Hostname: page-component-848d4c4894-xm8r8 Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-07-03T04:10:17.008Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

The impacts of the Brazilian NDC and their contribution to the Paris agreement on climate change

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  15 April 2019

Angelo C. Gurgel*
Affiliation:
São Paulo School of Economics, Fundação Getulio Vargas, São Paulo, Brazil
Sergey Paltsev
Affiliation:
MIT Joint Program on the Science and Policy of Global Change, Cambridge, MA, USA
Gustavo Velloso Breviglieri
Affiliation:
Center for Sustainability Studies, Business Administration School of São Paulo, Fundação Getulio Vargas, São Paulo, Brazil
*
*Corresponding author. E-mail: angelo.gurgel@fgv.br
Get access
Rights & Permissions [Opens in a new window]

Abstract

This paper measures the economic impacts of Brazil's climate mitigation strategies contained in its Nationally Determined Contribution (NDC). To do so, we employ the computable general equilibrium MIT Economic Projection and Policy Analysis model and simulate alternative carbon pricing scenarios (sectoral versus economy-wide carbon markets), set to achieve the country's overall emissions targets announced under the Paris Agreement. The results show relatively cheap emissions reductions from land-use changes and agriculture in the short run: the cost of the Brazilian NDC is predicted to be only 0.7 per cent of GDP in 2030. Further efforts to reduce carbon emissions beyond 2030 would require policy changes, since all the potential emissions reductions from deforestation would be finished and the capacity to expand renewable energy sources would be constrained. In this case, an economy-wide carbon pricing system would help substantially to avoid higher compliance costs.

Type
Research Article
Copyright
Copyright © Cambridge University Press 2019 

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

1. Introduction

Climate change is one of the most important risks threatening the planet both today and into the future. Solutions to this problem likely require cooperation at a global level (Keohane and Victor, Reference Keohane and Victor2016). The 2015 Paris AgreementFootnote 1 is the broadest and most inclusive international agreement aimed at addressing climate change globally. Under the Agreement, both developed and developing countries have proposed measures to reduce greenhouse gas (GHG) emissions over the next decade.

Brazil has been an important player in the discussions about climate change. It has a unique pattern of emissions, most of it coming from agriculture (32 per cent), land-use changes and deforestation (28 per cent), followed by fossil fuel energy use (27.7 per cent) (Brazil, 2016). The country also boasts one of the broadest market experiences with biofuels in the world (La Rovere et al., Reference La Rovere, Pereira and Simões2011), although offshore deep oil exploration has also gained impetus in recent years (Lefèvre et al., Reference Lefèvre, Wills and Hourcade2018).

Moreover, since the 15th UNFCCC Conference of the Parties (COP) in Copenhagen in 2009, Brazil has assumed a pioneering position among developing countries in terms of commitments to mitigate climate change (Hochstetler and Viola, Reference Hochstetler and Viola2012). On that occasion, it announced voluntary goals to decrease its emissions by 36.1 or 38.9 per cent by 2020 (against a reference scenario), which were translated into the National Policy on Climate Change (Law 12.187, from December 2009). These targets should be reached through emissions cuts from land-use changes and deforestation (24.7 per cent), agriculture (4.9 to 6.1 per cent), energy (6.1 to 7.7 per cent), and iron and steel production (0.3 to 0.4 per cent) (Brazil, 2008).

Recently Brazil increased its commitments to address climate change. Under the Paris Agreement, it has announced plans to cut its emissions by 37 per cent by 2025 and 43 per cent by 2030 (relative to 2005 levels) in its Nationally Determined Contribution (NDC) (UNFCCC, 2016). To achieve these targets, the Brazilian NDC highlighted its intentions to decrease deforestation, reforest degraded land areas, expand the use of renewable energy sources, increase energy efficiency and intensify agricultural and livestock production. In this context, it is highly relevant to understand the costs associated with these commitments, as well as alternative policy options to achieve them.

There are already several studies about GHG emissions control in Brazil. Rocha (Reference Rocha2003), Tourinho et al. (Reference Tourinho, da Motta and Alves2003), Ferreira Filho and Rocha (Reference Ferreira Filho and Rocha2008) and Feijó and Porto (Reference Feijó and Porto2009) investigated the impacts of carbon taxes on the Brazilian economy. Ferreira Filho and Moraes (Reference Ferreira Filho and Moraes2015) projected climate change impacts on Brazilian agriculture. EMCB (2010) analyzed the costs of reducing deforestation in the Amazon region, heavily deploying biofuels into the energy mix, and adopting carbon taxes, but each of these mitigation options were considered individually in alternative models.

Gurgel and Paltsev (Reference Gurgel and Paltsev2014) compared the economic impacts from sectoral carbon taxes and cap-and-trade schemes to achieve Brazil's voluntary targets under the Copenhagen Agreement. La Rovere et al. (Reference La Rovere, Pereira, Dubeux and Wills2014) also addressed the efforts to achieve these goals by mapping the initiatives and policy instruments proposed, although not simulating them. Magalhães et al. (Reference Magalhães, Carvalho and Domingues2016) simulated cap-and-trade scenarios on energy and industrial sectors. Lucena et al. (Reference Lucena, Clarke, Schaeffer, Szklo, Rochedo, Nogueira, Daenzer, Gurgel, Kitous and Kober2016) performed a multi-model comparison of carbon taxes and mitigation scenarios on energy sectors. Similarly, Kober et al. (Reference Kober, Summerton, Pollitt, Chewpreecha, Ren, Wills, Octaviano, McFarland, Beach, Cai, Calderon, Fisher-Vanden and Rodriguez2016) compared six models and country results for carbon tax scenarios in Latin America, including Brazil, while Octaviano et al. (Reference Octaviano, Paltsev and Gurgel2016) compared the economic impacts for Brazil and Mexico to meet their 2020 climate commitments. Magalhães and Domingues (Reference Magalhães and Domingues2016) investigated how energy efficiency measures may reduce GHG emissions in Brazil, while Lefèvre et al. (Reference Lefèvre, Wills and Hourcade2018) presented a similar analysis, but in the context of the country's official energy planning. Some efforts have also been made to measure the regional impacts of deforestation targets, as in Carvalho et al. (Reference Carvalho, Domingues and Horridge2017).

