as public goods (Bueno de Mesquita et al., Reference Bueno de Mesquita, Morrow, Siverson and Smith2002; Lake and Baum, Reference Lake and Baum2001); and authoritarian governments seek direct control over the marketplace (Koop and Kessler, Reference Koop and Kessler2021). Political competition in democracy may also lead to cycles in antitrust enforcement (Dove, Reference Dove2014; Hofstadter, Reference Hofstadter1964), and variation in economic models could affect the development of antitrust, even among democratic countries (Foster, Reference Foster2021). The enforcement record on antitrust policies is mixed, and the effects of antitrust for small firms are contested. Antitrust helps small firms where it prohibits entry barriers; it hurts small firms if it prevents coordination among them (Thelen, Reference Thelen2025; Foster and Thelen, Reference Foster and Thelen2024; Arslan, Reference Arslan2022; Whitman, Reference Whitman2007). In weakly institutionalized settings, antitrust policy can suffer from capacity constraints (Avdasheva and Shastitko, Reference Avdasheva and Shastitko2011) and over-zealous regulators (Zhang, Reference Zhang2022).

In this paper, we abstract away from much of the complexity surrounding the implementation of antitrust. We simply accept that politicians have policy tools at their disposal when seeking to foster competitive markets, and we question when they are likely to use these tools. Our objective is to introduce an important consideration into research on the politics of market concentration: corporate taxation. Around the world, corporate tax revenues remain an important share of total government revenue. Corporate taxes make up a larger share of government revenue than the personal income tax on-average in Latin America, the Asia-Pacific region and in Africa.Footnote 1 Corporate revenues have also been eroded by international tax competition (Arel-Bundock, Reference Arel-Bundock2017) and trade liberalization (Bastiaens and Rudra, Reference Bastiaens and Rudra2016; Betz and Pond, Reference Betz and Pond2023a), and recent efforts like the Base Erosion and Profit Shifting agreement illustrate the shared emphasis on reclaiming these revenues.

We argue that taxation and competition policies are closely related to each other: While increasing competition in markets carries price benefits for consumers, it also reduces corporate profits. Reduced profits, in turn, leave a smaller pool of resources for governments to tap into—through formal transfers like taxation and campaign donations and informal transfers like bribes and kickbacks. Alternatively, weakening competition elevates firm profits. Politicians can then tap into these profits, leaving both firms and politicians with more resources. We thus expect that those firms, who provide important sources for government transfers, are less likely to be targeted by regulators who seek to increase market competition.

Our contention is not that this exchange of competition for transfers is always explicit. It might come about implicitly through repeated interactions between governments and firms: Firms seek reduced competition in order to earn larger profits. Those that provide politicians with transfers are better able to secure their preferred policies. Over time this leads to a stable empirical pattern where we see weaker competition policies for large firms who provide the government with substantial transfers. In short, governments select both corporate taxation and competition regulation. Divergence between these two—weakened competition in exchange for transfers—is a particularly attractive strategy combination.

We further expect that politicians are more willing to reduce competition for transfers under less representative political institutions. Limits to representation frequently privilege concentrated interests, like large firms, over the public or consumer interests. In democratic countries, there are institutional safeguards that prevent governments from intervening in the economy on behalf of specific firms; these safeguards are weaker or reversible in autocracies (North and Weingast, Reference North and Weingast1989; Schultz and Weingast, Reference Schultz and Weingast2003; Bodea and Higashijima, Reference Bodea and Higashijima2017). Safeguards in democracy might also ensure that antitrust is faithfully executed, for example through the political independence of regulators (Koop and Hanretty, Reference Koop and Hanretty2018; Koop and Jordana, Reference Koop and Jordana2022), and that antitrust is not captured by special interests. Autocrats alternatively may rely on intervention in the economy to reward political supporters (Menaldo, Reference Menaldo2016). Authoritarian institutions should thus make the exchange of transfers for competition more attractive, as autocrats are less constrained by liberalized markets, impartial institutions, and consumer benefits.

Historical anecdotes help elaborate the theory: In the 19th century, the Mexican government under President Porfirio Díaz broke up the national market and granted monopoly bank charters in local markets. These charters limited competition and generated high rates of return. In exchange the bankers gave Díaz access to substantial resources (Calomiris and Haber, Reference Calomiris and Haber2014, Chapt 10). Similarly, in England the East India Company was granted lucrative, monopoly trading rights in India and China. The Charter, which granted these rights, was not permanent and instead was continuously renewed in exchange for payments to the government (Zingales, Reference Zingales2017, 115–16). In both cases, the authoritarian government cared little about consumer welfare but benefited directly from the monopoly profits earned by their chosen firms.

It is difficult to know when this exchange (competition for transfers) takes place, as politicians have an incentive to obfuscate costly policies (Kono, Reference Kono2006). Nevertheless, it should still show up in market statistics. Drawing on the reverse Polity score as a measure of authoritarianism, as well as measures of taxation, firm size, industry concentration, and competition, we present evidence that, in authoritarian contexts, firms grow larger and industries more concentrated when they are significant sources of tax revenue.

We then leverage data from Turkey, which provides an appropriate testing ground for our theory: Turkey has variation in political institutions, which have become more authoritarian in recent years. And, Turkey’s competition authority releases data documenting competition cases at the industry level. Firms in Turkey also report both their tax payments and merger and acquisition activities. We show that the movement towards authoritarianism in Turkey was accompanied by (1) fewer competition policy investigations among industries that provide more tax revenue and by (2) mergers and acquisitions among larger firms, operating in concentrated industries, if they provide more tax revenue. Although the results are simple correlations, that they hold across several different measures and fine-grained data helps corroborate the theory.

The theory carries implications for several literatures. To make the argument and empirical analysis tractable, we have focused specifically on market competition, tax revenue, and antitrust as benefiting consumers. The paper has implications beyond these areas. Theoretically, elevated profits could come from many sources, including any policy that creates a barrier to competitor entry (Perlman, Reference Perlman2019; Gulotty, Reference Gulotty2020), which could include increased tariffs, the rationing of operating licenses, the under-provision of shareholder rights, or targeted financing. We expect that a similar pattern could emerge in any of these policy areas. We also focus narrowly here on tax revenue as transfers to governments. While this strategy facilitates measurement, it also narrows the scope of the argument. Politicians may also be willing to trade-off market competition for campaign contributions or bribes (Perotti and Volpin, Reference Perotti and Volpin2004). These relationships may also link the political fate of politicians and their supporters, which could strengthen their political alliance. The theory therefore has implications for literatures on corruption, campaign donations, and economic regulation.

Second, many of the analyses reported here consider competition as an outcome of antitrust. Research has shown that antitrust can also be used to benefit influential domestic industries (Faith, Leavens and Tollison, Reference Faith, Leavens and Tollison1982) and target foreign firms (Foster, Reference Foster2022; Ro Reference Ro2021). It may be harder for governments to wield antitrust for political purposes when antitrust regulators are operationally independent (Koop and Hanretty, Reference Koop and Hanretty2018; Koop and Jordana, Reference Koop and Jordana2022), and like other regulators this independence is plausibly more credible under democratic institutions (Bodea and Higashijima, Reference Bodea and Higashijima2017). That our study uses a combination of antitrust investigations and market outcomes reassures us that the divergence between antitrust aims and antitrust execution is unlikely to drive our results. Nevertheless, better understanding how antitrust is made and wielded remains an important research objective.

Finally, the paper complements a large and growing literature on the relative influence of special interests, particularly commercial, versus the public interest (Carey and Shugart, Reference Carey and Shugart1995). Most studies find that consumers, by virtue of being a large, diffuse group, with small individual benefits to organization, will be collective action disadvantaged. In the context of trade policy, consumer interests seem to have little effect on policy preferences and outcomes (Guisinger, Reference Guisinger2009; Bearce and Moya, Reference Bearce and Moya2020; Betz and Pond, Reference Betz and Pond2019).Footnote 2 Here we look to the broader policy environment to examine how consumer influence affects antitrust, market concentration, and corporate taxation. Although firms may seek out reduced corporate taxation (Garrett and Lange, Reference Garrett and Lange1999; Basinger and Hallerberg, Reference Basinger and Hallerberg2004; Swank, Reference Swank2006; Franzese and Hays, Reference Franzese and Hays2008), they may be willing to provide higher tax transfers if they are compensated with large profits in concentrated markets.

