Hostname: page-component-78c5997874-mlc7c Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-11-06T11:17:30.612Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Penalty Clauses In England And France: A Comparative Study

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  17 January 2008

Extract

The study of penalty clauses1 is a rewarding area of comparative research. The most cursory of examinations reveals the diametrically opposed theoretical positions of contemporary legal orthodoxy in France and England. Asearch for the rationale behind this theoretical divergence gives insight not only into the broader conceptual and substantive differences between the two jurisdictions, but, importantly, their many similarities as well.

Type
Articles
Copyright
Copyright © British Institute of International and Comparative Law 2004

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

References

1 The term is problematic in a comparative study. In England it specifically refers to an invalid agreed damages clause. A valid clause is referred to as a liquidated damages clause. In France, the term clause pénale encapsulates both English notions. Unless obvious from the context, the term ‘penalty clauses’ will connote both valid and invalid agreed damages clauses as well as the French clause pénale.Google Scholar

2 One French author considers the penalty clauserules a precursor for general contractual developments representing ‘une image assez exacte des modifications qui ont affecté le droit contractuel’. Mazeaud, D, La Notion de Clause Pénale (LGDJ 1992) at 31. It is a comment equally valid in England.Google Scholar

3 See Ibbetson, DAn Historical Introduction to the Law of Obligations (OxfordOxford University Press 1999) 249 who outlines how the incursion into the Will Theory from competing socio-economic, philosophical and legal theories created a suitable climate for more active judicial control of unconscionable behaviour of contracting parties. Whilst at first this did not amount to a wholesale renouncement of the Will Theory, it was recognition that contracts could be more extensively regulated by principles of reasonableness and justice. By the later part of the twentieth century, the Will Theory had been ‘seriously compromised’ (at 261).Google Scholar

4 It will be seen below that in England, unlike in France, even at the height of the enlightenment, penalty clauses were treated with suspicion. Intervention however was restrained by strict delimitation of what was classified as a penalty clause. A clause was only treated as penal if it could not have represented the parties' intentions. See Ibbetson, op cit at 255.Google Scholar

5 This, at least, is the traditional language used. The significance of the term is explored below.

6 It should be noted that the common law has not always been distrustful of penalties. The penal bond with conditional defeasance was a much used instrument until the mid-seventeenth century. A full account can be found in AWB Simpson ‘The Penal Bond with Conditional Defeasance’ [1966] 92 LQR 392.Google Scholar

7 Tai Hing cotton Mill v Kamsing Knitting Factory [1979] AC 95, at 105.Google Scholar

8 Export Credits Guarantee Department v Universal Oil Products [1983] 2 Lloyd's Rep 152, at 155.Google Scholar

9 ‘[T]he distinction between penalties and liquidated damages depends on the intention of the parties to be gathered from the whole of the contract’Law v Redditch Local Board [1892] 1 QB 127, at 132.Google Scholar

10 See, eg, Kemble v Farren (1829) 6 Bing 141 where a clause described as a ‘liquidated damages clause’ was held to be a penalty clause and, for the reverse, see Elphinstone v Monkland Iron & Coal Co Ltd (1886) 11 App Cas 332.Google Scholar

11 Dunlop Pneumatic Tyre Co Ltd v New Garage & Motor Co Ltd [1915] AC 79, at 87.Google Scholar

12 Above n 11.

13 At 87–8.Google Scholar

14 Butterworths Common Law Series The Law of Contracts (LondonButterworths 1999) 1303.Google Scholar

15 Treitel, GThe Law of Contracts (LondonSweet & Maxwell 1999) 930.Google Scholar

16 (1882) 21 Ch D 243.Google Scholar

17 See Treitel above n 15, at 931; Butterworths, above n 14, at 1304.Google Scholar

18 Above n 15, at 93.

19 Philips Hong Kong v A-G of Hong Kong (1993) 61 Build LR 41, at 59.Google Scholar

20 Dunlop, at 88. This seems in contradiction with the third rule.Google Scholar

21 The difficulty with the common law distinction is evidenced in the contradictory cases of Dunlop and Ford Motor Co v Armstrong (1915) 31 TLR267.Google Scholar