Some of these papers used static economic models adapted to incorporate environmental aspects or focus on emissions reductions only in some specific sectors, such as industry and energy, or else only on deforestation. Others considered only CO2 emissions, disregarding other GHGs. A few studies, such as Gurgel and Paltsev (Reference Gurgel and Paltsev2014) and Octaviano et al. (Reference Octaviano, Paltsev and Gurgel2016), addressed mitigation efforts in all sectors, but they restricted their analysis to mandatory cap-and-trade schemes alone. Therefore, to the best of our knowledge, none of these studies has been able to inform policy makers and society in general on the effects of the Paris Agreement targets, considering all mitigation efforts Brazil has committed to take. Also, none of these studies has compared alternative policy scenarios to achieve the country's emissions targets, including carbon pricing mechanisms and mitigation efforts based on land use, land-use change and forestry. Given Brazil's position as a major GHG emitter and its important role in global climate negotiations, such an investigation has domestic and international relevance.

Accordingly, this paper aims to estimate and compare the economic impacts of the Brazilian NDC with the impacts from alternative climate policies based on carbon pricing schemes. To do so, we adapt and employ a dynamic-recursive general equilibrium model of the world economy, namely, the MIT Economic Projection and Policy Analysis (EPPA) model, in its fifth version (Paltsev et al., Reference Paltsev, Reilly, Jacoby, Eckaus, McFarland, Sarofim, Asadoorian and Babiker2005; Chen et al., Reference Chen, Paltsev, Reilly, Morris, Karplus, Gurgel, Winchester, Kishimoto, Blanc and Babiker2017). Section 2 describes the model. Section 3 presents the results and section 4 presents our conclusions. Such an exercise gives us an indication of the likelihood that the country will adopt the necessary policies to fulfill its commitments, while also highlighting the trade-offs between alternative instruments to achieve the country's NDC.

2. Methods

Policies to reduce GHG emissions usually affect many economic sectors and agents. In order to evaluate the impacts of climate policies in Brazil, we use a computable general equilibrium (CGE) model that represents several emitting agents and sectors and captures the interdependencies between them in the economy. The model estimates the directions and magnitudes of exogenous shocks on the economy, allowing us to measure the effects and costs of alternative scenarios.

CGE models combine the abstract general equilibrium structure formalized by Arrow and Debreu (Reference Arrow and Debreu1954) with economic data to obtain supply, demand and price levels in equilibrium conditions in a set of specific markets. They are a standard tool of empirical analysis, widely used in welfare and distributive analyses. Kydland and Prescott (Reference Kydland and Prescott1996) and Shoven and Whalley (Reference Shoven and Whalley1984) discuss other aspects and details of CGE models.

We use the MIT EPPA model in its fifth version.Footnote 2 It is a dynamic recursive general equilibrium model of the world economy, built on the Global Trade Analysis Project (GTAP) database (Dimaranan and Mcdougall, Reference Dimaranan and Mcdougall2002; Narayanan and Walmsley, Reference Narayanan and Walmsley2008) with additional data about GHGs and other pollutants. EPPA considers a long-run simulation horizon (2005 to 2100) and incorporates all of the main GHGs (CO2, CH4, N2O, HFCs, PFCs and SF6). For instance, within the model, CH4 emissions from agricultural production stem from rice (production), enteric fermentation, manure management, waste, savannah and, indirectly, from deforestation.Footnote 3 Opportunities for mitigation of non-CO2 gases are also considered, calibrated from marginal abatement cost curves. The model also allows us to evaluate the economic impacts of mitigation policies, including welfare and equity measures.

EPPA aggregates GTAP data in 16 regions and 21 sectors (table 1). It is worth mentioning that the model distinguishes household (i.e., private automobiles) and industrial transportation and separately represents mature (e.g., hydro, nuclear, fossil) and alternative energy supply technologies (e.g., second-generation biomass).

Table 1. Regions, sectors and primary factors in the EPPA model

a Includes managed forest areas for forestry production and secondary forests previously used for wood extraction and agricultural purposes (natural vegetation re-growth).

Alternative energy sources are neither extensively used nor available in the benchmark year of the model (2004), but could potentially be demanded on a larger scale in the future, depending on energy prices and climate policies. To represent these technologies, EPPA takes detailed bottom-up engineering parameters into account, described by Chen et al. (Reference Chen, Paltsev, Reilly, Morris, Karplus, Gurgel, Winchester, Kishimoto, Blanc and Babiker2017), as well as Paltsev et al. (Reference Paltsev, Reilly, Jacoby, Eckaus, McFarland, Sarofim, Asadoorian and Babiker2005).Footnote 4 These so-called ‘backstop’ technologies are one way to represent technical changes in CGE models; here they include additional fuels (such as biofuels) and electricity generating technologies (such as wind and solar power), also listed in table 1.

EPPA is formulated as a mixed complementarity problem (MCP) in the General Algebraic Modeling System (GAMS) software (Brooke et al., Reference Brooke, Kendrick, Meeraus and Raman1988) and solved using a mathematical programming system for general equilibrium analysis as its modeling language (Rutherford, Reference Rutherford1995). In each period, production functions for each sector and region describe how capital, labor, land, energy and other primary factors and intermediate inputs are combined to obtain goods and services.