Political incentives for corporate taxation and competition

In this section, we derive several theoretical insights from a simple model. We model the economy as a Cournot model of quantity competition.Footnote 3 The government in the model decides how to regulate the economy, selecting the rates of taxation and antitrust. We assume that authoritarian leaders value consumer welfare less than democratic leaders, and antitrust enters the model by affecting the number of firms operating in the market. As is always the case in these models, when the number of firms increases, consumer welfare increases, but firm profits decrease. This reduces the corporate revenue available for taxation. Thus, increasing antitrust has diverging effects from a public-minded perspective: it reduces corporate tax revenue but increases consumer surplus. The model makes these assumptions transparent and helps us adjudicate competing effects of taxation and competition policy and their relative value for different governments.

The game is between the government and several firms. The government moves first and selects the tax rate, $t$ , and the level of antitrust. Antitrust affects the number of firms, $n$ , operating in the economy. Although other factors also affect whether a firm enters or exits the market, the model focuses on the government’s policy incentives. Stronger antitrust results in a larger $n$ , while weaker antitrust reduces $n$ .Footnote 4 The $n$ firms then engage in economic activity, which we model as Cournot competition over quantity. The firms simultaneously select the quantity, ${q_i}$ , that each firm $i$ produces to maximize its profits. The firms are assumed to be identical.

Each firm’s maximization problem is:Footnote 5

$$ma{x_{{q_i}}}\left\{ {{\pi _i} = \left( {1 - \mathop \sum \nolimits_{j = 1}^n {q_j} - c} \right){q_i}} \right\}$$

Which pins down the equilibrium quantities, prices, and per-firm profits:

$${q_i} = {{1 - c} \over {n + 1}} \hskip5pc{p_i} = {{1 + nc} \over {n + 1}} \hskip5pc {\pi _i} = {{{{(1 - c)}^2}} \over {{{(n + 1)}^2}}}$$

Profits in the full economy then are:

$${\rm{\Pi }} = \mathop \sum \nolimits_{i = 1}^n {\pi _i} = {{n{{(1 - c)}^2}} \over {{{(n + 1)}^2}}}$$

And the consumer surplus is:

$$CS = {1 \over 2}\left( {1 - p} \right)q = {{{n^2}{{(1 - c)}^2}} \over {2{{(n + 1)}^2}}}$$

The government selects $n$ and $t$ to maximize a combination of consumer surplus and tax revenue.

$${V_g}\left( {t,n} \right) = BCS + t{\rm{\Pi }} - k{t^2}$$

$k$ is a cost of taxation, which might deter future investment. This functional form ensures an interior solution for taxation. $B$ is the weight that the government attaches to consumer surplus, $CS$ . We assume that more democratic countries, and within authoritarian countries those with more widespread political participation, have a larger weight on consumer surplus.

The government’s first order conditions are:

(1) $${{\partial {V_g}\left( {t,n} \right)} \over {\partial t}} = \Pi - 2kt = 0$$
(2) $${{\partial {V_g}\left( {t,n} \right)} \over {\partial n}} = B{{\partial CS} \over {\partial n}} + t{{\partial \Pi } \over {\partial n}} = 0$$

In the taxation equation (1), the first term represents the marginal benefit of a tax increase, $t$ , in that it increases government revenue proportional to firm profits. The second term represents the marginal costs of the tax increase, in that it discourages future investments. In the antitrust equation (2), the first term again represents the marginal benefit of increasing the number of firms, $n$ , because consumer surplus is increasing in $n$ . The second term represents the marginal cost of increasing the number of firms, because profits are decreasing as the number of firms increases.Footnote 6

To see the full equation for antitrust, we can plug equation (1), $t = {\Pi \over {2k}}$ , into equation (2).Footnote 7

(3) $${{\partial {V_g}\left( {t,n} \right)} \over {\partial n}} = B+ {{{{(1 - c)}^2}\left( {1 - n} \right)} \over {{{(n + 1)}^2}}} = 0$$

The second order condition is:Footnote 8

(4) $${{{\partial ^2}{V_g}\left( {t,n} \right)} \over {\partial {n^2}}} = {{ - {{(1 - c)}^2}} \over {{{(n + 1)}^2}}} + {{2{{(1 - c)}^2}\left( {n - 1} \right)} \over {{{(n + 1)}^3}}}$$

To compute the effect of political institutions, $B$ , on antitrust policy, $n$ , we use the implicit function theorem.

Proposition 1. Increasing the government’s weight on consumer welfare has the following effects:

  1. 1. It increases the provision of antitrust policy, increasing $n$ .

  2. 2. It reduces firm profits.

  3. 3. It reduces the optimal tax rate.

Proof. For 1, use the implicit function theorem. The derivative of the government’s antitrust FOC is ${{{\partial ^2}{V_g}\left( {t,n} \right)} \over {\partial n\partial B}} = 1$ . The SOC is negative, so the overall effect is positive. For 2, see the effect of an increase in $n$ on total profits. Profits are ${{n{{(1 - c)}^2}} \over {{{(n + 1)}^2}}}$ . The derivative of profits with respect to $n$ is negative, ${{\left( {1 - n} \right){{(1 - c)}^2}} \over {{{(n + 1)}^3}}}$ , as long as $n \gt1$ . For 3, the optimal tax policy is $t = {\Pi \over {2k}}$ , which decreases when ${\rm{\Pi }}$ decreases.

In sum, we should observe a weakening of antitrust policy accompanied by an increase in corporate taxation as countries become more authoritarian. Put simply, authoritarian governments are more willing than democratic governments to offer weak antitrust, especially as it allows them to raise revenue through taxation.

Limitations. The model is highly stylized and simplified, which induces several limitations. First, there are markets where firms form cartels and are able to elevate prices. Adding an additional firm to the cartel may not have competitive effects. Absent cartels or coordination of market strategies however, the expectation is that adding more firms to a market will make the marketplace more competitive.

Second, we model autocracies and democracies as differing only in their weights on consumer welfare. There are plausibly other differences that could be relevant here. Democracies may also place higher value on liberal market competition, and authoritarian governments may prefer to use intervention in the economy to pick winners and support their regime. Democratic governments may also have effective institutional protections in place that prevent them from implementing biased policies, which would otherwise privilege individual firms with political connections. These alternatives are largely consistent with the logic of the formal model and would motivate similar insights. We retain the Cournot model in the text, as we want to display the microfoundations for competition, prices, and consumer effects.

In the Appendix, we formalize an alternative model that emphasizes the government’s preference for biased policies. We assume that increasing antitrust policy improves economic performance overall but harms politically connected firms, as they would typically benefit from biased policies, which are ruled out by unbiased interpretations of antitrust law (which yields competition for all). In this model, authoritarian leaders value these politically connected firms, relative to overall economic performance, more than democratic leaders do. The model in the Appendix emphasizes the trade-off between revenue from growing markets versus from taxing politically connected firms, which is an alternative mechanism that provides an explicit connection to the seminal literatures on revenue and political institutions (Olson, Reference Olson1965; Levi, Reference Levi1988) and on particularist policy benefits for politically connected firms in autocracy (Menaldo, Reference Menaldo2016; Betz and Pond, Reference Betz and Pond2023b).

Historical examples. The historical record provides many examples of governments offering weak competition policies or even monopoly rights in exchange for revenue, especially in undemocratic settings. In 1600, the British government granted the East India Company monopoly rights over trade between England and modern India and China. When the monopoly was set to expire, the Company secured an extension by providing revenue to the government, as well as lobbying and bribes: “To seal the deal and prevent future competitive challenges, the East India Company extended a 3.2 million pound loan to the British Treasury, which, in exchange, again granted the monopoly of trade” (Zingales, Reference Zingales2017, 117).