22 Bridge v Campbell Discount Co Ltd [1962] AC 600, at 622.Google Scholar

23 See on this Barton ‘Penalties and Damages’ [1976] 92 LQR 26; Gordon [1974] 90 LQR 296; Hudson ‘Penalties Limiting Damages’ [1974] 90 LQR 30.Google Scholar

24 [1915] 3 K B 66.Google Scholar

25 Cellulose Acetate Silk Co Ltd v Widnes Foundry (1925) Ltd. [1933] AC 20.Google Scholar

26 Robophone Facilities Ltd v Blank [1966] 3 All ER129, at 142.Google Scholar

27 Elsley v JG Collins Ins Agencies Ltd (1978) 83 DLR (3d) 1.Google Scholar

28 Perhaps a simplified way of looking at this would be to ask whether the same clause can be recognised as pursuing multifarious purposes; eg coercion, compensation and limitation. If so, a refusal to enforce a penalty clause could be viewed as ignoring one characteristic of the particular clause (viz coercion) whilst leaving another (viz limitation) to be enforced. The traditional common law separation of a penalty from a liquidated damages clause tends to hinder this process of analysis since it presupposes that the clause has either one function or another. Jobson v Johnson [1989] 1 WLR 1026 (discussed in detail below) represents a move towards viewing the same clause as having an amalgam of functions.Google Scholar

29 See Hudson, above n 23.Google Scholar

30 Above n 28.Google Scholar

31 Zimmermann, R The Law of Obligations. Roman Foundations of the Civilian Traditions (Cape TownJuta & Co 1990), at 107.Google Scholar

32 Treitel, above n 15, at 929.Google Scholar

33 Mckendrick, EContract Law (LondonPalgrave 2000), at 430; Butterworths, above n 14, at 1295; and Clarkson et al ‘Liquidated Damages v Penalties: Sense or Nonsense’ [1978] Wise LR 351, at 351.Google Scholar

34 Collins, HThe Law of Contract (LondonButterworths 1997), at 347.Google Scholar

35 Harris, ‘Incentives to Perform or Break Contracts’ (1992) 45 CLP 29, at 37 and Downes, ‘Rethinking Penalty Clauses’ in Birks, (ed) Wrongs and Remedies in the Twenty-First Century (OxfordClarendon Press 1996), at 153, are noteworthy exceptions.Google Scholar

36 Above n 28, at 1030. This can be compared with, eg, an ‘unreasonable’ exclusion clause which seeks to exclude or restrict liability for breach of contract under UCTA 1977, or aprovision imposing unlawful restraints on trade.Google Scholar

37 Above n 28, at 1040.Google Scholar

38 Above n 28, at 1042.Google Scholar

39 There is an action in debt for the recoverable part of the penalty clause.Google Scholar

40 Above n 28, at 1040.Google Scholar

41 And thus it has become a ‘dead letter’ (at 1039).Google Scholar

42 White and Carter (Councils) Ltd v McGregor [1962] AC 413 shows the advantages of a claim in debt. The claimants were not obliged to mitigate their loss. The advantages in avoiding the remoteness rules are exemplified in Robophone Facilities Ltd v Blank above n 26.Google Scholar

43 And Elsley v JG Collins Ins Agencies Ltd, above n 27.

44 Thilmany, JFonctions et Révisibilité des Clauses Pénales en Droit Comparé’ (1980) 44 Rev Int Dr Comp 17, at 18.Google Scholar

45 Starck et al Droit Civil. Les Obligations Tome 2 (Paris Litec 1998) at 1843. It will be seen in Section IV that the French emphasise the performance of an obligation (exécution en nature) as opposed to an action for damages. The law is equipped with complementary mechanisms to compel, or encourage, performance. Outside the penalty clause rules one finds such things as the astreinte—‘une mesure licite d'intimidation’ (Terré et al Droit Civil; Les Obligations (Paris Dalloz 1996), at 1025)—or the mise en demeure (see below n 126).Google Scholar

46 Other civilian systems (eg German, Italian, Spanish, Portuguese) adopt a similar approach.

47 Une clause n'est…pénale que si elle a un caractére comminatoireMazeaud, D, above n 2, at 85. See also Mestre, J ‘De la Notion dela Clause Pénale’ RTD civ 1985, 372, at 373–the clause pénale is ‘nécessairement comminatoire’. For jurisprudence supporting this; Civ ler, 22 févr 1977, Bull civ I, no 99, 77.Google Scholar