In each region of the model there is a representative agent maximizing its utility by choosing how to allocate its income to consume goods and services. The economic sectors are represented by a representative firm, which chooses primary factors and intermediate inputs to maximize its profits, given the available technology. The model has a complete representation of markets, which must achieve the equilibrium simultaneously. We illustrate the general model structure in MCP by presenting the three conditions to be fulfilled in this type of representation: zero profit, market clearance and income balance.

EPPA uses constant elasticity of substitution (CES) function forms to specify production and utility functions, including Cobb-Douglas and Leontief. Different levels of substitution among inputs and factors and between fuels, electricity and other emitting processes are enabled via the use of nested structures. Table 2 lists elasticity values for the production sectors in the model.

Table 2. Elasticities of substitution in production sectors in the EPPA model

a AGRI sectors are: CROP, LIVE and FORS (sectors as defined in table 1).

Figure 1 presents the technologies assumed in the agricultural sectors (crop, livestock and forestry) as an illustration. It shows several elasticities (σ ) governing the ability to substitute inputs and primary factors. The structure of the agricultural sector explicitly includes land and represents the tradeoff between land and an energy-materials bundle. This resource-intensive bundle enters at the top nest, with the value-added bundle. Because land as an input is critically unique in agriculture, the nested structure for agriculture allows for substitution between land and other inputs.Footnote 5

Source: Paltsev et al. (Reference Paltsev, Reilly, Jacoby, Eckaus, McFarland, Sarofim, Asadoorian and Babiker2005).

Figure 1. Structure of agricultural production sectors

Figure 2 presents the nested CES structure used to represent household consumption. It considers the endogenous decision about consumption and savings at its top level and includes an energy nest completely separated from the household decision on transportation. That is, it splits the decision about fuel consumption for transportation and other energy uses. Families can also consume their own transportation services (composed of automobiles, fuel, maintenance parts and services, and insurance) or may buy transportation services from air, road and subway transportation companies. Table 3 presents the elasticities of substitution in consumption, i.e., final demand, in the EPPA model.

Source: Paltsev et al. (Reference Paltsev, Reilly, Jacoby, Eckaus, McFarland, Sarofim, Asadoorian and Babiker2005).

Figure 2. Structure of final demand in EPPA

Table 3. Elasticities of substitution in consumption in the EPPA model

For each period, the model's closure considers a fixed endowment of primary factors in each region, which are free to move among sectors, with the exception of the non-malleable fraction of capital.Footnote 6 Land is used only in the agricultural sector or to grow natural vegetation. One land use type can be converted to another if the full conversion costs are paid. Fossil fuels, nuclear and hydro resources are specific to the energy sectors using them.

The model does not consider unemployment, and prices are flexible. From the demand side, the marginal propensity to save is constant and regionally specified, given the benchmark share of savings in the aggregate household expenditure. International capital flows that compensate trade imbalances are exogenously specified to decline smoothly over time. This means that in each period an implicit real exchange rate will adjust to accommodate changes in export and import flows. Government expenditures react to changes in relative prices and tax revenues are subject to economic activity.

EPPA5's base year is 2004. The model simulates the economy recursively at 5-year intervals from 2005 to 2100. Economic development in 2005 and 2010 matches actual GDP growth data. Future growth scenarios are driven by savings and investment patterns and exogenous assumptions about productivity improvements in labor, energy, and land.

The demand for goods produced by each sector, including food and fuels, grows as GDP grows. The use of depletable resources decreases stocks, driving production to higher cost grades. Sectors that use renewable resources, such as land, compete for the available flow of services and rents stemming from them.

These parameters and assumptions, as well as the different policies modeled (e.g., constraints in the total amount of GHG emissions), change the relative economic appeal of different technologies over time and across scenarios. The adoption of advanced technologies, such as cellulosic bio-oil, is endogenous and happens as they become cost-competitive with existing technologies.

Population growth is based on long-run trends from the United Nations forecast (UN, 2009). Labor productivity improvements are specified to reproduce observed and expected average GDP levels from the International Monetary Fund (IMF, 2011). Physical units are used to represent energy data, according to the International Energy Agency (IEA, 2011). With regard to Brazil, we have compared this data with the most relevant domestic sources (IBGE, 2006; EPE, 2010, 2011, 2012; MCTI, 2014; Brazil, 2016). Data on GHG emissions in EPPA comes from Waugh et al. (Reference Waugh, Paltsev, Selin, Reilly, Morris and Sarofim2011).

2.1 Land conversion and competing uses

Each land-type area can be converted to another type or removed from agricultural production to a non-use category (secondary vegetation). Conversion is achieved by assuming that one hectare of land of one type is converted to one hectare of another type, assuring consistency between physical and economic accounting in the general equilibrium setting. Marginal conversion costs are equal to the difference in values between each land type, with real inputs being added during the conversion process through a land transformation function, following Gurgel et al. (Reference Gurgel, Reilly and Paltsev2007) and Melillo et al. (Reference Melillo, Reilly, Kicklighter, Gurgel, Cronin, Paltsev, Felzer, Wang, Sokolov and Schlosser2009). Finally, land is also subject to exogenous productivity improvements (Reilly and Fuglie, Reference Reilly and Fuglie1998).

Conversion of natural forest areas to agriculture produces timber and other forestry products. This transformation from natural vegetation to agricultural production is calibrated to represent a response in land supply. We assume that land conversion patterns in the last two decades are representative of the long-term response: price elasticities of supply of land for each region are calculated from observed annual averages for land price increases and conversion rates (from natural forest to managed land), in percentages, from 1990 through 2005.