Similar deals were struck in the banking sector in Mexico. Under President and General Porfirio Díaz, bankers were offered high returns in exchange for agreeing to operate a bank and to provide loans to the government.Footnote 9 The bankers benefited from the large profits they enjoyed, politicians benefited from having a capital pool they could tap into when needed, and citizens paid the cost. In sum:

“Díaz and Mexico’s financiers crafted a set of institutions designed to coaxe capital into the banking system by systematically limiting competition. The rents generated by this system of segmented monopolies were then split between the bankers…, bank minority shareholders…, the government (which obtained access to low interest loans), and the individuals in control of the government… Everyone outside this coalition—which is to say the vast majority of Mexican population—was left out in the cold, with no political voice, no credit, and limited opportunities for economic mobility.” (Calomiris and Haber, Reference Calomiris and Haber2014, 332)

These examples are consistent with several assumptions and findings in the model. First, the absence of antitrust policy—and indeed the active creation of monopolies—increased profits for those with political connections, while consumers and the aggregate economy suffered. Second, these heightened profits benefited both the politically connected bankers and the politicians, who were able to finance their expenditures. Third, the policy exchange, competition for transfers, took place under authoritarian institutions.

While historically these sorts of agreements are common, they are hard to locate in the contemporary period. This is plausibly because politicians have an incentive to hide unpopular and inefficient policies. Citizens widely recognize the benefits of a competitive market, so politicians must obscure their support for non-competitive policies (Kono, Reference Kono2006). Accordingly, although we do not expect to observe politicians loudly proclaiming their support for un-competitive policies, their support should nevertheless be captured in contemporary market outcomes. In the next section, we examine the extent to which this pattern endures in the present era and the extent to which it is reflected beyond trade and financial sector policies. We assess whether politicians, especially those who come to power under undemocratic political institutions, create barriers to competition and in exchange receive increased revenues.

Cross-national Data

The theory anticipates that governments trade-off transfers for market competition. They are more willing to make this trade in authoritarian countries, as governments are thought to value consumer welfare and competitive markets less. To assess the theoretical predictions, we first draw on firm-level, cross-national, time-series data to capture competition, corporate tax revenue, and the level of representation. We expect to observe competitive markets where governments introduce and enforce pro-competition policies.

Our dependent variable is the extent of competition and antitrust in the country. We draw on two different measures. We first use the Herfindahl–Hirschman index (HHI) of market concentration, calculated for each industry. The index is calculated by summing up the value of the market share for each firm operating in each industry, at the 4-digit NACE level.Footnote 10 We log the HHI to reduce the effect of extreme values. We expect that industries will be allowed to grow more concentrated when firms, operating in the industry, provide substantial tax revenue—particularly in more authoritarian countries. The HHI and all firm-level variables detailed below are calculated using data from the Orbis Historical Database.Footnote 11 Concentration varies at the industry level.

Our second dependent variable is logged firm size, as captured by the firm’s total assets. We expect that firms, which provide substantial revenue, will be allowed to grow larger, especially in more authoritarian countries. This variable varies at the firm-level.

Our independent variables of interest must capture corporate taxation and the extent of autocracy. To measure corporate taxation, we use the logged total taxes paid by businesses. The variable is larger for firms that are more important sources of government revenue. Because we expect the effect of corporate taxation on competition and antitrust to depend on political institutions, we also require a measure of authoritarianism in each country. We draw on the Polity2 data from Marshall, Jaggers and Gurr (Reference Marshall, Jaggers and Gurr2017). Since our theory is about less representative institutions, we use the inverted Polity2 score, the autocracy score. We interact the autocracy score with tax revenue, as we expect to observe a stronger, negative association between tax revenue and competition in more authoritarian countries.

We control for several, potentially confounding factors. First, we include the profit margin and the logged number of employees of the firms, as larger firms plausibly earn higher profits and pay more tax revenue. We also control for state capacity, using the Quality of Government indicator from the International Country Risk Guide (ICRG), as a stronger state has a greater ability to tax firms and to enforce regulations, and democracies frequently have more state capacity. Third, we control for domestic economic conditions: market size (logged GDP), wealth (GDP per capita), the annual growth rate, and unemployment (all economic variables are from the World Bank, World Development Indicators). We expect that a wealthier state has more resources to enforce regulations. We also expect that economic conditions affect tax revenue and antitrust, as governments may approve mergers or refrain from antitrust enforcement to stave off business failure and stimulate economic activity (Hylton and Lin, Reference Hylton and Lin2010).

We also include country fixed effects, which account for time-invariant, country specific effects, and industry fixed effects at the 4-digit level (NACE). Industry fixed effects account for differences in industry, like returns to scale, which could be related to firm size, market concentration, profits, and tax revenue. Moreover, if democracy affects industrial development (Nunn, Reference Nunn2007), industry could be related to political institutions. We also include year fixed effects, which provide for a flexible time trend and control for shared shocks to antitrust, political institutions, and taxation over time. We cluster standard errors by country. Once merged, our data includes over 22 million observations from 127 countries from 1992 to 2017. Our theory anticipates that governments may be more willing to accept weak competition if they are compensated through revenue. This trade-off should be more pronounced in countries with less representative institutions. To evaluate our theoretical expectations, we conduct linear regression and interact corporate taxation with autocracy.

Results

Table 1 reports the estimates of the relationship between taxation and antitrust conditional on regime type. Odd columns include firm-level controls, while even columns add the set of country-level controls. In columns (1) and (2), the dependent variable is log industrial concentration. In (3) and (4), the dependent variable is log firm size (total assets).

Table 1. Corporate taxation and competition policy enforcement

Robust standard errors in parentheses, clustered by country: * $p \lt 0.05$ , ** $p\lt 0.01$ , *** $p \lt 0.001$ . The level of analysis is the firm-year. In columns (1) and (2), the dependent variable is log industrial concentration at the 4-digit level. In (3) and (4), it is log firm size (total assets).

From columns (1) to (4), the taxation measure and its interaction with the autocracy variable are statistically significant and positive. The results suggest that an increase in corporate tax revenue is associated with an increase in industrial concentration and an increase in firm size and the effects increase in countries with more authoritarian political institutions. Drawing on column (2) and (4), we illustrate the marginal effects of corporate tax revenue across the autocracy scores in Figure 1. Consistent with our expectations, the marginal effects on industrial concentration and firm size increase in more authoritarian countries.

Figure 1. Marginal effects of corporate tax revenue from Table 1.

In democratic countries where the autocracy score is smaller than -8.5, an increase in corporate tax revenue is associated with a decrease in industrial concentration. This effect reverses as political institutions become more autocratic, and corporate tax revenue is associated with more concentrated industries. In countries with the autocracy score larger than 0, an increase in corporate tax revenue significantly correlates with an increase in industrial concentration. The results in more authoritarian countries accord with our theoretical expectations, but our theory did not predict the negative association between tax revenue and concentration in democratic countries. This negative association could be explained by policy motives in democracy: In democracy, the political opposition has an incentive to identify unpopular policies (like policy privileges for large firms), and democracies may also be better at preventing biased policies and extracting revenue. The result is theoretically and empirically related to state capacity, as democratic countries may be more capable of extracting revenue and limiting market concentration. Indeed the size of the coefficient on tax revenue decreases by over 40 percent when we add the control for state capacity to the model.

The results for firm size accord more closely with our theoretical expectations. Across countries with democratic and authoritarian political institutions, firms that provide more tax revenue are larger on-average, and the association between revenue and size becomes larger still in more authoritarian countries.

Robustness

Errors clustered by industry. We report results in the Appendix with standard errors clustered by industry. The results remain statistically significant. We leave the errors clustered at the country level in the main analysis, because this is more conservative and the autocracy score is measured at the country level.

Dichotomous autocracy. We report results drawing on a dichotomous autocracy score. The dummy variable takes a value of one if Polity2 is under six, and it takes a value of zero otherwise. The results are less stable but overall similar. In democracy, tax revenue is associated with less concentrated industries, but the relationship reverses itself in the expected way in autocracies. The results for firm size are similar when using the dichotomous and continuous autocracy measures.

Within autocracy. Our argument assumes that autocratic regimes are more willing to trade competition for revenue than democracies. This can be more true for some types of autocracy (multi-party autocracy) than others (military and one-party autocracies). In the Appendix, we report the heterogeneous interaction effects depending on the types of autocracy (Hadenius and Teorell, Reference Hadenius and Teorell2007; Wahman et al., Reference Wahman, Teorell and Hadenius2013).

