Hostname: page-component-586b7cd67f-vdxz6 Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-11-22T06:55:19.408Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

The Rise and Fall of Enforcement Institutions: An Example of Religion and Secularism

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  30 March 2012

Pavel Ciaian
Affiliation:
European Commission, DG Joint Research Centre, Edificio Expo, C/Inca Garcilaso 3, 41092 – Seville, Spain
Ján Pokrivčák
Affiliation:
Department of Economics, Slovenská Pol'nohospodárska Univerzita, Tr. A. Hlinku 2, 94901 Nitra, Slovakia
D'Artis Kancs
Affiliation:
European Commission, DG Joint Research Centre, Edificio Expo, C/Inca Garcilaso 3, 41092 – Seville, Spain. Email: d'artis.kancs@ec.europa.eu

Abstract

Societies in Western civilisation enforce their rules through formal secular institutions (SES), whereas less developed civilisations often rely on informal, often religious, institutions (RES). The present paper attempts to explain the determinants of societies’ choice between different enforcement systems, and their implications for society development using an example of two different enforcement models: one informal (RES) and one formal (SES). We find that, because the RES is based on beliefs, its efficiency depends heavily on its credibility, making it hardly flexible and highly susceptible to conflicts in dynamic environments. In contrast, because under the SES societal rules are enforced through a formal legal enforcement sector, the SES is more flexible, although also more costly than the RES. The empirical evidence strongly supports our findings that wealthy, dynamic and fast growing economies typically choose the SES for enforcing societal norms and rules.

Type
Focus: Knowledge Management in Contemporary Europe
Copyright
Copyright © Academia Europaea 2012