3. Results

3.1 BAU and climate policy scenarios

Brazil's NDC envisions and explicitly describes several mitigation strategies in order to reduce the country's emissions by 43 per cent by 2030, compared to 2005 levels. These include: achieve zero illegal deforestation; restore and reforest 12 million hectares (ha) of forests; increase the share of sustainable biofuels in the energy mix to 18 per cent; achieve 45 per cent of renewable energy sources in the energy mix; increase the share of renewable energy sources in the power supply to 23 per cent; achieve efficiency gains of 10 per cent in the electricity sector; restore 15 million ha of degraded pastures; and expand the area of integrated cropland-livestock-forestry systems by 5 million ha (UNFCCC, 2016).

We simulate different policy scenarios to investigate alternative ways to achieve Brazil's proposed targets and compare the results, in terms of GHG emissions and economic performance, with those from a Business as Usual (BAU) scenario. These scenarios enable us to analyze the existing measures planned by the Brazilian government to curb emissions, as well as alternatives for carbon pricing instruments (not explicitly included in Brazil's current or proposed policy mix).

First, we consider those strategies described in the Brazilian NDC, with a mix of sectoral incentives (subsidies) to renewable energy, agricultural and livestock expansion, and penalties (taxes) to deforestation. Following this, we implement alternative scenarios with carbon pricing instruments, simulated as different configurations of a cap-and-trade scheme, given that carbon prices are endogenous in our model. Here we envisage two main alternatives: sectoral cap-and-trade systems, with equivalent emissions cuts (in relative terms) for each economic sector; and an economy-wide carbon market, covering all sectors, excluding emissions from deforestation, which are constrained by a specific tax on it.Footnote 7 These cap-and-trade (C&T) scenarios are first imposed on all GHGs and later only on CO2 emissions.Footnote 8

Table 4 briefly presents all scenarios. We simulate the model from 2010 to 2050, and mitigation strategies start in 2020. Climate policies in Brazil are implemented to achieve its reduction targets announced under the Paris Agreement. After 2030, we keep constraining emissions linearly to reach a level of emissions that is 50 per cent below those observed in 2005.

Table 4. Scenarios simulated

Figure 3 shows Brazil's GHG emissions trajectory in the BAU scenario. From 2005 to 2012, data comes from official sources (early emissions estimates) (MCTI, 2014). Data for 2014 comes from the independent initiative ‘Sistema de Estimativa de Emissão de Gases de Efeito Estufa’ (SEEG, 2017). EPPA projects GHG emissions from 2015 onwards. Figure 3 presents the expected level of emissions by 2025 and 2030.Footnote 9

Sources: MCTI (2014)Footnote 10, SEEG (2017) and EPPA results.

Figure 3. GHG emissions in Brazil. *Emissions targets under the Paris Agreement

The model produces an increasing trend in emissions, especially from the energy sector. Emissions from land-use changes and agriculture retain larger shares in total emissions during the entire projection. Total emissions reflect: expected economic growth; increased use of fossil fuels in the energy mix; and the expansion of the agricultural sector. The rate of economic growth is one of the most important drivers of emissions in the BAU scenario. These rates range from 2.48 to 2.80 per cent per year between 2015 to 2050 and are in alignment with IMF projections, with the exception of the first five years (until 2020), which have a slightly higher growth rate in EPPA.

Land-use changes are another relevant driver of GHG emissions in Brazil. Figure 4 shows expected changes in land-use patterns under the BAU scenario, in cumulative terms, compared to 2015. These changes reflect the average rate of deforestation in the Amazon and Cerrado (Brazilian Savannah) biomes from 2000 to 2010 and are indicative of a BAU scenario that considers weak deforestation controls after 2015. Land-use changes projected by the model also reveal an increase in cropland area from 51 million ha in 2015 to 95 million ha in 2050. Total area dedicated to pastures would fall from 182 million ha in 2015 to 175 million in 2050, following current trends (IBGE, 1995, 2006; LAPIG, 2015).

Source: Model results.

Figure 4. Cumulative land-use changes in the BAU scenario compared to 2015

3.2 Emissions trajectories

Table 5 presents total GHG emissions in Brazil for each of the alternative scenarios, relative to the BAU scenario. After 2030, targets were set to reach 50 per cent emissions reductions by 2050 relative to 2005 emissions. The scenario COP-2030 simulates the actions proposed in the Brazilian NDC. Table 5 shows that these would not guarantee that the country would reach its targets, although it would draw close.

Table 5. GHG emissions in Brazil in the alternative scenarios (% of BAU emissions)

Source: Model results.

Possible (partial) explanations for this result are the lack of current measures for GHG emissions and sequestration from pasture areas, as well as those emissions reductions and sequestration stemming from recovered pasture areas and integrated crop-livestock-forest systems. These are not present in Brazil's official GHG inventories. Thus, we do not have the necessary data to represent them in the model. Nonetheless, we implement measures related to them, such as pasture recovery and the expansion of integrated systems.

A first lesson from our results is the urgent need to create methodologies and mechanisms to measure and register emissions from the processes mentioned above, as well as to include them in the country's official GHG inventory.

Table 5 also shows that the COP-2030 scenario does not avoid an increase in emissions after 2030, since there is no intensification of efforts to reduce emissions through sectoral mitigation actions, such as incentives to renewable energy sources, forest recovery and intensification in agricultural and livestock production. Given that many other relevant emissions sources are not directly covered by Brazil's NDC (e.g., energy-related fossil fuel emissions), total emissions grow beyond 2030, once again drawing closer to the BAU scenario.