National measures. Our main results relied on firm-level taxation and market outcomes to measure concentration and firm size. In the Appendix, we report the results of similar empirical models in Table 1 but replace the variables with country-level measures of the extent of antitrust. We report associations with both the Effectiveness of Antimonopoly Policy (EAP) from the World Economic Forum and Competition Law Index (CLI) from Bradford et al. (Reference Bradford, Chilton, Megaw and Sokol2019).Footnote 12 The direction of the associations is consistent with the theory but fails to consistently reach statistical significance.

The association with the CLI is only significant without country fixed effects in the model. This is a de jure measure of legal competition or antitrust law. Like many other legal measures it lacks substantial within-country variation over time, and thus country fixed effects explain much of the variation in the index. The EAP measure alternatively gains significance when country fixed effects are in the model, suggesting that there are many differences between how countries implement antimonopoly policy, which are not captured by the polity score. However, within countries, firm executives plausibly take notice when the government’s policy stance changes (even if the laws have changed little).

Within-country analysis from Turkey

We now turn to a within-country analysis that allows us to explore variation in antitrust and competition, as it relates to political institutions. Looking at competition within a single country holds many potentially confounding factors constant. This is important, as enforcement can vary dramatically across countries, even among those with similar legal institutions (Arslan, Reference Arslan2021).

We select Turkey as our country of interest for various reasons. First, Turkey has substantial variation in its political institutions in recent years. Its authoritarianism score (the reversed Polity2 score) decreased from negative seven to negative nine in 2011, indicating movement towards greater democratization. Then, Turkey experienced a dramatic increase in authoritarianism moving from negative nine to negative three in 2014 and then moving further from negative three to positive four in 2016, as Turkey’s President Recep Tayyip Erdogan suppressed dissent. In terms of the binary concept, these authoritarianism scores correspond to movement from democracy to autocracy in 2014. Figure 2 displays Turkey’s authoritarianism score over time.

Figure 2. Authoritarianism score in Turkey.

Second, recent reforms in Turkey demonstrate the political importance of antitrust enforcement (Arslan, Reference Arslan2021, 265–66). Although the competition authority had previously been relatively independent of political oversight, President Erdogan has reformed the structure of the agency to increase his influence on policy. In 2005, he reduced the number of commissioners. In 2011, he increased the share of commissioners that he appoints, and in 2018, he took the power to appoint all commissioners. He also increased the oversight of the authority by the central ministries (2011), and reduced the independence of the authority by leveling salaries (2012) and allowing less autonomy in hiring (2013). Looking for evidence of political influence in Turkey’s antitrust enforcement therefore seems plausible. Increasing political influence with the competition authority may allow politicians to interfere in competition policy on behalf of politically connected firms, and interference may be facilitated by authoritarian institutions, where there are fewer institutional limits on government authority.

Third, Turkey makes data on the enforcement of antitrust publicly available at the sector level. Turkey reports the number of concluded antitrust investigations in each sector of the economy. Finally, Turkey also has a relatively large economy with detailed firm-level information—including tax data and data on mergers and acquisitions (M&As)—available from Bureau van Dijk’s Orbis Database.Footnote 13 Looking at M&As is appropriate in Turkey, because the competition authority is explicitly tasked with investigating and approving mergers (Bradford et al., Reference Bradford, Chilton, Megaw and Sokol2019). The law states that firms must notify the competition authority of planned mergers prior to the sale. The law also directs the agency to prohibit mergers that would create a dominant position (which is relatively broad and does not require that the prohibition be based on abusive acts by the firm) or that would restrict competition. Based on these legal provisions, we expect that—if the competition authority sought to enforce antitrust laws—stricter enforcement of antitrust law would result in fewer M&As and in M&As that produce less concentration. Turkey thus allows us to assess how antitrust and taxation respond to changes in political institutions, holding many other factors constant.

We collect detailed data from Orbis reporting the completed number of M&A deals, the characteristics of the M&A, and the participating firm characteristics for each firm from 2010 to 2018. We merge the M&A data with the Turkish firm-level database using company name and year as an identifier.Footnote 14 We construct two distinct datasets: one at the firm-level and another at the M&A deal-level. The firm-level dataset includes Turkish firms, while the deal-level dataset compiles information on M&A transactions. For the firm-level data, the unit of observation is a firm in a given year, and it is a deal in a given year for the deal-level data. To measure the tax revenue, profits, and employees at stake in the M&A deals for each firm, we take an average of the values reported by the acquirer and target firms. Averaging the firm data helps improve missingness (for example, we have data on the operating revenue of both acquirer and target firms for only 167 firms—see column (6) in Table 3).

We draw on several measures of antitrust and the competitiveness of the market. First, we conduct a firm-level analysis in Turkey. We code a count variable that captures the number of M&A deals that each firm participated in during each year. Second, we look at the character of M&A deals in the deal-level analysis. For each deal, we code a set of variables capturing characteristics of the M&A transaction. Our first dependent variable is the deal size. We then code dummy variables capturing whether the acquiring and target firms are located in the same industry and whether the acquiring firm gains at least 50 percent ownership. We also code the average level of industrial concentration of the acquiring and target firms’ industries, and the size difference, which we square, between the acquiring and target firm. We expect that as Turkey became more authoritarian, we should observe weaker antitrust and thus a stronger association between tax revenue and the number of M&As. We should also observe larger M&As, M&As where the acquiring firm gains majority ownership, and M&As in more concentrated industries. We might also observe more M&As with larger size differentials, as regulators do not prevent [hostile] takeovers.

Figure 3 presents the average number of completed M&As (as a share of the total number of firms) and the average number of investigations (as a share of all divisions).Footnote 15 Figure 4 presents the share of competition cases by each NACE Section.Footnote 16 Our data is at the division level, which is more fine-grained than the section but would be difficult to include in a single figure.

Figure 3. Antitrust enforcement and firm activity in Turkey.

Figure 4. Share of competition cases by NACE Section.

Figures 3 and 4 demonstrate that M&A activity fluctuates considerably but has probably declined on-average, over time in Turkey. The decline in M&As as Turkey became more authoritarian is on its face inconsistent with a weakening of antitrust. However, the decline could plausibly be explained by the increased difficulty of access to financing. Table 2 reports indicators capturing the availability of finance in Turkey over the period between 2008 and 2019. The table shows that fewer firms are taking out bank loans and using banks to finance investments, and that the value of collateral needed to access loans increased since 2008. In addition, our theory makes nuanced predictions about M&As. The theory anticipates more M&As between firms that provide substantial revenue, as well as differences in the character of M&As. We expect regulators to be more permissive toward firms with substantial revenue benefits, especially allowing M&As that increase market concentration or where the firms are from the same industry. Evaluating these more nuanced predictions allows us to assess whether the character of competition enforcement has changed as Erdogan strengthened his control over politics, over regulators and over the economy.

Table 2. Access to financing in Turkey

Data are from the Global Financial Development Database.

Table 3. Corporate tax revenue and M&As

Standard errors in parentheses: * $p \lt 0.05$ , ** $p\lt 0.01$ , *** $p \lt 0.001$ . In column (1), the data is run at the firm-level and the dependent variable is the number of M&As. In all other columns, the data is at the M&A deal-level, and the dependent variables by column are: (2) the deal size, (3) a dummy indicating that the acquirer and target are in the same industry, (4) a dummy indicating that the deal was an acquisition leading to a new majority owner, (5) the average industrial concentration of the acquirer and target, and (6) the operating revenue of the acquirer minus the target, squared.

In a second analysis, we measure the extent of antitrust using the number of investigations into antitrust infringements reported by the Turkish Competition Authority. The Authority provides the sectoral information about investigations from 2010 to 2017.Footnote 17 We hand-code the sectoral information from the Authority to match the widely used 2-digit NACE division code, available from Orbis. We expect industries that are more important sources of tax revenue to have fewer investigations, especially as Turkey’s political institutions became more authoritarian. Importantly, we assume here that the investigations represent genuine competition investigations, and we expect political influence to result in fewer investigations of those firms that are important tax revenue sources. If Erdogan is able to wield policy to target his political opposition, we might actually observe more investigations as Turkey became more authoritarian. We thus interpret these regressions as largely suggestive. That said, we do observe a positive association between concentration and competition cases (see column 2 of Table 4), suggesting that on-average more concentrated industries are more likely to be investigated.

Table 4. Corporate tax revenue and competition cases

Standard errors in parentheses: * $p\lt 0.05$ , ** $p\lt 0.01$ , *** $p\lt 0.001$ . The dependent variable is the number of competition investigations in each industry-year. Tax, profit, and employee variables are industry averages.

