Hostname: page-component-586b7cd67f-t8hqh Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-11-22T04:16:41.010Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Rationality and social norms

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  28 July 2009

Get access

Extract

One of the most persisting cleavages in the social sciences is the opposition between two lines of thought conveniently associated with Adam Smith and Émile Durkheim, between homo economicus and homo sociologicus. Of these, the former is supposed to be guided by instrumental rationality, while the behavior of the latter is dictated by social norms. The former is ‘pulled’ by the prospect of future rewards, whereas the latter is ‘pushed’ from behind by quasi-inertial forces (Gambetta 1987). The former adapts to changing circumstances, always on the lookout for improvements. The latter is insensitive to circumstances, adhering to the prescribed behavior even if new and apparently better options become available. The former is easily caricatured as a self-contained, asocial atom, and the latter as the mindless plaything of social forces. In this paper I characterize this contrast more fully, and discuss attempts to reduce norm-oriented action to some type of optimizing behavior.

Type
The puzzling scope of rationality
Copyright
Copyright © Archives Européenes de Sociology 1991

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

References

Abreu, D., 1988, On the theory of infinitely repeated games with discounting, Econometrica, LVI, 383396.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ainslie, G., 1982, A behavioral economic approach to the defense mechanisms; Freud's energy theory revisited, Social Science Informotion, XXI, 735779.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ainslie, G., 1984, Behavioral economics II: motivated involuntary behavior, Social Science Information, XXIII, 247274.Google Scholar
Ainslie, G., 1986, Beyond microeconomics, in Elster, J. (ed.), The Multiple Self, pp. 133176 (Cambridge, Cambridge University Press).Google Scholar
Akerlof, G., 1976, The economics of caste and of the rat race and other woeful tales, Quarterly Journal of Economics, XC, 599617.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Akerlof, G., 1980, A theory of social custom, of which unemployment may be one consequence, Quarterly Journal of Economics, XCIV, 749775.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Arrow, K., 1971, Political and economic evaluation of social effects and externalities, in Intriligator, M. (ed.), Frontiers of Quantitative Economics, pp. 325 (Amsterdam, North-Holland).Google Scholar
Axelrod, R., 1986, An evolutionary approach to norms, American Political Science Review, LXXX, 10951111.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Banfield, E. G., 1958, The Moral Basis of a Backward Society (New York, The Free Press).Google Scholar
Barry, B., 1979, Sociologists, Economists and Democracy2 (Chicago, University of Chicago Press).Google Scholar
Boehm, C., 1984, Blood Revenge. The anthropology of feuding in Montenegro and other tribal societies (Lawrence, University of Kansas Press).Google Scholar
Bourdieu, P., 1966, The sentiment of honour in Kabyle society, in Peristiany, J. G. (ed.), Honour and Shame: The values of Mediterranean society (Chicago, University of Chicago Press).Google Scholar
Bourdieu, P., 1979, La Distinction (Paris, Édition de Minuit).Google Scholar
Bryson, F. R., 1935, The Point of Honor in Sixteenth-Century Italy (New York, Publications of the Institute of French Studies, Columbia University).Google Scholar
Coleman, J. S., 1990, Foundations of Social Theory (Cambridge, Mass., Harvard University Press).Google Scholar
Czwartosz, Z., 1988, On queuing, Archives européennes de sociologie, XXIX, 311.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Deutsch, M., 1985, Distributive Justice (New Haven, Yale University Press).Google Scholar
Djilas, M., 1958, Land without Justice (London, Methuen).Google Scholar
Durkheim, É., 1958, The Rules of Sociological Method (Glencoe, Ill., The Free Press).Google Scholar
Edgerton, R., 1985, Rules, Exceptions and the social order (Berkeley, University of California Press).CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Elster, J., 1983, Sour Grapes (Cambridge, Cambridge University Press).CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Elster, J., 1986, Editorial Introduction to Rational Choice (Oxford, Blackwell).Google Scholar
Elster, J., 1988, Is there (or should there be) a right to work? in Guttman, A. (ed.), Democracy and the welfare state (Princeton, Princeton University Press).Google Scholar