In the COP scenario, we assume increasing efforts to reduce emissions after 2030, using the same mitigation actions as in COP-2030. These efforts allow emissions to stabilize at 1.3 billion tons of CO2 eq per year, but are not able to achieve increasingly reduced targets beyond 2030 (below 43 per cent of the 2005 levels).

Brazil's proposed actions at COP21 are based on stopping deforestation, restoring forest areas, increasing the use of renewable energy sources and intensifying agriculture and livestock production. Given that deforestation will be controlled by 2030 and carbon sequestration from intensified agriculture is not accounted for, the model results just mean that there are some limits to curbing emissions by expanding the share of renewable sources in the energy mix.

Since current policy proposals will have reached their potential to reduce emissions by 2030, the country needs to consider additional mitigation strategies in the long term. Possible avenues are adopting carbon pricing mechanisms and covering a broader number of economic sectors and activities in its policies.

In this sense, we designed cap-and-trade scenarios that reach the proposed emission targets. In the sectoral C&T scenarios, all sectors reduce emissions by the same percentage. In the economy-wide scenarios, we set a quantitative emissions target (table 5) to the whole economy and let the model generate the equivalent national carbon price to reach it.

3.3 Economic costs

Alternative climate policy scenarios induce different changes in the relative prices of energy inputs and emissions-intensive activities, thereby altering the choices made by both consumers and producers. These changes determine the impacts on the aggregated economic activity, measured here by variations in GDP relative to the BAU scenario (table 6).

Table 6. Changes in GDP (%) relative to BAU

Source: Model results.

Economic impacts are relatively small until 2030, reaching at most a 0.8 per cent lower GDP in the Sectoral C&Ts scenario. The COP-2030 and COP scenarios lead to a 0.7 per cent decrease in GDP by 2030. This result suggests that the Brazilian proposals under the Paris Agreement were well designed: they target efforts in those sectors with relatively low abatement costs. Such a decrease in GDP seems modest, given the benefit of achieving 43 per cent emissions reductions relative to 2005 levels.

Beyond 2030, however, low-cost mitigation opportunities become scarce, and costs increase fast. The scenario COP-2030 is the only one that does not lead to higher costs, since mitigation efforts are not intensified; emissions, though, are considerably higher. On the other end, the COP scenario produces unreasonable GDP losses. Since cheaper emissions reductions through stopping deforestation and reforesting are finished by 2030, the only mitigation measure in this scenario is increasing incentives to renewable energy sources. A 19 per cent loss in GDP by 2050 suggests that these incentives would lead to too many distortions in the economy and quickly reach the limit for the expansion of renewable sources in the country. Consequently, carbon pricing strategies are better options to curb GHG emissions in the long run.

Sectoral C&Ts affect GDP by minus 1.5 per cent in 2035. This impact reaches negative 6.6 per cent by 2050 in order to achieve 50 per cent emissions reductions compared to 2005 levels. These are expressive numbers, but much smaller than those from the COP scenario. A broader coverage divides the burden of cutting emissions among all sectors in the economy. However, as every sector needs to reduce emissions by the same relative amount, the sectoral C&Ts do not enable the best allocation of resources, given that those sectors facing higher mitigation costs need to reduce emissions by the same share as those with lower costs.

The Economy-wide C&T produces the lowest negative impact on GDP. GDP losses by the year 2035 remain around 0.5 per cent in these scenarios, and reach only 3.3 per cent by 2050, in other words, half of the losses in the Sectoral C&T scenarios. This difference is only due to the possibility of the sectors with higher mitigation costs buying carbon allowances from those with lower mitigation costs, leading to an efficient outcome. Given the complexities involved in setting up and implementing a cap-and-trade program, these results show the importance of planning institutions and instruments well in advance in order to guarantee future emissions reductions at a lower total economic cost to the country.

3.4 Sectoral and economy-wide carbon prices

Figure 5 shows the carbon prices achieved in each sector through the Sectoral C&Ts and the carbon price negotiated in the overall economy in the Economy-wide scenario in four different years (2025, 2030, 2040 and 2050). As sectors have different mitigation opportunities and capacities to substitute between energy sources and technologies, those with higher costs will face higher prices. This is the case of the services sector, which produces low levels of emissions but does not have many alternative energy sources or low-carbon technologies available; any reductions in emissions impose big challenges to the sector. Ambitious emissions reductions for the services sector are only possible at very high prices, reaching US$370/ton of CO2 eq by 2050.

Source: Model results.

Figure 5. Sectoral and economy-wide carbon prices (2025, 2030, 2040, and 2050)

The agricultural sector can cheaply cut emissions until 2030 (under US$2/ton of CO2 eq), not only through reduced deforestation, but also via abatement opportunities from better management and input use that lead to lower CH4 and N2O emissions from livestock, waste, and fertilizer application. In a longer timeframe the costs for this sector rise to US$354/ton of CO2 eq (in 2050), reflecting the exhaustion of these opportunities.

The carbon price in the Economy-wide scenario is remarkably low when compared to those of most economic sectors (in Sectoral C&Ts), reaching only US$3/ton of CO2 eq by 2030 and rising to US$103/ton of CO2 eq by 2050. These numbers highlight the existence of cheap mitigation opportunities for the Brazilian economy until 2030. However, they also show how these opportunities are all taken by 2050. These results reinforce the conclusion that future mitigation policies need to be designed early and to take into consideration the lowest overall impact on economic efficiency, for instance by involving all economic sectors under a single instrument.