48 Treitel, G, Remedies for Breach of Contract (OxfordOxford University Press 1988), at 212.Google Scholar

49 Civ 3e, 12 janv 1994: RTD civ. 1994, 605, obs Mestre.Google Scholar

50 Although, it has been more recently argued that the code wholly subscribes to natural law principles and it is only through later interpretation that individualist philosophies have been given any substance. See A Burge ‘Le code civil et son évolution vers un droit imprégné d'individualisme libéral’ RTD civ. 2000, 1 and J Gordley, ‘Myths of the French Civil Code’ 42 Am J Comp Law (1994) 459.Google Scholar

51 Embodied in Art 1134 al 1; Les conventions légalement formées tiennent lieu de loi à ceux qui les ont faites. The complementarity of Arts 1152 al 1 and 1134 al 1 is later underlined in a decision of the Cour commerciale le 2 11 1967–Bull Civ III, no 351, 333; RTD civ, 1969,116 et obs Chevallier, J, ‘la convention…tenant lieu de loi à ceux qui I'ont faite, il ne peut être alloué à l'autre partie une somme plus forte ni moindre’.Google Scholar

52 Other continental jurisdictions did not grant the same inviolable status to the penalty clause as France. For example, Italy (Art 1134 c.civ), Switzerland (Art 163 C. Federal des Obligations) and Germany (§343 BGB) all allowed the sum to be reduced by the courts where it was excessive.Google Scholar

53 The conception of the clause as an assessment of damages means that the obligee cannot demand the penalty in addition to performance or damages. This contrasts with the German provision §340 BGB which provides that the penalty clause is a minimum sum and does not preclude an action for damages if actual loss is more.Google Scholar

54 La peine peut être modifiée par le juge lorsque l'obligation principale a été éxécutée en partie.’Google Scholar

55 Boccarra, B‘La Liquidation de la Clause Pénale et la Querelle de 1'article 1231 du Code Civil’ JCP 1970 I 2294, at para 9.Google Scholar

56 Sanz, S‘La Consécration du Pouvoir Judiciaire par la Loi du 9 juillet 1975 et ses Incidences sur la Théorie Générale de la Clause Pénale’ RTD civ. 1977, 268.Google Scholar

57 Thilmany aboven 44 and Mazeaud above n 2 talk of ‘contractual terrorism’.Google Scholar

58 For a particularly harsh case concerning a rental agreement see Com et Fin, 2 novembre 1967, Bul 1967, III, n° 351, 333.Google Scholar

59 The Court did express regret at the principle of non-intervention in its ’Rapport au Garde des Sceaux19721973 demanding reform of the texts that it felt bound to follow.Google Scholar

60 The power of the judge has been seen as resting more on a notion of equity than that of law. Armand-Prevostand Richard ‘Le Contrat Déstabilise (De L'Autonomie de la Volonté au Dirigisme Contractuel)’JCP 1979 I 2952, at para 19. Nevertheless the reform affirmed the importance of judicial powers in private contractual relations; Mazeaud above n 2, at 30.Google Scholar

61 Une bréche a ainsi été ouverte en 1975 dans le principe de la force obligatoire des conventions’; Paisant, G ‘Dix ans d’Application de la Reforme des Articles 1152 et 1231 du Code Civil Relative à la Clause Pénale (loi du 9 juillet 1975)’ RTD. civ 1985. 647, at 4. F Chabas—considers that the law is ‘une des premieres entorses importantes apportées à l'article 1134 du Code civil’ ‘La Réforme dela Clause Pénale’ D 1976 Chron 229.Google Scholar

62 Boubli, BLa Mort de la Clause Pénale ou le déclin du principe de l'autonomie de la volontéJ not 1976. 1. 945.Google Scholar

63 Letartre, YRequiem pour une Clause Pénalé?Rev Jur Com (1978) 101.Google Scholar

64 It is interesting to draw attention to this powerful judicial role bearing in mind that one purpose of the clause pénale is to obviate judicial evaluation of damages.Google Scholar

