Hostname: page-component-586b7cd67f-t7czq Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-11-25T19:21:07.048Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

“The Conflation of Productivity and Efficiency in Economics and Economic History”: A Comment

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  05 December 2008

John Vincent Nye
Affiliation:
Washington University

Extract

In a recent article, Edward Saraydar (1989) takes economists and economic historians to task for equating productivity and efficiency in comparative economic analysis. Although I found his thesis interesting, I was a bit surprised to see selected remarks from my article on firm size in nineteenth-century France (Nye,1987) used to frame his criticism of productivity comparisons as a means of making prescriptive statements. The passages selected may mislead the reader as to the nature of my arguments. Let me quote Saraydar on this: … I argue that … the problem with equating productivity with efficiency is that from the neoclassical standpoint this strongly suggests a prescriptive view - a view that things should be or should have been different - and thereby frees the analyst from the need to justify the utility costs that might be or might have been required to make things different. Thus, in the French industrialization debate, for example, Nye points out that evidence that smaller family firms were less productive would support the conclusion “that nineteenth-century French firms were too small (for whatever reasons) and that consequently French industry suffered from inefficiency” (Nye, 1987, pp. 667–68). Suppose the evidence to which Nye refers to existed. [My emphasis] Distributive considerations aside, in neoclassical economics a more Pareto-efficient state by its very nature is to be preferred to a less efficient one. Therefore, the implication is that family firms should have been larger and more productive. However, suppose also that the plethora of small family firms in nineteenth-century France, in fact, constituted a longstanding, widely accepted, socially imbedded institution. Clearly, the traditionalist thought-experiment and conclusion would ignore the potential costs in utility or satisfaction to owners of factors of production, a utility loss that may well have been required to make the “more efficient.” transformation to a relatively few large-scale industrial firms. That potential utility loss cannot be ignored and should be part of the analysis. (Saraydar, 1989, p. 56)

Type
Discussion
Copyright
Copyright © Cambridge University Press 1990

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

References

REFERENCES

Conrad, Alfred H., and Meyer, John R. 1971. “The Economics of Slavery in the AnteBellum South.” In The Reinterpretation of American Economic History, edited by Fogel, R. W. and Engerman, S. L., pp. 342–61. New York: Harper & Row. This is a slightly revised version of the article that originally appeared in 1958 in The Journal of Political Economy 66:95–122.Google Scholar
David, Paul A., 1976. Reckoning with Slavery. New York: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Fogel, Robert W., and Engerman, Stanley L. 1974. Time on the Cross, vols. 1 and 2. Boston: Little, Brown.Google Scholar
North, Douglass C. 1981. Structure and Change in Economic History. New York: Norton.Google Scholar
Nye, John Vincent. 1987. “Firm Size and Economic Backwardness: A New Look at the French Industrialization Debate.” Journal of Economic History 47:649–69.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Saraydar, Edward. 1989. “The Conflation of Productivity and Efficiency in Economics and Economic History.” Economics and Philosophy 5:5567.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Wright, Gavin. 1976. “Prosperity, Progress, and American Slavery.” In Reckoning with Slavery, David, P. A., pp. 302–36. New York: Oxford Univeristy Press.Google Scholar