We can compare our results to a few others found in the literature, although none of the other studies have simulated and compared full NDC implementation and carbon pricing in Brazil. There are other differences in models, baseline trajectories and policy assumptions. Gurgel and Paltsev (Reference Gurgel and Paltsev2014) is the closest; they used an older version of the EPPA model to find 1.5 per cent of GDP loss in Brazil to achieve 38 per cent emissions reductions in 2020 at a price of US$50/ton of CO2 eq. Their baseline scenario does not assume any deforestation control at all, generating much higher emissions in the baseline and imposing stricter mitigation efforts on other sectors in 2020. We achieve similar carbon price and GDP losses in our Sectoral C&Ts scenarios in 2035, which, in fact, shows mitigation efforts from industrial and agricultural sectors similar to those simulated by them. Lefèvre et al. (Reference Lefèvre, Wills and Hourcade2018) found similar GDP impacts in 2030 from mitigation efforts and efficiency measures in the energy system, but they did not consider mitigation in land-use change and the agricultural sector.

4. Conclusion

The goal of this paper was to investigate the emissions trajectories and economic impacts stemming from different climate policy scenarios in Brazil. We simulate those mitigation strategies proposed by the country under the Paris Agreement in its NDC as well as other scenarios, even going beyond 2030. The Brazilian NDC targets emissions reductions by stopping deforestation, increasing the adoption of low-carbon practices in agriculture, improving energy efficiency and expanding the share of renewable sources (such as biomass, wind, solar and hydropower) in the energy mix.

We model most of these through incentives (subsidies) to increase supply, but also as taxes on emissions from deforestation. We also implement alternative scenarios with carbon pricing (cap-and-trade) mechanisms both separately for each sector (Sectoral C&Ts, forcing every sector to reduce emissions by the same percentage) and for the whole economy (Economy-wide C&T). Both alternative scenarios are set to achieve the country's overall emissions target under the Paris Agreement.

The strategies contained in the Brazilian NDC bring the country close to achieving its target for 2030; difficulties in measuring emissions reductions and carbon sequestration in the agricultural sector and in expanding the share of renewable energy sources are the main factors hindering full achievement. Further efforts to reduce emissions beyond 2030 would require changes in the country's climate policies, since all potential reductions from deforestation and renewable energy would be finished.

The economic costs of the Brazilian NDC are relatively small until 2030: a 0.7 per cent decrease in GDP relative to a BAU scenario. However, the same emissions target may be achieved with less than 0.2 per cent decrease in GDP if a cap-and-trade system is adopted. The carbon price to be paid under a national cap-and-trade scheme will be as low as US$3 per ton of carbon equivalent in 2030, but can reach U$103 per ton in 2050 if Brazil pursues additional emissions reductions.

If sectoral cap-and-trade systems are applied to make each economic sector reduce emissions by the same ratio, carbon prices may vary from US$0.5 to US$60 per ton by 2030, and from US$25 to US$370 per ton by 2050. These results show the potential of relatively cheap emissions reductions from land-use changes and agriculture in the short run, but the need for a quick turn in climate policies towards some broad-based carbon pricing system in order to avoid high costs to society.

Such an analysis, encompassing all emissions sources, is unique for Brazil and provides valuable insights concerning the likelihood that the country will adopt the necessary measures to fulfill its international commitments. Although the adoption of an economy-wide cap-and-trade system greatly reduces the economic costs associated with emissions reductions, it may also require more political bargaining and increase the transaction costs related to monitoring GHG emissions from different sources and activities. In this sense, a sensible strategy for Brazil would be to establish the necessary institutions to operate such a carbon-pricing instrument, while it reduces emissions cheaply from deforestation and agriculture.

Author ORCIDs

Gustavo Velloso Breviglieri 0000-0001-7268-8770.

Acknowledgements

This research was supported in part by the National Council for Scientific and Technological Development (CNPq) of Brazil. The MIT Economic Projection and Policy Analysis (EPPA) model used in this study is supported by a consortium of governments, industry, and foundations, sponsors of the MIT Joint Program on the Science and Policy of Global Change. For a list, see: http://globalchange.mit.edu/sponsors/all.

Footnotes

1 The Agreement was the main outcome from the 21st Conference of the Parties under the United Nations Framework Convention on Climate Change (UNFCCC), held in Paris in 2015.

2 Paltsev et al. (Reference Paltsev, Reilly, Jacoby, Eckaus, McFarland, Sarofim, Asadoorian and Babiker2005) present a detailed description of the EPPA model in its previous versions.

3 Chen et al. (Reference Chen, Paltsev, Reilly, Morris, Karplus, Gurgel, Winchester, Kishimoto, Blanc and Babiker2017: 23) provide a list relating gases, emissions sources and activities within EPPA for all GHGs.

4 Backstop technologies are not explicitly represented in the GTAP data, since they are not largely deployed in the base year. Generally, the output of a backstop technology sector is a perfect substitute for the output of an existing sector. Cost differences between energy produced from the backstop and the conventional technology are captured by a markup factor. Actual relative costs of the conventional and alternative technologies after the base year are determined endogenously as the costs of inputs change.

5 The nest structure for the other sectors in EPPA can be found in Paltsev et al. (Reference Paltsev, Reilly, Jacoby, Eckaus, McFarland, Sarofim, Asadoorian and Babiker2005).

6 The non-malleable fraction of capital is specific to each sector and used in fixed proportions to other inputs. It represents short-run rigidity in technology and fixed investments, particularly important in the case of energy suppliers (electric power plants) that can only make a few changes in their capacities-and-inputs mix once their operations start.

7 Such a tax remains purely theoretical, although it also may be seen as a fine, a monetary penalty or levy on the agents. Brazil currently adopts command-and-control policies to curb illegal deforestation.