65 See Mestre above n 47, at 372 et seq; Mazeaud above n 2, 145 et seq; Dagorne-Labbe ‘Rejet de la demande de réduction de l'indemnité contractuelle de résiliation due au mandataire’ JCP 2002 II, 10 067.Google Scholar

66 See, eg, case D 1996 Somm 329, obs Mazeaud where the court refused to extend the ambit of 1152. al 2.Google Scholar

67 Mazeaud above n 2, at 148. Chabas Leçons de Droit Civil; Tome II Obligations (Montchrestien 1998), at 772 states that apart from certain clauses whose identity is settled—I'indemnité d'immoblisation and la clause de dédit—the court will look at the intention of the parties. The parties' denomination of the clause is not determinative.Google Scholar

68 As per Lord Diplock, in Robophone above n 26, at 142.Google Scholar

69 ‘[W]hat the parties have agreed should normally be upheld’ Philips Hong Kong Ltd v A-G of Hong Kong, above n 19, at 59.Google Scholar

70 Ibid and Lord Diplock in Robophone, above n 26, at 142.

70 See Privy Council judgment of Union Eagle Ltd v Golden Achievement Ltd [1997] AC 514.Google Scholar

72 My emphasis.Google Scholar

73 The judge not only decides whether to intervene but also evaluates whether the conditions for intervention are present—in other words whether the sum is manifestement excessive—arrět de la Première Chambre civile—24 juill 1978 Gaz Pal 8, 9 déc 1978.Google Scholar

74 Loi no 85–1097 du 11 oct 1985.Google Scholar

75 This point is punctuated by comparison with the Swiss legislative provision which provides, ‘le juge doit reduire les peines qu'il estime excessives’. [my emphasis]Google Scholar

76 The explicit inclusion of subjective values contrasts with the common law orthodoxy that the judge must work within solely objective confines.Google Scholar

77 It is submitted that since assessment can openly incorporate all factors up to the time of the judgment—and not just the circumstances at the contract's conclusion—appreciation of the subjective element is facilitated. The contrast with the English rejection of subjective concerns is noteworthy. Dillon, LJ, in Jobson v Johnson, above n 28, at 1033 (referring to Wallingford v Mutual Society (1880) 5 App Cas 685, at 702) states that neither the financial circumstances nor the extent of culpability of the mortgagor were relevant to relief from enforcing the penalty. Nicholls, LJ (at 1041) considered the ‘circumstances of the default’ immaterial.Google Scholar

78 Cornu, G ‘Clause Pénale; principle, limite et conséquence de l'appreciation souveraine par les juges du fond, du caractère manifestement excessif de la peine stipulée et du montant de la modération’ RTD civ 1979. 150.Google Scholar

79 Cass com, 23 janv 1979, Bull civ IV, no 30; Amiens, CA, 23 nov 1976, JCP 1977.II.18567, note EMB.Google Scholar

80 Modérer n'est pas supprimer’ Paisant;D 1991, 481, at 13.Google Scholar

81 Com, juill 1991, D 92, 365.Google Scholar

82 See Section V.Google Scholar

83 White & Carter (Councils) Ltd v McGregor, above n 42; The Protector Endowment Loan Co v Grice (1880) 5 QBD 529. It is not the purpose of this paper to evaluate the commercial efficacy or desirability behind this mechanism, rather to highlight the fact that a penal element is seen as acceptable.Google Scholar

84 In other words, a provision that stipulated for interest for the whole contractual period as well as accelerated payment would be considered penal. See The Angelic Star [1988] 1 Lloyd's Rep 122, at 125Google Scholar

85 Civ lre, 22 fév 1977 Bull civ I, no 99.Google Scholar

86 Hongkong Fir Shipping Co Ltd v Kawasaki Risen Kaisha Ltd [1962] 2 QB 26.Google Scholar

87 See below n 90 and n 91 for qualifications to this rule.Google Scholar

88 La résolution doit être demandée en justice.Google Scholar

89 Thus the onus of initiating litigation shifts to the obligor.Google Scholar

90 Although where breach of a ‘condition’ occasions negligible damage the court may hold that termination is not justified; Wickman Ltd v Schuler AG [1974] AC 235. See also Rice v Great Yarmouth BC (2001) 3 LGLR 4 where the Court of Appeal refused to recognize a termination clause which extended to multiple types of obligation under a 4-year contract.Google Scholar