Our independent variables of interest again measure the level of tax revenue and the extent of representation. We use taxation, logged (all data from Orbis). In the industry-level analysis of competition authority investigations, we use the average tax revenue from each industry. As before, we use the authoritarianism score (the inverted Polity2 score) to measure the extent of representation.

To test our theoretical expectations, we again interact the measures of corporate taxation with the authoritarianism score variable. We anticipate that Turkey supervised more competitive markets in years when its political institutions were more democratic. As Turkey’s institutions became more authoritarian, we expect to observe that antitrust weakens and competition is less pronounced for firms and industries that provide larger tax payments, indicated by more and larger M&A deal completions in more concentrated industries and fewer antitrust investigations.

We control for potential confounders, including the average profits of the firms that participated in M&AsFootnote 18 and the average number of employees, logged. We also include year and industry fixed effects to account for trends over time and stable industry effects (e.g., returns to scale).

Two examples provide an illustration of the sorts of activities captured in the data. In the case of the TAV Havalimanlari (airport) Holding Company, we observe high levels of tax revenue and elevated numbers of acquisitions, both relative to the industry average for holding companies.Footnote 19 Figure 5 plots the tax revenue and acquisitions of TAV over time. TAV is a Turkish aviation company. The aviation, transportation, and construction industries are thought to be closely connected to Erdogan and have been “mired in corruption” in recent years.Footnote 20 TAV acquired several transport and airport development companies between 2012 and 2019. Importantly, aviation is a sector with high fixed costs, which could pose entry barriers for competitor firms. Traditionally, M&As in industries with high fixed costs are closely scrutinized by regulators. TAV does not seem to have been subject to this scrutiny.

Figure 5. TAV Havalimanlari tax and acquisition activities.

Another firm in our sample that engaged in a large number of M&As is Sise ve Cam Fabrikalari (or simply Sisecam). Sisecam is a glass manufacturer and an important source of tax revenue. Sisecam also increasingly pursued M&A deals over the course of Erdogan’s rise. Sisecam is owned by Isbank,Footnote 21 one of the largest banks operating in Turkey. Isbank in turn is owned about a third by the main opposition party.Footnote 22 Erdogan has tried to takeover ownership, but has not yet been successful.Footnote 23 The size and importance of Isbank and Sisecam plausibly make them attractive targets. At the same time, Erdogan would not want to jeopardize their functioning—and the tax revenue they provide—by doing anything too disruptive. Tax revenue may thus provide some cover to firms, even those who are not owned by Erdogan supporters.

These examples are merely illustrative of how incentives could play out with respect to a specific firm. We now turn to the data to examine whether these firm’s experiences show up in a broader cross-section of firms and industries.

Results

Table 3 reports the estimates of the relationship between corporate taxation and antitrust conditional on regime type in Turkey. Column (1) reports the results of the firm-level analysis, and columns (2) to (6) report the deal-level analysis results. The dependent variable in column (1) is the number of M&As that each firm participated in; in column (2), it is the deal size; in column (3), it is the dummy capturing whether the acquirer and target are in the same industry; in column (4), the dependent variable is the dummy for the transfer of majority ownership; in column (5), it is the average industrial concentration of the acquiring and target firms, and in column (6), the dependent variable is the size difference between the acquirer and the target, squared. Note that the constitutive effect of the autocracy score is absorbed by the year fixed effects, as there is no variation in the autocracy score in each year. We can nevertheless estimate the interactive effect of autocracy and tax revenue.

Although the effects of tax revenue are insignificant on the M&As within the same industry and acquisitions leading to new majority ownership (columns 3 and 4), the coefficients are statistically significant for the number of M&As that the firm engages in (at the 10 percent level), the value of the M&A transaction, the average industrial concentration, and the average size difference (at the five percent level). Furthermore, the estimates of the interaction term are statistically significant in columns 2, 4, and 5. For the remaining results, despite their insignificance, the directions of the coefficients align with our theoretical expectations.

Drawing on these results, we plot the marginal effects of tax revenue in Figure 6. The associations between corporate taxation and different M&A activities become larger as the regime becomes more authoritarian. Especially, in more authoritarian years, the marginal effects of tax revenue become significantly positive for the deal value (column 2), the average industrial concentration (column 5), and the average size difference between acquiring and target firms (column 6). The results suggest that, as Erdogan consolidated his power, firms that provided more tax revenue engaged in higher value transactions, in M&As in concentrated industries, and in deals with counterparts with larger size differences. Additionally, the marginal effects of tax revenue on the acquisition leading to new majority ownership are statistically significant and negative under democratic institutions (column 5): Thus, before Erdogan’s presidency, firms with higher tax payments were less likely to make acquisitions to gain new majority ownership. Taken together the results help corroborate the idea that antitrust authorities scrutinized M&As from firms that are important sources of tax revenue less, as Turkey became more authoritarian. The results are consistent with politicians foregoing the benefits of market competition in exchange for tax revenue in countries with less representative political institutions.

Figure 6. Marginal effects of corporate tax revenue from Table 3.

Table 4 presents the results for antitrust investigations. The level of analysis is the industry-year level. While the coefficient for tax revenue is negatively correlated with investigations, this association does not reach statistical significance. However, the interaction effect is statistically significant and in the expected direction, and its significance persists even after controlling for industrial concentration. This pattern is consistent with tax revenue preventing Turkey’s authorities from investigating specific firms. Additionally, the positive association between concentration and investigations suggests that at least on-average the investigations are being pursued for competitive purposes. To further explore this relationship, we graph the marginal effects of corporate tax revenue on competition cases in Figure 7. The marginal effect of tax revenue becomes statistically significant when the authoritarianism score exceeds 1. This implies that as Turkey’s political institutions grew more authoritarian, authorities were less inclined to investigate industries that generated higher tax revenues. Taken together, the results suggest that Turkey’s authority is neither entirely politicized nor entirely motivated by programmatic objectives: Turkey pursues cases on-average in more concentrated industries. At the same time, it is less likely to investigate firms that provide important sources of tax revenue, and this pattern has become more pronounced as Turkey became more authoritarian.

Figure 7. Marginal effects of corporate tax revenue on cases from Table 4, Column 2.

Conclusion

We argue here that governments are willing to accept lower levels of market competition for firms that provide more important revenue sources. We further argue that this pattern is more pronounced in countries with less representative political institutions, as they plausibly have a greater ability to ignore consumer interests and to intervene in the market in ways that reward their political supporters.

We report three sets of evidence that are consistent with the theory. First, drawing on firm-level datasets across countries and over time, we show that increases in tax revenue are associated with firms operating in more concentrated industries and with larger firms—in non-democratic contexts. Second, drawing on data from Turkey, we show that tax revenue is associated with more M&As, with larger M&As, and with M&As that increase concentration, when Turkey became more authoritarian. Third, we report that Turkish regulators became less likely to investigate industries that are important sources of tax revenue, as it became more authoritarian. Although merely correlational, these findings are consistent with weaker antitrust and less competition for firms that provide more tax revenue in authoritarian countries.

The results suggest several avenues for future research. First, we stress the need for increased research into the political incentives for antitrust and the broader context in which antitrust policy is made. For example, antitrust was created not only to ensure free and fair markets but also to ensure the persistence of democratic institutions (Wu, Reference Wu2018). Because large firms operating in concentrated industries have more political influence (Olson, Reference Olson1965; Hart, Reference Hart2003; Bombardini, Reference Bombardini2008; Osgood, Reference Osgood2018), the risk that firm pressures will dominate politics increases as firms grow. Understanding when politicians will respond to market concentration with increased antitrust emerges as an important question for predicting the durability of political institutions. While some scholars are not optimistic that regulators will be able to wrest political control away from concentrated special interests (Zingales, Reference Zingales2017; Callander, Foarta and Sugaya, Reference Callander, Foarta and Sugaya2022, Reference Callander, Foarta and Sugaya2024), others expect strengthened antitrust enforcement when it is most needed (Hofstadter, Reference Hofstadter1964).