8 From a theoretical standpoint, cap-and-trade systems and carbon taxes are equivalent. Stavins (Reference Stavins1996) explores the uncertainty conditions in which these instruments differ.

9 Brazil's Third National Communication to the UNFCCC (Brazil, 2016) improved its methodology regarding land-use change emissions. This most recent inventory shows total emissions in 2005 at 2.73 billion tons of CO2 eq. In the Second Communication, total emissions reached 2.04 billion tons of CO2 eq (MCTI, 2014). Brazilian NDCs were defined as cuts in total emissions, as declared in the Second Communication. We understand that the absolute level of total emissions in 2025 and 2030 should be those related to the commitments under the Paris Agreement.

10 GHG emissions data for 2005, 2011 and 2012 in figure 3 are from Brazil's Second National Emissions Inventory, published by MCTI (2014).

References

Arrow, KJ and Debreu, G (1954) Existence of an equilibrium for a competitive economy. Econometrica 22, 265290.Google Scholar
Brazil (2008) Plano Nacional Sobre Mudança do Clima – PNMC. Brasília: Comitê Interministerial Sobre Mudança do Clima, Governo Federal (in Portuguese).Google Scholar
Brazil (2016) Third National Communication of Brazil to the United Nations Framework Convention on Climate Change – Volume III. Brasília: Ministry of Science, Technology and Innovation.Google Scholar
Brooke, A, Kendrick, D, Meeraus, A and Raman, R (1988) GAMS: A User's Guide. Washington, DC: GAMS Development Corporation.Google Scholar
Carvalho, TS, Domingues, EP and Horridge, JM (2017) Controlling deforestation in the Brazilian Amazon: regional economic impacts and land-use change. Land Use Policy 64, 327341.Google Scholar
Chen, YHH, Paltsev, S, Reilly, J, Morris, J, Karplus, V, Gurgel, A, Winchester, N, Kishimoto, P, Blanc, E and Babiker, M (2017) The MIT Economic Projection and Policy Analysis (EPPA) Model: Version 5. Cambridge, MA: Massachusetts Institute of Technology.Google Scholar
Dimaranan, B and Mcdougall, R (2002) Global Trade, Assistance, and Production: The GTAP5 Data Base. West Lafayette: Center for Global Trade Analysis.Google Scholar
EMCB (2010) Economia da Mudança do Clima no Brasil: Custos e Oportunidades. São Paulo: IBEP Gráfica (in Portuguese).Google Scholar
EPE (2010) Balanço Energético Nacional 2010: Ano Base 2009. Rio de Janeiro: Empresa de Pesquisa Energética (in Portuguese).Google Scholar
EPE (2011) Balanço Energético Nacional 2011: Ano Base 2010. Rio de Janeiro: Empresa de Pesquisa Energética (in Portuguese).Google Scholar
EPE (2012) Balanço Energético Nacional 2012: Ano Base 2011. Rio de Janeiro: Empresa de Pesquisa Energética (in Portuguese).Google Scholar
Feijó, FT and Porto, S Jr. (2009) Protocolo de quioto e o bem estar econômico no Brasil uma análise utilizando equilíbrio geral computável. Análise Econômica 51, 127154 (in Portuguese).Google Scholar
Ferreira Filho, JBS and Moraes, GI (2015) Climate change, agriculture and economic effects on different regions of Brazil. Environment and Development Economics 20, 3756.Google Scholar
Ferreira Filho, JBS and Rocha, MT (2008) Economic evaluation of public policies aiming the reduction of greenhouse gas emissions in Brazil. Journal of Economic Integration 23, 709733.Google Scholar
Gurgel, AC and Paltsev, S (2014) Costs of reducing GHG emissions in Brazil. Climate Policy 14, 209223.Google Scholar
Gurgel, A, Reilly, JM and Paltsev, S (2007) Potential land use implications of a global biofuels industry. Journal of Agricultural & Food Industrial Organization 5, article 9.Google Scholar
Hochstetler, K and Viola, E (2012) Brazil and the politics of climate change: beyond the global commons. Environmental Politics 21, 753771.Google Scholar
IBGE (1995) Censo Agropecuário: 1995/96. Rio de Janeiro: Instituto Brasileiro de Geografia e Estatística – IBGE (in Portuguese).Google Scholar
IBGE (2006) Censo Agropecuário 2006. Rio de Janeiro: Instituto Brasileiro de Geografia e Estatística – IBGE (in Portuguese).Google Scholar
IEA (2011) World Energy Outlook. Paris: Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development/International Energy Agency.Google Scholar
IMF (2011) World Economic and Financial Surveys: World Economic Outlook Database. Washington, DC: International Monetary Fund.Google Scholar
Keohane, RO and Victor, DG (2016) Cooperation and discord in global climate policy. Nature Climate Change 6, 570575.Google Scholar
Kober, T, Summerton, P, Pollitt, H, Chewpreecha, U, Ren, X, Wills, W, Octaviano, C, McFarland, J, Beach, R, Cai, Y, Calderon, S, Fisher-Vanden, K and Rodriguez, AML (2016) Macroeconomic impacts of climate change mitigation in Latin America: a cross-model comparison. Energy Economics 56, 625636.Google Scholar
Kydland, F and Prescott, EC (1996). The computational experiment: an econometric tool. Journal of Economic Perspectives 10, 6985.Google Scholar
La Rovere, EL, Pereira, AS and Simões, AF (2011) Biofuels and sustainable energy development in Brazil. World Development 39, 10261036.Google Scholar