91 In practice, the courts will have regard for the consequences that termination will have for the obligor in determining whether a breach is sufficiently serious to justify termination by the obligee.Google Scholar

92 See, eg, Mazeaud above n 2, at 63.Google Scholar

93 See Friedmann ‘Good Faith and Remedies for Breach of Contract’ in Beatson, and Friedmann, (eds)Good Faith and Fault in Contract Law (OxfordOxford Univeristy Press 1995)Google Scholarand Goode, R ‘Europe and English Commercial Law’ in Markesinis, (ed), The British Contribution to the Europe of the Twenty-first Century. British Academy Centenary Lectures (OxfordHart 2002) 19. It should also be borne in mind that judicial assistance may be required to work out the consequences of termination. Thus, the distinction between self-help and judicial remedies can be slightGoogle Scholar

94 A good example is Alder v Moore [1961] 2 QB 57. A sum due to an insurance company if a professional footballer returned to the sport after an injury was not a penalty. There was no breach on his return to the sport since he had not promised otherwise. As far back as 1975 a Law Commission Working Paper (No 61) recommended that the ‘court should have the power to deal with such clauses in the same way whether or not they come into operation by breach’ (para 22). It further proposed that the penalty clause rules should apply ‘wherever the object of the disputed contractual obligation is to secure the act or result which is the true purpose for the contract’ (para 26).Google Scholar

95 Associated Distributors Ltd v Hall [1938] 2 KB 83 and Bridge v Campbell Discount Co Ltd, above n 22.Google Scholar

96 Where the contract is governed by the Consumer Credit Act 1974 then this may not apply.Google Scholar

97 Above n 32. Here the judges were able to find the hirer in breach of contract to release him from liability. In this case the result furthered the general policy underlying the law relating to penalties. But it is a rather precarious basis on which to proceed should the facts of the case differ.Google Scholar

98 Civ 3e, 5 déc 1984 D 1985.545 et note Benac-Schmidt.Google Scholar

99 Export Credits Guarantee Department v Universal Oil Products, above n 8 and Civ Ire, 16 janv 1985 JCP 1986 II 20661 et note Paisant.Google Scholar

100 The court will look at the intention of the parties to determine their objectives; Mayson v Clouet [1924] AC 980, at 985.Google Scholar

101 Howe v Smith (1884) 27 Ch D 89.Google Scholar

102 Mayson v Clouet above n 100. However the issue of whether a part payment is recoverable will be subject to the standard of unconscionability. See Stockloser v Johnson [1954] 1 QB 476.Google Scholar

103 Linggi Plantations Ltd v Jagatheesan [1972] 1 MLJ 89 at 94. It is interesting that this definition replicates one given to the French clause pénale in an attempt to distinguish between that and a clause de dédit: une clause pénale ‘est la garantie des obligations contractuelles’—Mazeaud D 29996 Somm 329. (A clause de dédit can be broadly translated as a ‘forfeiture clause’. It is seen not as a guarantee to perform but as the payment by the obligor for the freedom to unilaterally withdraw from the contract without incurring liability. It is the exercise of a right as opposed to the English breach of an obligation).Google Scholar

104 Workers Trust and Merchant Bank Ltd v Dojap Investments Ltd [1993] AC 573.Google Scholar

105 The 1975 Law Commission's Working Paper No 61 had proposed that control over penalty clauses should be extended to forfeitures and deposits (paras 64–6).Google Scholar

106 This percentage, although [without logic], was used as a benchmark since it was normal practice in contracts for the sale of land.Google Scholar

107 Unless special circumstances prove otherwise.Google Scholar

108 As per Lord Browne-Wilkinson in Workers Trust, above n 104, at 580.Google Scholar

109 Although there is scope for the argument that ‘unreasonable’ can be equated with ‘unconscionable’ under the first Dunlop rule.Google Scholar

110 Following the Jobson v Johnson rules on penalty clauses.Google Scholar

111 He will though be able to recover damages for any loss suffered from breach.Google Scholar

112 Defined above n 103.Google Scholar

113 Dimatteo, L‘A Theory of Efficient Penalty; Eliminating the Law of Liquidated Damages’ 38 Am Bus LJ (2001) 633, at 635.Google Scholar