Second, revenue considerations are relevant in many policy areas, including antitrust. To the extent that antitrust is studied in political science, we often consider antitrust from the standpoint of competitive markets versus targeted benefits for politically connected firms (Weymouth, Reference Weymouth2016). Antitrust also has important revenue effects. Although declining in importance as a share of total revenue, corporate revenue remains an important revenue source, particularly as governments seek to restore lost revenues from international tax competition (Arel-Bundock, Reference Arel-Bundock2017) and trade liberalization (Queralt, Reference Queralt2015; Bastiaens and Rudra, Reference Bastiaens and Rudra2016; Betz and Pond, Reference Betz and Pond2023 a). Because market competition may reduce firm profits, it can also undermine revenue collection from corporate taxation. We thus join a broader movement to incorporate revenue considerations into models of policy choice in diverse areas (Flores and Nooruddin, Reference Flores and Nooruddin2016). The paper also has implications for the literature on the “middle income trap” (Doner and Schneider Reference Doner and Schneider2016; Goenaga and Hanson, Reference Goenaga and Hanson2024). If a country’s inability to grow out of middle income is caused by economic favoritism and limited competition (Acharya, Haber and Lee, Reference Acharya, Haber and Lee2024), the revenue costs of competitive markets discussed here may further reinforce the trap.

Third, the paper uncovers how the absence of competition allows some firms to grow larger, to earn elevated profits, and to provide larger transfers to the government. However, we do not have clear expectations about which firms receive these benefits. A large literature on political connections would suggest that connected firms may be more likely to receive these benefits (Fisman, Reference Fisman2001; Earle and Gehlbach, Reference Earle and Gehlbach2015; Markgraf and Rosas, Reference Markgraf and Rosas2019; Resimic, Reference Resimic2021; Betz and Pond, Reference Betz and Pond2023b). At the same time, the literature on asset mobility suggests that firms may gain influence from their characteristics (Bates and Lien, Reference Bates and Lien1985; Oatley, Reference Oatley1999; Boix, Reference Boix2003; Kerner and Lawrence, Reference Kerner and Lawrence2014; Pond and Zafeiridou, Reference Pond and Zafeiridou2020; Johns and Wellhausen, Reference Johns and Wellhausen2020), and providing revenue may be a lever for gaining political influence—separate from political connections. We leave to future research considerations about which firms receive preferential treatment and the extent to which firms can gain influence from revenue.

Finally, we joined others in arguing that democratic governments value public goods like consumer welfare more highly than authoritarian governments (Mansfield, Milner and Rosendorff Reference Mansfield, Milner and Peter Rosendorff2000; Lake and Baum, Reference Lake and Baum2001; Bueno de Mesquita et al., Reference Bueno de Mesquita, Smith, Siverson and Morrow2003; Baker, Reference Baker2005). Recent evidence has brought this claim into question (Betz and Pond, Reference Betz and Pond2019), especially as individual consumer costs are small and spread throughout the population and citizens are unlikely to vote on consumer costs alone (Guisinger, Reference Guisinger2009; Naoi and Kume, Reference Naoi and Kume2011; Bearce and Moya, Reference Bearce and Moya2020). Moreover, firm influence is likely to counter consumer influence, and democratic governments provide firms with many avenues of political influence (Ehrlich, Reference Ehrlich2011; Bearce and Roosevelt, Reference Bearce and Roosevelt2023). Indeed, citizens in democracy value outcomes like jobs beyond consumer welfare (Short, Reference Short2022), and authoritarian governments value consumer welfare, as consumption affects protest behavior (Ballard-Rosa, Reference Ballard-Rosa2016). Consistent with this latter argument, antitrust policy has targeted price increases of outward facing consumer goods in Russia and China (Avdasheva and Shastitko, Reference Avdasheva and Shastitko2011; Zhang, Reference Zhang2021). Understanding how political institutions affect consumer and producer influence, especially in the face of inflation and price instability, remains a pressing question for political scientists.

Supplementary material

To view supplementary material for this article, please visit https://doi.org/10.1017/bap.2024.39

Acknowledgements

We are thankful to Timm Betz for his generosity in sharing theoretical and data insights, especially into the Orbis Historical database, which would have been difficult to access without his help. We also thank Tim Büthe, Randall Calvert, Zeynep Ceren, Chase Foster, Justin Fox, Hannah Löffler, Nathan Miller, Thomas Plümper, Christy Qiu, Craig Volden, and Guy Whitten for many helpful comments.

Footnotes

1 In 2019 in Latin America, corporate taxes were 15 percent of total taxation, while the personal income tax was only 9 percent; in the Asia-Pacific, it was 18 percent corporate to 16 percent personal income; and in Africa, it was 19 percent corporate to 17 percent personal income – social security, value added, and other taxes make up large shares as well). https://www.oecd.org/tax/tax-policy/global-revenue-statistics-database.htm

2 For a counter argument, see Baker (Reference Baker2005).

3 Callander, Foarta and Sugaya (Reference Callander, Foarta and Sugaya2024) also draw on Cournot competition to derive expectations for antitrust law; their emphasis is on the long-term effects of early levels of concentration for both policy and future concentration. Our model unpacks the relationship between taxation and competition.

4 Lax merger review for example would reduce $n$ . Splitting up large firms would increase $n$ .

5 Note that because corporate taxation is applied to firm profits, it does not affect the firm’s maximization problem. Each firm keeps $\left( {1 - t} \right){\pi _i}$ of its profits. When taking the first order condition, divide both sides by $\left( {1 - t} \right)$ , and it falls out of the model.

6 Profits converge to zero as the number of firms grow.

7 That is, ${{\partial {V_g}\left( {t,n} \right)} \over {\partial n}} = B{{n{{(1 - c)}^2}} \over {{{(n + 1)}^3}}} + {{n{{(1 - c)}^4}\left( {1 - n} \right)} \over {{{(n + 1)}^5}}} = 0$ . This simplifies to equation (3).

8 This expression is less than 0 as long as ${{{{(1 - c)}^2}} \over {{{(n + 1)}^2}}} \gt {{2{{(1 - c)}^2}\left( {n - 1} \right)} \over {{{(n + 1)}^3}}} \Rightarrow n \lt 3$ . If $n \gt3$ , we would have a corner solution. In this case, the government’s marginal cost to antitrust law is negative and increasing more quickly than the marginal benefit is decreasing. This means the marginal benefit overwhelms the marginal cost and the government would strengthen competition law and increase the number of $n$ as much as possible in this corner solution.

9 Monopoly rights for the bank also ensured that the government could not selectively steal from banks. A concentrated banking industry could punish the government for expropriation.

10 This level of aggregation differentiates for example between (2331) the manufacture of ceramic tiles and flags and (2332) the manufacture of ceramic bricks, tiles and construction products, in baked clay.

11 We thank Timm Betz for essential help in collecting and cleaning the data. The data was accessed through the license purchased by the Technical University in Munich.

12 See https://reports.weforum.org/global-competitiveness-index-2017-2018/downloads/ for the WEF measure. We use one of the survey questions to capture the Effectiveness of Antimonopoly Policy (EAP): “In your country, how effective are anti-monopoly policies at ensuring fair competition?” The respondents rate the effectiveness from 1 (not effective at all) to 7 (extremely effective).

13 www.bvdinfo.com Orbis provides data used commonly in studies using firm-level data. See Beazer and Blake (Reference Beazer and Blake2018), Betz, Pond and Yin (Reference Betz, Pond and Yin2021) and Cory, Lerner and Osgood (Reference Cory, Lerner and Osgood2021).

14 The names often do not align perfectly. After cleaning the data and removing common identifiers (e.g., “corp”, “inc”, “ltd”, etc), we use the Stata matchit fuzzy matching package to link the M&A and balance sheet data. We retain observations with a similarity score of over .76.