La Rovere, EL, Pereira, AO Jr., Dubeux, CBS and Wills, W (2014) Climate change mitigation actions in Brazil. Climate and Development 6, 2533.Google Scholar
LAPIG (2015) Mapa Síntese da Área de Pastagens no Brasil (Sexta Versão). Goiânia, GO: Laboratório de Processamento de Imagens e Geoprocessamento (in Portuguese).Google Scholar
Lefèvre, J, Wills, W and Hourcade, JC (2018). Combining low-carbon economic development and oil exploration in Brazil? An energy–economy assessment. Climate Policy 18, 12861295.Google Scholar
Lucena, AFP, Clarke, L, Schaeffer, R, Szklo, A, Rochedo, PRR, Nogueira, LPP, Daenzer, K, Gurgel, A, Kitous, A and Kober, T (2016) Climate policy scenarios in Brazil: a multi-model comparison for energy. Energy Economics 56, 564574.Google Scholar
Magalhães, AS and Domingues, EP (2016) Aumento da eficiência energética no Brasil: uma opção para uma economia de baixo carbono? Revista Economia Aplicada 20, 273310 (in Portuguese).Google Scholar
Magalhães, A, Carvalho, T and Domingues, E (2016) Policies for reduction of greenhouse gas emissions and their costs and opportunities for the Brazilian industry. Paper presented at the 44° Encontro Nacional de Economia, 13–16 December 2016, ANPEC, Foz do Iguaçú, PR.Google Scholar
MCTI (2014) Estimativas Anuais de Emissões de Gases de Efeito Estufa no Brasil - 2a Edição. Brasília: Ministério da Ciência, Tecnologia e Inovação – MCTI (in Portuguese).Google Scholar
Melillo, JM, Reilly, JM, Kicklighter, DW, Gurgel, AC, Cronin, TW, Paltsev, S, Felzer, BS, Wang, X, Sokolov, AP and Schlosser, CA (2009) Indirect emissions from biofuels: how important? Science 326, 13971399.Google Scholar
Narayanan, BG and Walmsley, TG (2008) Global Trade, Assistance, and Production: The GTAP 7 Data Base. West Lafayette: Center for Global Trade Analysis.Google Scholar
Octaviano, C, Paltsev, S and Gurgel, AC (2016) Climate change policy in Brazil and Mexico: results from the MIT EPPA model. Energy Economics 56, 600614.Google Scholar
Paltsev, S, Reilly, JM, Jacoby, HD, Eckaus, RS, McFarland, J, Sarofim, M, Asadoorian, M and Babiker, M (2005) The MIT Emissions Prediction and Policy Analysis (EPPA) Model: Version 4. Cambridge, MA: Massachusetts Institute of Technology.Google Scholar
Reilly, J and Fuglie, K (1998) Future yield growth in field crops: what evidence exists? Soil and Tillage Research 47, 275290.Google Scholar
Rocha, MT (2003) Aquecimento global e o mercado de carbono: uma aplicação do modelo CERT. Ph.D. thesis, Escola Superior de Agricultura Luiz de Queiroz, Universidade de São Paulo, Piracicaba, SP (in Portuguese).Google Scholar
Rutherford, TF (1995) Extensions of GAMS for complementarity problems arising in applied economic analysis. Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control 19, 12991324.Google Scholar
SEEG (2017) Sistema de Estimativas de Emissões e Remoções de Gases de Efeito Estufa. Available at http://seeg.eco.br/ (in Portuguese).Google Scholar
Shoven, JB and Whalley, JL (1984) Applied general equilibrium models of taxation and international trade: an introduction and survey. Journal of Economic Literature 22, 10071051.Google Scholar
Stavins, RN (1996) Correlated uncertainty and policy instrument choice. Journal of Environmental Economics and Management 30, 218232.Google Scholar
Tourinho, OAF, da Motta, RS and Alves, YLB (2003) Uma Aplicação Ambiental de um Modelo de Equílibrio Geral. Rio de Janeiro: IPEA (in Portuguese).Google Scholar
UN (2009) World Population Prospects: The 2008 Revision, New York: United Nations Population Division.Google Scholar
UNFCCC (2016) Federative republic of Brazil intended nationally determined contribution towards achieving the objective of the United Nations framework convention on climate change. Available at https://www4.unfccc.int/sites/ndcstaging/PublishedDocuments/Brazil%20First/BRAZIL%20iNDC%20english%20FINAL.pdf .Google Scholar
Waugh, C, Paltsev, S, Selin, N, Reilly, J, Morris, J and Sarofim, M (2011) Emission Inventory for NonCO2 Greenhouse Gases and Air Pollutants in EPPA5. Cambridge, MA: Massachusetts Institute of Technology.Google Scholar
Figure 0

Table 1. Regions, sectors and primary factors in the EPPA model

Figure 1

Table 2. Elasticities of substitution in production sectors in the EPPA model

Figure 2

Figure 1. Structure of agricultural production sectors

Source: Paltsev et al. (2005).
Figure 3

Figure 2. Structure of final demand in EPPA

Source: Paltsev et al. (2005).
Figure 4

Table 3. Elasticities of substitution in consumption in the EPPA model

Figure 5

Table 4. Scenarios simulated

Figure 6

Figure 3. GHG emissions in Brazil. *Emissions targets under the Paris Agreement

Sources: MCTI (2014)10, SEEG (2017) and EPPA results.
Figure 7

Figure 4. Cumulative land-use changes in the BAU scenario compared to 2015

Source: Model results.
Figure 8

Table 5. GHG emissions in Brazil in the alternative scenarios (% of BAU emissions)

Figure 9

Table 6. Changes in GDP (%) relative to BAU

Figure 10

Figure 5. Sectoral and economy-wide carbon prices (2025, 2030, 2040, and 2050)

Source: Model results.