114 Ibbetson, above n 3, at 245.Google Scholar

115 This is common law terminology. Whereas in England the law of ‘remedies’ is treated as a coherent set of legal principles, in France, the same area of law is instead incorporated in different chapters and sections of the Code civil and analysed as the effects of the contract or obligation rather than a wholly separate legal category. Although the difference is principally only one of structure, it does draw attention to the different approaches (see B Nicholas The French Law of Contract (OxfordOxford University Press 1992) 211).Google Scholar

116 It should be stressed that the discussion in this section represents the traditional theoretical positions. Legal systems do not remain static and trends have meant that in practice, despite the different emphasis, the systems often arrive at the same results. The types of contract which are specifically enforced in France and England ‘share common characteristics’ Ogus ‘Remedies. 1. English Report’ in Harris and Tallon (eds) Contract Law Today; Anglo-French Comparisons (OxfordClarendon Press1989) 243. Despite modern trends examination of the traditional approach is of course imperative to an understanding of the underlying legal structures and ‘attitudes of mind’ (Nicholas ibid, at 211) that have formed the penalty clause rules.

117 Farnsworth ‘Legal Remedies for Breach of Contract’ Columbia L Rev (1970) 1145.Google Scholar

118 Despite the suggestion in Art 1142 that damages are the primary remedy (for an obligation defaire or de ne pas faire) the principle is subject to numerous qualifications and a juristic interpretation that has reduced it to an exception.Google Scholar

119 Davy v Spelthorne BC [1983] 3 All ER 278,185 per Lord Wilberforce, ‘Typically English law fastens not on principles but remedies.’Google Scholar

120 Ogus above n 117, at 293.Google Scholar

121 See on this generally, A de Moor ‘Common and Civil Law conceptions of Contract and a European Law of Contract; the Case of the Directive on Unfair terms in Consumer Contracts’ European Review of Private Law (1995) 257.Google Scholar

122 It is suggested that the term ‘remedies’ accentuates the common law focus on only one side of the contractual relationship—the obligee's. In France conceptualization as les effets du contrat presupposes rules relating to both obligor and obligee.Google Scholar

123 Picod, ‘L'Obligation de coopération dans l'exécution du contrat’ JCP 1988 I 3318, visualises the contract as an obligation of cooperation. Kötz believes French law ‘ranks solidarity higher than individualism’ ‘Towards a European Civil code; The Duty of Good Faith’ in Cane, P and Stapleton, J (eds) The Law of Obligations; Essays in Celebration of John Fleming (OxfordClarendon Press 1988) 256. This concept of contract is not fitting for an adversarial system such as the common law.Google Scholar

124 When the French do talk of damages it is perceived as a substitute for actual performance rather than simply compensation for the loss of bargain, reflecting the French emphasis on performance.Google Scholar

125 The French requirement of the mise en demeure (Art 1146) whereby the injured party, acting through a huissier, must serve a formal notice on the defaulter is another example of the importance of performance in France. In practice it will work to give the obligor one last chance to perform. The nineteenth century judicial innovation known as the astreinte, likewise, is geared towards ensuring performance. It imposes a monetary sanction for each day of non-compliance with the contractual obligation.Google Scholar

126 Although apart from the dicta in Printing and Numerical Registering Company v Sampson (1875) LR 19 Eq 462 as per Sir Jessel, G, MR, at 465, adherence to the Will Theory is perhaps usually more a question of objective interpretation rather than formal, explicit judicial acknowledgement.Google Scholar

127 By ‘certainty’ is meant the formulation of clear rules that enable forward planning and risk assessment rather than the systemic certainty that comes with the preservation of the contractual obligation itself.Google Scholar

128 Harris and Tallon (eds), above n 116, at 386.Google Scholar

129 This is the basis for the so-called ‘efficient breach’ theory advocated by Posner in Economic Analysis of Law (5th edn New YorkAspen Law & Business 1998). Where the breaching party will still be better off by the breach, even after paying damages to the ‘innocent’ party, then economic theory regards this as a positive thing. Thus, a contracting party should be free to breach and not be compelled to perform the obligation.Google Scholar

