Hostname: page-component-cd9895bd7-q99xh Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-12-21T07:08:51.713Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Banking on distant shores: a comparison of the development of foreign banks in pre-World War I China and Japan

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  04 November 2024

Ghassan Moazzin*
Affiliation:
Hong Kong Institute for the Humanities and Social Sciences and School of Humanities (Department of History), The University of Hong Kong, Hong Kong, Hong Kong SAR
*
Rights & Permissions [Opens in a new window]

Abstract

This article provides the first in-depth systematic comparison of foreign banking in pre-World War I China and Japan. As the article shows, after their entry into China and Japan, the presence and activities of foreign banks in China and Japan differed markedly, with these banks developing a much more prominent position in China. Making use of sources in German, English, Chinese, and Japanese, this article aims to explain why foreign banks in China and Japan developed so differently before World War I. It does so by first providing an overview of the development of foreign banks in both countries and then discussing their activities and development with regards to Chinese and Japanese financial institutions, trade finance, and public finance. The article shows that it was Japan's emphasis on financial reforms that led to the limited presence of foreign banks in that country.

Type
Research Article
Creative Commons
Creative Common License - CCCreative Common License - BYCreative Common License - NCCreative Common License - ND
This is an Open Access article, distributed under the terms of the Creative Commons Attribution-NonCommercial-NoDerivatives licence (http://creativecommons.org/licenses/by-nc-nd/4.0), which permits non-commercial re-use, distribution, and reproduction in any medium, provided that no alterations are made and the original article is properly cited. The written permission of Cambridge University Press must be obtained prior to any commercial use and/or adaptation of the article.
Copyright
Copyright © The Author(s), 2024. Published by Cambridge University Press

It is well known that modern multinational banking saw a major expansion in the nineteenth and early twentieth centuries.Footnote 1 Scholarship on this expansion has produced a wide range of studies that have either tried to provide a comprehensive picture of the spread of multinational banking or have focused on studying the history of a particular bank, multinational banks of a particular nationality or the activities of multinational banks in a particular host country.Footnote 2 However, despite the fact that previous scholarship has emphasized the importance of the comparative study of host countries of multinational firms and pointed out that “what requires more inter-country research is how host nations were (or were not) able to absorb what the multinational enterprise introduced – how they responded to the multinationals’ activities,”Footnote 3 no study has so far tried to systematically and in detail compare the operations of multinational banks in and impact on different host countries before 1914.

This article aims to address this gap in the literature by comparing the activities of multinational banks in pre-1914 China and Japan and their impact and interaction with the Chinese and Japanese economies. China and Japan are a particularly suitable subject for a systematic comparison of the activities of multinational banks. Not only are these two countries geographically close and both located in East Asia. Multinational banks also entered both countries at roughly the same time – the mid-nineteenth century. Moreover, as we will see, after their first entry multinational banks followed two different development trajectories in China and Japan before World War I respectively, which makes an exploration of the reasons behind these different development paths particularly worthwhile.Footnote 4

While studies that explore the activities of foreign banks in either China or Japan exist,Footnote 5 so far the only study that – if only in passing – makes a comparison between foreign banking in China and Japan is Donnithorne and Allen's dated comprehensive study of foreign business in East Asia, which, amongst other fields of business, also covers banking. They note that in Japan Western entrepreneurs were “relegated to a subordinate role as soon as native enterprise had achieved maturity,” that foreign investment in China was greater and at times more politicized than in Japan and that the proactive role of the Japanese state in economic development meant that the activities of foreign enterprise in Japan were of a more limited nature. More specifically, they ascertain that due to the Japanese unwillingness of leaving the exchange business to foreign banks and the early success of state-led financial reform and modernization in Japan, including the establishment of the Yokohama Specie Bank, and the lack thereof in China, “foreign banks naturally fulfilled a more modest and a more highly specialised role in Japan than in China.” In contrast, they explain that due to the lack of modern Chinese financial institutions in nineteenth and early twentieth century China, foreign banks played a broader and more dominant role in the Chinese economy. However, they neither go into much depth in their comparative analysis nor properly compare the activities of foreign banks in both countries. Moreover, their account of finance and banking in East Asia does not take into account Chinese or Japanese language sources.Footnote 6 Nevertheless, building on these preliminary insights of Allen and Donnithorne, the main contribution of this article is that it offers the first detailed and systematic comparative analysis of foreign banking in pre-WW1 China and Japan.Footnote 7

This study adopts a comparative approach to shed light on the differences in the development trajectories of foreign banks in China and Japan. For this purpose, it juxtaposes and compares both the development of foreign banking institutions in both countries and the context of financial modernization in China and Japan within which this development occurred. Moreover, this article further pursues this comparative approach by zooming in on two major areas of activity of foreign banks in both China and Japan: trade finance and the issuing of loans for their host countries on foreign capital markets. The comparative analysis in this article is based on a wide range of primary and secondary sources in Chinese, Japanese, German, and English. While the main stay of the analysis is based on secondary sources to allow for a broad comparative analysis along the lines outlined above, primary sources are used to supply further (particularly quantitative) evidence to complete the comparative picture provided in this article.