15 Many firms did not engage in M&As and are in industries with no competition cases, making the reported shares low.

16 Some Sections are omitted for display purposes.

18 When one firm was missing, we used the values of the other firms participating in the same deal.

19 This is the industry-average for NACE code 6420.

References

Acharya, Avidit, Haber, Stephen, and Lee, Alexander. 2024. “The Political Economy of Middle Income.” Working Paper. https://www.rochester.edu/college/faculty/alexander_lee/wp-content/uploads/2024/09/Middle_Income-7.pdf CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Arel-Bundock, Vincent. 2017. “The Unintended Consequences of Bilateralism: Treaty Shopping and International Tax Policy.” International Organization 71: 349–71.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Arslan, Melike. 2021. “Unruling Markets: How the Fight Against Monopolies Derailed Globally.” PhD diss., Northwestern University.Google Scholar
Arslan, Melike. 2022. “Legal Diffusion As Protectionism: The Case of the U.S. Promotion of Antitrust Laws.” Review of International Political Economy 30 (6): 2285–308.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Avdasheva, Svetlana, and Shastitko, Andrei. 2011. “Russian Anti-Trust Policy: Power of Enforcement versus Quality of Rules.” Post-Communist Economies 23 (4): 493505.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Baker, Andy. 2005. “Who Wants to Globalize? Consumer Tastes and Labor Markets in a Theory of Trade Policy Beliefs.” American Journal of Political Science 49 (4): 924–38.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ballard-Rosa, Cameron. 2016. “Hungry for Change: Food Imports, Urban Bias, and the Political Economy of Debt Default in Autocracies.” International Organization 70(2):313–46.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Basinger, Scott J. and Hallerberg, Mark. 2004. “Remodeling the Competition for Capital: How Domestic Politics Erases the Race to the Bottom.” American Political Science Review 98 (2): 261–76.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bastiaens, Ida, and Rudra, Nita. 2016. “Trade Liberalization and the Challenges of Revenue Mobilization: Can International Financial Institutions Make a Difference?Review of International Political Economy 23 (2): 261–89.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bates, Robert, and Lien, Donald. 1985. “A Note on Taxation, Development and Representative Government.” Politics and Society 14 (1): 5370.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bearce, David H., and Roosevelt, Megan. 2023. “The variation in firm lobbying by political regime: can it explain trade and currency policy differences?Political Science Research and Methods 11 (1): 95109.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bearce, David H., and Moya, Samantha L.. 2020. “Why is the Mass Public not More Supportive of Free Trade? Evidence from the United States.” International Studies Quarterly 64 (2): 380–91.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Beazer, Quintin H., and Blake, Daniel J.. 2018. “The Conditional Nature of Political Risk: How Home Institutions Influence the Location of Foreign Direct Investment.” American Journal of Political Science 62 (2): 470–85.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Betz, Timm. 2017. “Trading Interests: Domestic Institutions, International Negotiations, and the Politics of Trade.” Journal of Politics 79 (4): 1237–52.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Betz, Timm, and Pond, Amy. 2019. “The Absence of Consumer Interests in Trade Policy.” Journal of Politics 81 (2): 585600.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Betz, Timm, and Pond, Amy. 2023a. “Governments as Borrowers and Regulators.” Review of International Organizations, Forthcoming.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Betz, Timm, and Pond, Amy. 2023b. “Politically Connected Owners.” Comparative Political Studies 56 (4): 561–95.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Betz, Timm, Pond, Amy, and Yin, Weiwen. 2021. “Investment Agreements and the Fragmentation of Firms across Countries.” Review of International Organization 16: 755–91.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bodea, Cristina, and Higashijima, Masaaki. 2017. “Central Bank Independence and Fiscal Policy: Can the Central Bank Restrain Deficit Spending?British Journal of Political Science 47 (1): 4770.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Boix, Carles. 2003. Democracy and Redistribution. Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bombardini, Matilde. 2008. “Firm heterogeneity and Lobby Participation.” Journal of International Economics 75: 329–48.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bradford, Anu, Chilton, Adam S., Megaw, Christopher, and Sokol, Nathaniel. 2019. “Competition Law Gone Global: Introducing the Comparative Competition Law and Enforcement Datasets.” Journal of Empirical Legal Studies 16 (2): 411–43.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bueno de Mesquita, Bruce, Smith, Alastair, Siverson, Randolph M., and Morrow, James D.. 2003. The Logic of Political Survival. MIT Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bueno de Mesquita, Bruce, Morrow, James D., Siverson, Randolph M., and Smith, Alastair. 2002. “Political Institutions, Policy Choice and the Survival of Leaders.” British Journal of Political Science 32 (4): 559–90.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Callander, Steven, Foarta, Dana, and Sugaya, Takuo. 2022. “Market Competition and Political Influence: An Integrated Approach.” Econometrica 90 (6): 2723–53.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Callander, Steven, Foarta, Dana, and Sugaya, Takuo. 2024. “The Dynamics of a Policy Outcome: Market Response and Bureaucratic Enforcement of a Policy Change.” American Journal of Political Science, 68 (4): 1252–65. https://onlinelibrary.wiley.com/doi/abs/10.1111/ajps.12784 CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Calomiris, Charles W., and Haber, Stephen H.. 2014. Fragile by Design: The Political Origins of Banking Crisis and Scarce Credit. Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Carey, John M., and Shugart, Mathew Soberg. 1995. “Incentives to Cultivate a Personal Vote: a Rank Ordering of Electoral Formulas.” Electoral Studies 14 (4): 417–39.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Cory, Jared, Lerner, Michael, and Osgood, Iain. 2021. “Supply Chain Linkages and the Extended Carbon Coalition.” American Journal of Political Science 65 (1): 6987.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Doner, Richard F., and Schneider, Ben Ross. 2016. “The Middle-Income Trap.” World Politics 68 (4): 608–44.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Dove, John A. 2014. “Antitrust Enforcement by State Attorneys General: Institutional, Legal and Political Considerations.” Business and Politics 16 (2): 291312.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Earle, John S., and Gehlbach, Scott. 2015. “The Productivity Consequences of Political Turnover: Firm-Level Evidence from Ukraine’s Orange Revolution.” American Journal of Political Science 59 (3): 708–23.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ehrlich, Sean D. 2011. Access Points: An Institutional Theory of Policy Bias and Policy Complexity. Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Faith, Roger L., Leavens, Ronald R., and Tollison, Robert D.. 1982. “The Antitrust Pork Barrel.” The Journal of Law and Economics 15: 329–42.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Fisman, Raymond. 2001. “Estimating the Value of Political Connections.” American Economic Review 91(4):1095–102.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Flores, Thomas Edward, and Nooruddin, Irfan. 2016. Elections in Hard Times: Building Stronger Democracies in the 21st Century. Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Foster, Chase. 2021. “Varieties of Neoliberalism: Courts, Competition Paradigms and the Atlantic Divide in Anti-Trust.” Socio-Economic Review 20 (4): 1653–78. https://doi.org/10.1093/ser/mwab050 CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Foster, Chase. 2022. “The Politics of Global Regulatory Enforcement: Evidence from Cartel Prosecutions Involving Foreign Firms.” Working Paper August: 150. https://www.chasefoster.com/_files/ugd/892c68_1d782d8e5eff48c09a8a8397953fb938.pdf Google Scholar
Foster, Chase, and Thelen, Kathleen. 2024. “Coordination Rights, Competition Law and Varieties of Capitalism.” Comparative Political Studies, Forthcoming.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Franzese, Robert J. and Hays, Jude C.. 2008. “Interdependence in Comparative Politics: Substance, Theory, Empirics, Substance.” Comparative Political Studies 41 (4/5): 742–80.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Garrett, Geoffrey, and Lange, Peter. 1999. “Political Responses to Interdependence: What’s “Left” for the Left?International Organization 45 (4): 539–64.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Goenaga, Agustín, and Hanson, Jonathan. 2024. “State Capacity, Economic Complexity, and the Middle Income Trap.” Working Paper Presented at the annual meeting of APSA: 141.Google Scholar
Guisinger, Alexandra. 2009. “Determining Trade Policy: Do Voters Hold Politicians Accountable?International Organization 63 (3): 533–57.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Gulotty, Robert. 2020. Narrowing the Channel: The Politics of Regulatory Protection in International Trade. University of Chicago Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hadenius, Axel, and Teorell, Jan. 2007. “Pathway from Authoritarianism.” Journal of Democracy 18 (1):143–57.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hart, David M. 2003. “Political Representation in Concentrated Industries: Revisiting the “Olsonian Hypothesis”.” Business and Politics 5 (3): 261–86.Google Scholar