130 This brief foray into economic analysis cannot do justice to the complexity of this area. Nor does it give adequate voice to the persuasive counter-arguments of many commentators. See, eg, Rubin ‘Unenforceable Contracts: Penalty Clauses and Specific Performance’ 10 (1981) Legal, JStudies 237; Goetz and Scott ‘Liquidated Damages, Penalties and the Just Compensation Principles: Some Notes on an Enforcement Model and a Theory of Efficient Breach’ 77 Colum L Rev (1977) 554; Clarkson et al, above n 45.Google Scholar

131 The first provision of Ch III which deals with Les Effets Des Obligations.Google Scholar

132 Whittaker, Zimmermann and Good Faith in European Contract Law (CambridgeCambridge University Press, 2000)33.Google Scholar

133 Though it was not until 1985 that the Cour de cassation ruled on an appeal that was based on this provision—Civ 1, 20 mars 1985, B 1985 1, no 102.Google Scholar

134 La concept de bonne foi en droit francais du contrat’ <http://www.cnr.it/CRDS/tallon.htm>. In several civilian systems the concept of good faith has developed far beyond what the common lawyer might immediately think of—Beale,.+In+several+civilian+systems+the+concept+of+good+faith+has+developed+far+beyond+what+the+common+lawyer+might+immediately+think+of—Beale,>Google Scholar‘Legislative Control of Fairness; The Directive on Unfair terms in Consumer Contracts’ in Beatson, and Friedmann, (eds) Good Faith in Contract Law (OxfordOxford University Press 1995).Google Scholar

135 La bonne foi est le moyen de faire pnétrer la régie morale dans le droit positif. Terré et al, above n 45, at 347.Google Scholar

136 Picod, above n 123.Google Scholar

137 Ghestin, J, Traité de Droit Civil—Les Obligations. Le Contraf. Formation (LGDJ 1988), at 184 sees loyalty as a necessary complement to contractual justice.Google Scholar

138 Aubert, Flour and Les Obligations; L'Acte juridique (ParisArmand Colin 1998), at 386.Google Scholar

139 Tallon, Harris and, above, n 116, at 386.Google Scholar

140 Whilst the prolific and protean nature of English commentary on good faith counsels against cursory mention of the principle, a deep examination is outside the true scope of this paper. See instead, eg, Beatson and Friedman (eds), above n 171;Google ScholarBridge ‘Does Anglo-Canadian Contract Law Need a Doctrine of Good Faith?9 Canadian Business Law Journal (1984) 385;Google ScholarTeubner ‘Legal Irritants: Good Faith in British Law of How Unifying Law Ends up in New Divergences’ 61 [1988] MLR 11:Google ScholarWhittaker, Zimmermann and, above n 132; Brownsword et al ‘Good Faith in Contract: Concept and Context’ in Brownsword, et al. (eds) Good Faith in Contract: Concept and Context (DartmouthAshgate 1999).Google Scholar

141 English law has…committed itself to no such overriding principle but has developed piecemeal solutions in response to demonstrated problems of unfairness’ as per Lord Bingham, Interfoto Picture Library Ltd v Stiletto Visual Programmes Ltd [1989[ QB 433, at 439.Google Scholar

142 Although note comments regarding Law Commission Report No 166 in Section V below.Google Scholar

143 Waddams, The Law of Contracts (TorontoCanada Law Book Inc 1998), at 458.Google Scholar

144 Waddams seems to equate ‘unconscionability’ with ‘reasonableness’. See also Downes, above n 35.Google Scholar

145 He draws support for his argument from the law lords' speeches, Lord Atkinson and Lord Dunedin both using the words ‘unconscionable’ to describe the clause under consideration and Lord Atkinson supplementing ‘unconscionable’ with ‘unreasonable’ and ‘extravagant’. He further notes that in the facts of the case the clause, stipulating for a payment of £5 on each breach of the agreement, could hardly be described as a genuine pre-estimate of damage and that the only reason that it was enforced was that it was ‘unreasonable’.Google Scholar