This article will start by sketching the development of foreign banking in China and Japan between the middle of the nineteenth century and the First World War. It will show that foreign banking had a much stronger presence in modern China. The following three sections will then attempt to explain this more developed presence. First, this article will look at financial modernization in both modern China and Japan and its implication for the operation of foreign banks. Second, I will investigate how the business of trade finance developed for foreign banks in modern China and Japan. Third, I will look at the role foreign banks played in China and Japan in floating loans for the host government on foreign capital markets. Finally, this article concludes by summarizing its findings and discussing the potential implications of this study for our understanding of the operations of multinational banks.

An overview of foreign banking in China and Japan

The first Western bank entered China shortly after the Treaty of Nanjing had opened five Chinese ports to foreign trade in 1842. Only three years later, the British Oriental Bank Corporation opened branches in Hong Kong and Guangzhou.Footnote 8 During the following four decades, foreign banking saw moderate growth, with several foreign banks, mostly of British origin, entering the Chinese market (and some leaving it again) with British banks coming to dominate foreign banking in China.Footnote 9 These banks specialized in the financing of trade between China and Europe.Footnote 10 In addition, they also issued bank notes, accepted deposits, and provided loans to Chinese banks.Footnote 11 These three areas of business proved to be popular with Chinese customers.Footnote 12 As foreign banks operated under extraterritoriality in China, they were not subject to Chinese law.Footnote 13 This not only was the basis of their bank notes issuance, but also helped them attract deposits as these could not be touched by the Chinese government.Footnote 14 Starting from the 1870s, the Hong Kong and Shanghai Banking Corporation (HSBC) and other foreign banks also started to float foreign public loans for China on European capital markets.Footnote 15 After 1890, foreign banking in China grew rapidly with many new non-British banks entering the Chinese market during the two-and-a-half decades before World War I.Footnote 16 For instance, in the case of Tianjin, an important Northern Chinese port, the Hongkong Daily Press's Chronicle & Directory for China in 1889 only lists two foreign bank offices. However, by 1914, the same publication lists seven foreign banks for said port.Footnote 17 An important feature of this period was that loans provided through individual foreign banks and international consortia to China increased dramatically.Footnote 18 While China had only issued some £16 million in foreign loans on Western bond markets before the end of the Sino-Japanese War of 1894/95, it issued around £133 million pounds in public loans thereafter between 1895 and 1913.Footnote 19 By 1908, at least sixteen foreign banks operated in China. While the number of branches varied from bank to bank, foreign banks could by then be found in most of China's major treaty ports.Footnote 20

In Japan, the entry of foreign banks also followed the opening of the first Japanese treaty ports to Western trade – in the Japanese case these were the treaty ports of Hakodate, Nagasaki, and Yokohama opened in 1859. As early as 1860, the Chartered Bank of India, Australia, and China, which already had a presence in China at the time, sent its Shanghai manager to Nagasaki to investigate the potential for opening a branch in Japan. However, said manager concluded that the time for such a move had not come yet, as there was still no significant presence of merchant houses in Japan, no steamer connection between Japan and China and the existing merchant firms, such as Jardine, Matheson & Co., had no need for the financial support of a foreign bank.Footnote 21 It was only three years later that three British banks – the Central Bank of Western India, the Chartered Mercantile Bank of India, London & China and the Commercial Bank of India – opened branches in Yokohama in 1863.Footnote 22 Only during the 1870s foreign banks also started to establish offices in other treaty ports.Footnote 23 By the end of 1865, there were five foreign banks – all British –active in Yokohama.Footnote 24 Similar to foreign banks in China, these banks focused their business on trade finance, but also engaged in the deposit and loan business and issued bank notes.Footnote 25 However, there generally seems to have been limited business for foreign banks in Japan. The Chartered Bank of India, Australia, and China sent another emissary to Japan in 1866, but due to the “Oriental and the Chartered Mercantile banks having opened first and secured most of the available exchange business” for long there seemed to be little potential for profits and the Chartered Bank only opened a branch in Japan in 1880.Footnote 26