Hofstadter, Richard. 1964. “Antitrust in America.” Commentary 38 (2): 4753.Google Scholar
Hylton, Keith N., and Lin, Haizhen. 2010. “Optimal Antitrust Enforcement, Dynamic Competition, and Changing Economic Conditions.” Antitrust Law Journal 77 (1): 247–76.Google Scholar
Johns, Leslie, and Wellhausen, Rachel L.. 2020. “The Price of Doing Business: Why Replaceable Foreign Firms Get Worse Government Treatment.” Economics & Politics 33: 209–43.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kerner, Andrew, and Lawrence, Jane. 2014. “What’s the Risk? Bilateral Investment Treaties, Political Risk and Fixed Capital Accumulation.” British Journal of Political Science 44 (1): 107–21.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kim, In Song. 2017. “Political Cleavages within Industry: Firm-level Lobbying for Trade Liberalization.” American Political Science Review 111 (1): 120.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kono, Daniel Y. 2006. “Optimal Obfuscation: Democracy and Trade Policy Transparency.” American Political Science Review 100 (3): 369–84.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Koop, Christel, and Hanretty, Chris. 2018. “Political Independence, Accountability, and the Quality of Regulatory Decision-Making.” Comparative Political Studies 51 (1): 3875.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Koop, Christel, and Jordana, Jacint. 2022. Handbook of Regulatory Authorities. Edward Elgar Publishing Company. Chapter 14: Regulatory independence and the quality of regulation.Google Scholar
Koop, Christel, and Kessler, Philip. 2021. “Keeping Control of Regulation? Domestic Constraints on the Creation of Independent Authorities in Emerging and Developing Economies.” Governance 34 (2): 545–64.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lake, David A., and Baum, Matthew A.. 2001. “The Invisible Hand of Democracy: Political Control and the Provision of Public Services.” Comparative Political Studies 34 (6): 587621.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Levi, Margaret. 1988. Of Rule and Revenue. University of California Press.Google Scholar
Mansfield, Edward D., Milner, Helen V., and Peter Rosendorff, B.. 2000. “Free to Trade: Democracies, Autocracies, and International Trade.” The American Political Science Review 94 (2): 305–21.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Markgraf, Jonas, and Rosas, Guillermo. 2019. “On Board with Banks: Do Banking Connections Help Politicians Win Elections?Journal of Politics 81(4):148.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Marshall, Monty G., Jaggers, Keith, and Gurr, Ted Robert. 2017. Polity IV Project: Political Regime Characteristics and Transitions 1800–2016. Dataset. http://www.systemicpeace.org/inscrdata.html Google Scholar
Menaldo, Victor. 2016. “The Fiscal Roots of Financial Underdevelopment.” American Journal of Political Science 60 (2): 456–71.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Menon, Anil, and Osgood, Iain. 2024. “The Wrong Winners: Anti-Corporate Animus and Attitudes Towards Trade.” British Journal of Political Science, Forthcoming: 118.Google Scholar
Mitton, Todd. 2008. “Institutions and Concentration.” Journal of Development Economics 86:367–94.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Naoi, Megumi, and Kume, Ikuo. 2011. “Explaining Mass Support for Agricultural Protectionism: Evidence from a Survey Experiment During the Global Recession.” International Organization 65 (4): 771–95.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Nielson, Daniel L. 2003. “Supplying Trade Reform: Political Institutions and Liberalization in Middle-Income Presidential Democracies.” American Journal of Political Science 47 (3): 470–91.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
North, Douglass C. and Weingast, Barry. 1989. “Constitutions and Commitment: The Evolution of Institutions Governing Public Choice in Seventeenth-Century England.” Journal of Economic History 49 (4): 803–32.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Nunn, Nathan. 2007. “Relationship-Specificity, Incomplete Contracts, and the Pattern of Trade.” The Quarterly Journal of Economics 122 (2): 569600.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Oatley, Thomas. 1999. “How Constraining is Capital Mobility? The Partisan Hypothesis in an Open Economy.” American Journal of Political Science 43(4):1003–27.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Olson, Mancur. 1965. The Logic of Collective Action; Public Goods and the Theory of Groups. Harvard University Press.Google Scholar
Osgood, Iain. 2018. “Globalizing the Supply Chain: Firm and Industrial Support for US Trade Agreements.” International Organization 72: 455–84.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Perlman, Rebecca L. 2019. “For Safety or Profit? How Science Serves the Strategic Interests of Private Actors.” American Journal of Political Science 64 (2): 293308.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Perotti, Enrico, and Volpin, Paolo F.. 2004. “Lobbying on Entry.” Tinbergen Institute Discussion Paper 04-088/2:1–43.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Philippon, Thomas. 2019. The Great Reversal: How America Gave Up on Free Markets. Harvard University Press.Google Scholar
Pond, Amy, and Zafeiridou, Christina. 2020. “The Political Importance of Financial Performance.” American Journal of Political Science 64 (1): 152–68.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Queralt, Didac. 2015. “From Mercantilism to Free Trade: A History of Fiscal Capacity Building.” Quarterly Journal of Political Science 10 (2): 221–73.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Resimic, Milos. 2021. “Network Ties and the Politics of Renationalization: Embeddedness, Political-Business Relations, and Renationalization in Post-Milosevic Serbia.” Comparative Political Studies 54 (1): 179209.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ro, Hyeon-Young. 2021. “Disguised Protectionism: Competition Laws and National Security Policies as Barriers to Cross-border M&As.” Working Paper August: 133. https://hyeonyoungro.github.io/assets/pdf/Disguised-Protectionism_Ro.pdf Google Scholar
Schultz, Kenneth A., and Weingast, Barry R.. 2003. “The Democratic Advantage: Institutional Foundations of Financial Power in International Competition.” International Organization 57 (1): 342.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Short, Nicholas. 2022. “Antitrust Reform in Political Perspective: A Constructive Critique for the Neo-Brandeisians.” Working Paper, 141. https://scholar.harvard.edu/files/nickshort/files/nick_short_-_antitrust_reform_in_political_perspective.pdf.Google Scholar
Swank, Duane. 2006. “Tax Policy in an Era of Internationalization: Explaining the Spread of Neoliberalism.” International Organization 60 (4): 847–82.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Thelen, Kathleen. 2025. Attention Shoppers: American Retail Capitalism and the Rise of the Amazon Economy. Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Wahman, Michael, Teorell, Jan, and Hadenius, Axel. 2013. “Authoritarian Regime Types Revisited: Updated Data in Comparative Perspective.” Contemporary Politics 19 (1): 1934.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Weymouth, Stephen. 2012. “Firm Lobbying and Influence in Developing Countries: A Multilevel Approach.” Business and Politics 14 (4): 126.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Weymouth, Stephen. 2016. “Competition Politics: Interest Groups, Democracy, and Antitrust Reform in Developing Countries.” The Antitrust Bulletin 61 (2): 296316.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Whitman, James Q. 2007. “Consumerism versus Producerism: A Study in Comparative Law.” Yale Law Journal 117 (3): 340406.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Wu, Tim. 2018. The Curse of Bigness: Antitrust in the New Gilded Age. Columbia Global Reports.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Zhang, Angela Huyue. 2021. Chinese Antitrust Exceptionalism: How the Rise of China Challenges Global Regulation. Oxford University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Zhang, Angela Huyue. 2022. “Agility Over Stability: China’s Great Reversal in Regulating the Platform Economy.” Harvard International Law Journal 63 (457): 160.Google Scholar
Zingales, Luigi. 2017. “Towards a Political Theory of the Firm.” Journal of Economic Perspectives 31 (3): 113–30.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Figure 0

Table 1. Corporate taxation and competition policy enforcement

Figure 1

Figure 1. Marginal effects of corporate tax revenue from Table 1.

Figure 2

Figure 2. Authoritarianism score in Turkey.

Figure 3

Figure 3. Antitrust enforcement and firm activity in Turkey.

Figure 4

Figure 4. Share of competition cases by NACE Section.

Figure 5

Table 2. Access to financing in Turkey

Figure 6

Table 3. Corporate tax revenue and M&As

Figure 7

Table 4. Corporate tax revenue and competition cases

Figure 8

Figure 5. TAV Havalimanlari tax and acquisition activities.

Figure 9

Figure 6. Marginal effects of corporate tax revenue from Table 3.

Figure 10

Figure 7. Marginal effects of corporate tax revenue on cases from Table 4, Column 2.

Supplementary material: File

Lee and Pond supplementary material

Lee and Pond supplementary material
Download Lee and Pond supplementary material(File)
File 1.3 MB