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

References

References and Notes

1.North, D. (1990) Institutions, Institutional Change and Economic Performance (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press).Google Scholar
2.Redmond, W.H. (2005) A framework for the analysis of stability and change in formal institutions. Journal of Economic Issues, 39, pp. 665681.Google Scholar
3. The religion does not only serve as an enforcement system to impose behaviour norms and rules but also provides other benefits to the society. The religion encompasses concepts such as morality, the existence of sacred objects and rituals, the sense of the existence, personal belonging, divine devotion and sacrifice, religious sentiments, social adherence, etc. These, however, are beyond the scope of the present paper.Google Scholar
4. We do not consider a particular type of RES or SES. Instead, we consider the key stylised concepts of these two enforcement frameworks and investigate their determinants and implication for the development of societies.Google Scholar
5.Chaves, M. (1994) Secularization as declining religious authority. Social Forces, 72(3), pp. 749774.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
6.Kingston, C. and Caballero, G. (2009) Comparing theories of institutional change. Journal of Institutional Economics, 5(2), 151180.Google Scholar
7.Alchian, A. (1950) Uncertainty, evolution and economic theory. Journal of Political Economy, 58(3), 211221.Google Scholar
8.Libecap, G.D. (1989) Contracting for Property Rights (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press).Google Scholar
9.Ostrom, E. (2005) Understanding Institutional Diversity (Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press).Google Scholar
10. A further development in the institutional choice literature is the ‘Equilibrium View’ theory, which considers a more comprehensive treatment of institutional choice by considering the formal and informal enforcement forms within a unified framework – see Aoki, M. (2001) Towards a Comparative Institutional Analysis (Cambridge, MA: MIT Press); R. Calvert (1995) Rational actors, equilibrium and social institutions. In J. Knight and I. Sened (eds) Explaining Social Institutions (Ann Arbor, MI: University of Michigan Press), pp. 57–94; A. Greif (2006) Institutions and the Path to the Modern Economy (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press); A. Greif and D. Laitin (2004) A theory of endogenous institutional change. American Political Science Review, 98(4), 633–652; R. Myerson (2004) Justice, institutions, and multiple equilibria. Chicago Journal of International Law, 5, 91–107; A. Schotter (1981) The Economic Theory of Social Institutions (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press). This strand of literature argues that interactions between all constraints that individuals face (e.g. institutional and exogenous constraints) coordinates individuals to one of the multitude of possible equilibria by achieving a shared set of expectation about each other's behaviour. According to the Equilibrium View, the enforcement system change becomes fundamentally not about changing rules, but about changing expectations. The enforcement system change may emerge as a reaction to changing institutions and/or exogenous constraints by affecting people's expectations. A rule that fails to shift people's expectations in the desired way may not lead to enforcement system adjustment. Both the TCE and the CC theories are compatible with the Equilibrium View – see C. Kingston and G. Caballero (2009) Comparing theories of institutional change. Journal of Institutional Economics, 5(2), 151–180.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
11. For example, Islam regulates all main areas of social and economic life. This is embodied in the Muslim norms known as Shariah law. Shariah law consists of the Koran and the teachings/statements and preaching of the prophet Mohamed. Shariah law includes a set of lows and rules that an Islamic society is required to obey. Shariah law regulates religious matters, family issues, business activities, trade, property rights, inheritance, state administration, state defence, etc. Shariah law does not provide legal power to men to design new laws and regulation. The laws are considered sacred. It is believed that God transmitted them to men through the prophet Mohamed. For this reason the laws are considered ultimate. limiting the possibility for them to be changed or adjusted. In principle, God represents the only authority having legal powers, see Choudhury, M.A. (1989) The blending of religious and social orders in Islam. International Journal of Social Economics, 16(2), pp. 1345; B. Lewis (1995) The Middle East: 2000 Years of History from the Rise of Christianity to the Present Day (London: Phoenix).Google Scholar
12. For more about sanctions and rewards systems in different religions see McCleary, R.M. (2007) Salvation, damnation, and economic incentives. Journal of Contemporary Religion, 22(1), pp. 4974.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
13. One way of the norm's adjustment may occur through changing interpretation of scriptures (not examined in this paper). Religious norms are usually rules that are developed over a long period of time and, in most cases, their recording is very inconsistent. Their transmission through generations and among individuals is usually done orally or through informal methods. In such conditions, their interpretation may change over time and may differ between regions and groups reflecting preferences, background, history and environment. However, this interpretation driven rule-adjustment will tend to occur over a medium-long period.Google Scholar
14. For example, religions are often against the scientific explanation of the development of the Universe; alternative ways of the family organisation; divorce; adoption of scientific discoveries in every-day life; acceptance of other religions; and so on.Google Scholar
15. Note that this also explains why religions in general follow a policy of absolute rejection of other religions. If accepting the norms of other religions, it would reduce their credibility and thus the intensity of beliefs. In the same line of arguments, it follows the explanation of why a split within an existing religion (e.g. the split of the Protestant denomination form of the Roman Catholic Church in the sixteenth century) is usually accompanied by a mutual and absolute refusal of the new denominations.Google Scholar
16. Expressed in mathematical language, the indirect adjustment cost function in RES reaches higher values and has a steeper slope than the SES function. For a given additional gain from the rule adjustment, in equilibrium the RES will adjust less than the SES.Google Scholar