146 Waddams, above n 143, at 456.Google Scholar

147 United Dominion Trust (Commercial) Ltd v Ellis [1968] 1 QB 54, at 67.Google Scholar

148 The voluminous literature on the term proves its will-o-the-wisp nature. For example, the concept has been separated into substantive and procedural unconscionability—(Leff, ‘Unconscionability and the Code—The Emperor's New Clause’ 115 (19661967) University of Pennsylvania 485), defined as ‘substantive fairness’—(Smith ‘In Defence of Substantive Fairness’ 112 LQR (1996) 392) and as incorporating concepts such as unfairness, inequity, unreasonableness or oppression—Waddams above, n 143, at 543. One American commentator finds substantive unconscionability coterminous with the civilian idea of ‘manifestly excessive’ while procedural unconscionability draws on similar factors as are taken into account in the civilian review of the clause, Dimatteo, above n 113, at 653.Google Scholar

149 Waddams does not limit unconscionability to penalty clauses but includes areas of contract such as interpretation, duress, and incorporation of documents.Google Scholar

150 Good faith has been likened to the ‘surprise’ factor in a contract and unconscionability the ‘imbalance’; Dugan ‘Standardized Forms; Unconscionability and Good Faith’ 14 New England Law Review (1979) 711. Despite the fact that both ‘sound somewhat familiar’ good faith has different meanings in different contexts whereas unconscionability can encompass and unify quite different legal techniques under the same doctrinal umbrella. It is this difference that excludes good faith from similar treatment to unconscionability—Waddams ‘Good Faith, Unconscionability and Reasonable Expectations’ 9 JCL (1995), at 57–9.(Waddams, curiously, is very much against adoption of good faith as a general principle).Steyn ‘Contract Law; Fulfilling the Reasonable Expectations of Honest Men’ 113 LQR [1997] 433 likens good faith to ‘reasonable expectations’. Collins ‘Good Faith in European Contract Law’ 14 Oxford Journal Legal Studies (1994) 229, at 250 perceives unconscionability in similar terms as the French notion of bonne foi.Google Scholar

151 93/13/EEC.Google Scholar

152 Teubner, above n 140.Google Scholar

153 Collins, above n 150, at 249.Google Scholar

154 Tenreiro ‘The Community Directive on Unfair Terms and National Legal Systems. The Principle of Good Faith and Remedies for Unfair Terms’ European Review of Private Law (1995) 273 at 279 and Beale above n 134 at 245.Google Scholar

155 Collins, above n 150, at 250.Google Scholar

156 This is considered to be the case in France; in consumer law ‘les règles ont de surcrôit tendanace à s'étendre par contagion à d'autres secteurs’ Chabas, above n 67 at 634.Google Scholar

157 Article L 132–1.Google Scholar

158 Loi no. 95–96 du ler févr 1995. The report from the Commission on the implementation of Council Directive 93/13/EEC of 5 Apr 1993 on unfair terms in consumer contracts (COM/2000/248 final) considers that France has incorrectly implemented this article.Google Scholar

159 Or a ‘non-professional’ according to the French transposing legislation.Google Scholar

160 Les clauses abusives sont réputes non écrites Art L132–1 al 6.Google Scholar

161 D 1992 Somm. 268 obs Kullmann. Also, see Paisant, above n 61 ‘[L]e legislateur n'avait pas songé aux clauses pénales en modifiant la definition des clause abusives’.Google Scholar

162 Or according to some commentators, to an amount that equals loss. See above.Google Scholar

163 One could argue that the consumer would be adequately protected under Art 1152 Code civil without resort to the Code de la consommation. This is mooted by Kullmann, above 161. But since the 1993 law is a lex specialis it is to this that one should resort; Starck et al. above n 45, at 1833.Google Scholar

164 Even for the United Kingdom, whose commercial legal roots are attractive to foreign investment and who stands to gain the most from resisting harmonisation.Google Scholar

165 Consultation and discussion continues at the European Community level. See the recent Communication from the Commission to the European Parliament and the Council of 12 Feb 2003 (COM (2003) 68 final). This ‘Action Plan’ continues the consultative nature of the process begun by the Commission Communication of 11 July 2001 (COM (2001) 398 final).Google Scholar

166 Art 9:509 PECL; Art 7.4.13. Unidroit.Google Scholar

167 A de Moor, above n 121, at 262.Google Scholar