Foreign banks in Japan were gravely hit by the financial panic of 1866, which forced all foreign banks in Yokohama but the Oriental and Chartered Mercantile banks to close.Footnote 27 During the following three decades, several new foreign banks entered Japan, but others also withdrew from the market.Footnote 28 As a result, the overall number of foreign banks in Japan stagnated. By 1900, only four foreign banks – the HSBC, the Chartered Bank, the National Bank of China and the Russo-Chinese Bank – operated in Japan.Footnote 29 In the period before the outbreak of World War I, more now mostly non-British banks entered Japan. However, at the same time, four foreign banks left the Japanese market altogether.Footnote 30 As a result, the total number of foreign banks in Japan only increased from four in 1900 to a total of six banks operating in Japan at the beginning of 1914.Footnote 31 Foreign banks in Japan also became involved in floating loans for the Japanese government on Western bond markets. After Japan floated two loans with the help of the Oriental Bank Corporation in London worth a total of £3,4 million during the 1870s, the central government only tapped foreign capital markets again in 1897 and subsequently borrowed around £178 million in the period between its return to Western capital markets and the outbreak of World War I.Footnote 32

This overview of the development of foreign banking in pre-war China and Japan shows that while the areas of business foreign banks engaged in in the Chinese and Japanese banking sector were similar, foreign banks had much more of a presence in China. While China saw a rapid increase in the number of foreign banks after 1890, the number of foreign banks in Japan largely stagnated between the mid-1860s and the eve of the First World War. The much more significant presence of foreign banks in China compared to Japan becomes even clearer if we look at Figure 1, which shows that foreign bank offices were not only much more numerous in China but that there was also a large difference in the spatial distribution of foreign banks. While there were only 13 offices of foreign banks distributed amongst four cities in central and south Japan, one could find a total of 57 foreign bank offices in cities along the China coast with several hubs of foreign banking, such as Shanghai or Tianjin.Footnote 33 In the next three sections, I will explore why foreign banks had so much more of a strong presence in China.

Figure 1. Number of foreign bank offices in Chinese and Japanese Cities in 1908. Bars indicate location and number of foreign banks in that location.

Source: Moazzin Reference Moazzin2022, Appendix 2 (The appendix does not include the ports of Changchun, Harbin, Tieling, Jilin and Kulun); Ōkurashō rizaikyoku 1908, pp. 416–418 (The latter source provides the state of foreign banks in Japan on the last day of 1907).

Foreign banks and indigenous institutions

After foreign banks had first arrived in China in the mid-nineteenth century, the Chinese reaction was mixed. On the one hand, Chinese reformers saw foreign banks as a model for modernizing China's financial institutions. During the nineteenth century, there primarily existed two kinds of prevalent Chinese financial institutions: Piaohao and qianzhuang. Piaohao specialised in long distance remittances and had a particularly close relationship with the Chinese government. Qianzhuang were local commercial banks. While both types of financial institutions had been sufficient for financing China's traditional economy, they were unable to provide the capital for modern industrial development.Footnote 34 Chinese entrepreneurs like Zheng Guanying viewed the foreign banks that increasingly flocked China's treaty ports as models according to which China should reform its own financial institutions to spur on economic growth.Footnote 35 When reformers like Sheng Xuanhuai established China's first modern Bank in the 1890s, they also explicitly used foreign banks as a model, as they believed that “modern banks originated in the West” and therefore China should imitate foreign banks such as the Hongkong and Shanghai Banking Corporation (HSBC) when establishing its own bank.Footnote 36 At the same time, those wishing to modernize China's financial institutions did not only see foreign banks in China in a positive light. Sheng argued that unless a modern Chinese bank was established, China would continue to suffer from “submission to high interest rates and losses from the [fluctuations of the] price of pound sterling” when borrowing from foreign banks and these banks would continue to “monopolise our great economic benefits.”Footnote 37 Clearly, Sheng's motivation of establishing a modern Chinese bank was also driven by his wish to rival foreign banks.Footnote 38 The first modern Chinese bank, the Tongshang Yinhang or Imperial Bank of China, was subsequently established in 1897.Footnote 39

What deserves attention is that it thus took roughly fifty years after the opening of the first treaty ports and the entry of the first Western banks before the first modern Chinese bank was established. To be sure, there had been several proposals and plans for the establishment of a modern Chinese bank from many sides since the 1870s, including from the prominent entrepreneur Tang Tingshu, whose planned bank was to specialize in financing foreign trade and shipping, and the important China merchant firm Jardine, Matheson & Co. However, these did all not come to fruition. On more than one occasion Qing officialdom did not take up such proposals due to disinterest or fear of foreign influence.Footnote 40 However, what seems to have been the larger problem was that the reform of the financial system simply was not a priority for the Chinese reform movement – also known as the Self-Strengthening Movement – which was active between the 1860s and the Sino-Japanese War and mainly focused on military and industrial modernization geared toward strengthening national defense.Footnote 41 While certain civil modern enterprises were established during the Self-Strengthening Movement, banking reform was only pursued after 1895.Footnote 42