17. An example of a stable society includes ancient agrarian societies.Google Scholar
18. In general, exogenous shocks in the environment associated with more knowledge and/or better technology can increase the enforcement efficiency of the SES for two reasons. First, the efficiency can be increased, because dishonest individuals could be detected easier when new technologies and innovations become available (e.g. communication, transportation). Second, the technology-induced growth may create additional resources to invest in the improvement of the legal enforcement sector.Google Scholar
19. For example, because of high transportation costs.Google Scholar
20.Finley, M.I. (1973) The Ancient Economy (Berkley and Los Angeles: University of California Press).Google Scholar
21.Al Azm, S.J. (2007) Islam and the science-religion debates in modern-times. European Review, 15(3), pp. 283295.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
22.Dahrendorf, R. (1959) Class and Class Conflict in Industrial Society (Palo Alto: Stanford University Press).Google Scholar
23.Platteau, J.P. (2008) Religion, politics, and development: lessons from the lands of Islam. Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization, 68, 329351.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
24.Smith, C. (ed.) (2003) The Secular Revolution: Power, Interests, and Conflict in the Secularization of American Public Life (Berkeley and Los Angeles: University of California).CrossRefGoogle Scholar
25.Dobbelaere, K. (2002) Secularization: An Analysis at Three Levels (Bruxelles: P.I.E.-Peter Lang).Google Scholar
26. This is in line with the secularisation hypothesis of the social theory claiming that economic development reduces the religiosity of the society causing individuals to become less religious. The secularisation hypothesis also encompasses the idea that economic development causes organised religion to play a smaller role in political decision-making and in social and legal enforcement – see P.L. Berger (1967) The Sacred Canopy: Elements of a Sociological Theory of Religion (Garden City, NJ: Doubleday); M. Chaves (1994) Secularization as declining religious authority. Social Forces, 72(3), pp. 749–774; D. Martin (1978) A General Theory of Secularization (Oxford: Basil Blackwell); B. Wilson (1966) Religion in Secular Society: A Sociological Comment (London: Watts). Another strand of the same theory stresses the importance of reverse causality, whereby religion is an important factor influencing development by affecting personal traits such as honesty and the work ethic, which favours rule enforcement, see S.P. Huntington (1996) The Clash of Civilizations and the Remaking of World Order (New York: Simon and Schuster); D.S. Landes (1999) The Wealth and Poverty of Nations: Why Some Are So Rich and Some So Poor (New York: Norton); Weber, M. (1930) The Protestant Ethic and the Spirit of Capitalism (London: Allen and Unwin).Google Scholar
27. For example, see the recent work of Platteau, J.P. (2008) Religion, politics, and development: lessons from the lands of Islam. Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization, 68, 329351, who argues that institutional improvement is very hard to be implemented in the Islamic regions because of the particularities of the institutional organisation of Islam. Platteau attributes this to the absence of a religious hierarchy able to impose an Islamic orthodoxy that leaves room for rather ample margin of interpretation of the Islamic norms. This is based on the idea that as soon as any reformist group emerges it could always be opposed from an alternative group and both groups could legitimise their actions in the Koran.Google Scholar
28.Acemoglu, D. (2003) Why not a political Coase theorem? Social conflict, commitment, and politics. Journal of Comparative Economics, 31(4), pp. 620652.Google Scholar
29. This depends on the belief structure of the RES; e.g. if the RES norms require that all peoples’ actions must be sanctioned by the supernatural power, then the RES coexistence with the SES will be likely associated with strong tensions and may lead to conflicts. Only a reformed denomination of this religion may coexist with the SES.Google Scholar
30. We use the term ‘trade’ in a broader sense to denote different types of intra- and inter-societal interactions.Google Scholar
31. Note that in the absence of technological development but with inter-societal interactions a similar effect as in the case of technological development and autarky may emerge. This will occur when the development level is heterogeneous between societies, whereby technological spill-over will take place from the more developed society to the laggard society.Google Scholar
32.Campbell, J.L. (2004) Institutional Change and Globalization (Princeton and Oxford: Princeton University Press).Google Scholar
33.Streeck, S. (2007) Globalization: nothing new under the sun? Socio-Economic Review, 5(3), 537547.Google Scholar
34. Note that we do not argue that religion will totally disappear. Instead, our findings suggest that it will retreat from providing enforcement services to societies. However, the religion still may be important in providing other benefits to individuals such as spiritual ones.Google Scholar
35.Abanes, R. (1996) American Militias: Rebellion, Racism & Religion (Downers Grove, IL: Intervarsity Press).Google Scholar
36.Jurgensmeyer, M. (2000) Terror in the Mind of God: The Global Rise of Religious Violence (Berkeley: University of California Press).Google Scholar
37.Huntington, S.P. (1996) The Clash of Civilizations and the Remaking of World Order (New York: Simon and Schuster).Google Scholar
38.P.W. Barker and W.J. Muck (2004) Holy War for the 21st Century: Globalization, U.S. Foreign Policy, and the Development of Islamic Identity. Paper presented at the Annual Meeting of the Midwest Political Science Association, Palmer House Hilton, Chicago, Illinois, April 15, 2004.Google Scholar
39.Jenkins, P. (2002) The Next Christendom: The Coming of Global Christianity (New York: Oxford University Press).CrossRefGoogle Scholar
40.Johnson, T., Nichiporuk, B. and Jenkins, P. (2005) The Coming Religious Wars? Demographics and Conflict in Islam and Christianity (Washington, DC: Pew Research Center).Google Scholar
41. The Muslim population is rapidly growing due to high fertility rates in the Middle East, North Africa, and Central and Southeast Asia, yielding ‘youth bulges’ with potential strong consequences on the current world equilibrium structure. Christianity is moving south, expanding demographically in the developing world and augmenting ongoing socio-political turmoil in places such as West Africa, see Johnson, T., Nichiporuk, B. and Jenkins, P. (2005) The Coming Religious Wars? Demographics and Conflict in Islam and Christianity (Washington, DC: Pew Research Center).Google Scholar