Elster, J., 1989a, The Cement of Society (Cambridge, Cambridge University Press).CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Elster, J., 1989b, Solomonic Judgements (Cambridge, Cambridge University Press).Google Scholar
Elster, J., 1990, Norms of revenge, Ethics, C, 862885.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Engel, H., 1986, A City Called July (New York, Penguin Books).Google Scholar
Faia, M., 1986, Dynamic Functionalism (Cambridge, Cambridge University Press).CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Fenichel, O., 1945, The Psychoanalytic Theory of Neurosis (New York, Norton).Google Scholar
Gambetta, D., 1987, Did They Jump or Were they Pushed? (Cambridge, Cambridge University Press).CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Gouldner, A., 1960, The norm of reciprocity, American Sociological Review, XXV, 161178.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hume, D., 1751, An Enquiry Concerning the Principles of Morals.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kahn, A., Lamm, H. and Nelson, R., 1977, Preferences for an equal or equitable allocator, Journal of Personality and Social Psychology, XXXV, 837844.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kahneman, D., Knetsch, J. and Thaler, R., 1986, Fairness and the assumptions of economics, Journal of Business, LIX, S285S300.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kalai, E. and Smorodinsky, M., 1975, Other solutions to Nash's bargaining problem, Econometrica, XLIII, 513518.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kurtz, E., 1979, Not-God: A history of Alcoholics Anonymous (Center City, Minnesota, Hazelden Educational Services).Google Scholar
Laurin, U., 1986, På Heder och Samvete (Stockholm, Norstedts).Google Scholar
Lindbeck, A. and Snower, D. J., 1986, Wage rigidity, union activity and unemployment, in Beckerman, W. (ed.), Wage Rigidity and Unemployment, pp. 97126 (London, Duckworth).Google Scholar
Lindbeck, A. and Snower, D. J., 1988, Cooperation, harassment and involuntary unemployment, American Economic Review, LXXVIII, 167188.Google Scholar
McDonald, I. M. and Solow, R., 1981, Wage bargaining and employment, American Economic Review, LXXI, 896908.Google Scholar
Messick, D. M. and Sentis, K., 1983, Fairness, preference, and fairness biases, in Messick, D. M. and Cook, K. (eds), Equity Theory, pp. 6194 (New York, Praeger).Google Scholar
Mikula, G., 1972, Gewinnaufteilung in Dyaden bei variiertem Leistungsverhältnis, Zeitschrift für Sozialpsychologie, III, 126133.Google Scholar
Nash, J., 1950, The bargaining problem, Econometrica, XVIII, 155162.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
North, D., 1981, Structure and Change in Economic History (New York, Norton).Google Scholar
Okun, A., 1981, Prices and Quantities (Washington, D.C., The Brookings Institution).Google Scholar
Pileggi, N., 1986, Wiseguy (New York, Pocket Books).Google Scholar
Roethlisberger, F. J. and Dickson, W. J., 1939, Management and the Worker (Cambridge, Mass., Harvard University Press).Google Scholar
Rubinstein, A., 1982, Perfect equilibrium in a bargaining model, Econometrica, L, 97109.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Sandemose, A., 1936, A Fugitive Crosses his Track (New York, Knopf).Google Scholar
Thaler, R., 1980, Towards a positive theory of consumer behavior, Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization, I, 3960.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Thomas, K., 1973, Religion and the Decline of Magic (Harmondsworth, Penguin).Google Scholar
Tocqueville, A. de, 1969, Democracy in America (New York, Anchor Books).Google Scholar
Tumin, M., 1957, Some unapplauded consequences of social mobility, Social Forces, XV, 3237.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ullmann-Margalit, E., 1977, The Emergence of Norms (Oxford, Oxford University Press).Google Scholar
Veyne, P., 1976, Le Pain et le cirque (Paris, Éditions du Seuil).CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Waller, W., 1937, The rating and dating complex, American Sociological Review, II, 727734.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Williamson, O., 1985, The Economic Institutions of Capitalism (New York, The Free Press).Google Scholar
Yaari, M. and Bar-Hillel, M., 1988, Judgments of justice (Unpublished manuscript).Google Scholar
Zajac, E. P., 1985, Perceived economic justice: the example of public utility regulation, in Young, H. P. (ed.), Cost Allocation, pp. 119153 (Amsterdam, North-Holland).Google Scholar