The New Policies (or Xinzheng) reforms that followed in the period between 1901 and 1911 were more far-reaching than the Self-Strengthening Movement had been. They included some fiscal reforms and largely unsuccessful attempts at reforming the currency system. While these attempts at currency reform led to the establishment of another government-sponsored bank, the Daqing Bank, banking and financial market reform were not a major feature of the reform program.Footnote 43 Despite the establishment of the first modern Chinese bank in 1897, the development of a modern banking system did not make much progress during this period. The Imperial Bank of China took the regulations of the HSBC as its model and employed A.M. Maitland, a former HSBC banker, as its first general manager. It also tried to compete with foreign banks in several fields, such as the issuing of currency, even though it seems with modest success. Due to several external crises and internal problems, it eventually suffered a series of setbacks and failed to bring much change to China's financial markets. The Daqing Bank, originally envisioned as a central bank, seems to have been more successful than the Imperial Bank of China but suffered from problems of corruption. As a result, according to the historian Kong Xiangxian, it would have soon collapsed even if the Qing dynasty had not fallen in 1911. Apart from the Daqing Bank, the Chinese government also established the Bank of Communications, which mainly specialized in the funding of infrastructure. Moreover, several other modern banks were also established before 1911. Nevertheless, “At the end of the Qing dynasty, China's financial markets had not experienced significant change.”Footnote 44 Thus, in the pre-WW1 period, foreign banks faced little competition from new modern Chinese banks.Footnote 45 In fact, foreign banks in the late nineteenth and early twentieth centuries even developed an interdependent and profitable relationship with traditional Chinese qianzhuang.Footnote 46

Prior to the Meiji Restoration, Japan lacked Western-style modern financial institutions.Footnote 47 However, as Allen and Donnithorne correctly observe, compared with the Chinese government, Japan took a much more proactive role in financial reform. In fact, as Michael Schiltz has argued, “finance was at the heart of” the Meiji reform program that took off after 1868.Footnote 48 Even before the Meiji revolution of 1868, we can see evidence of the rather cautious attitude of the Japanese government toward foreign banks. The Tokugawa government ordered that Japanese financial dealings with the foreign banks in Yokohama could only be done through the Mitsui merchant house. This meant that the foreign banks were unable to directly interact with Japanese merchants and thereby prevented the development of a relationship along the lines of foreign banks and qianzhuang in China.Footnote 49 The first attempt at modernizing Japan's banking system started as early as 1869, when ryōgae, traditional merchant firms that also offered banking services, were reorganized into joint-stock exchange companies (Kawase kaisha), which were to financially support domestic and foreign trade and issue bank notes. While the operations of the exchange companies soon ended in failure – mainly due to larger structural changes taking place in Japan at the time – they familiarized people in Japan with the concept of the joint-stock company. They also already exemplified the wish of the Japanese government to challenge the position of foreign banks and not leave banking to foreign institutions. As the famous Japanese entrepreneur, Shibusawa Eiichi, later recalled, in the treaty ports, where initially foreign silver coins were used as a currency, the notes issued by foreign banks “became gradually a kind of trade currency” there and “fluctuations in foreign silver were controlled by the foreigners.” In addition, “these notes being printed in a foreign language were very inconvenient for the Japanese merchants.” To resolve this problem, the Yokohama Exchange Company was allowed to issue notes called yōginken (lit. foreign silver notes), which were denominated in foreign silver dollars.Footnote 50

The next Japanese attempt to establish a modern banking system was the establishment of national banks following the model of the United States. The national bank system was inaugurated with the National Bank Decree in 1872, which stipulated how one could apply for national bank status that came with the right to issue notes and also regulated their primary fields of business, including “dealing in bills of exchange, exchanging money, taking deposits, making loans, transacting business in shares, bonds, currency, and bullion, and also handling public funds when so required by the Government.”Footnote 51 Of the exchange companies that had been established, only the Yokohama Exchange Company survived. It was reorganized into the Second National Bank and continued to issue silver dollar notes until 1885.Footnote 52 During this time, to assist with the introduction of modern banking, the Japanese government employed and drew extensively on the advice of Alexander Allan Shand, the British manager of the Chartered Mercantile Bank in Yokohama. Shand came to play an important role in the reform of Japanese banking.Footnote 53 Notably, this was some two decades before the Chinese government would draw on the assistance of a foreign banker for financial reform. Subsequently, the Japanese national bank regulations underwent two major revisions: The first in 1876, which eased the establishment of national banks and – together with the encouragement of the Japanese government – led to a sharp rise in their number to 153 by the end of 1879; the second in 1883, which transferred the right of note issue to the newly established Bank of Japan and forced the national banks to eventually transform themselves into private banks. The national bank system eventually ended in 1899.Footnote 54 Further regulations for private banks were passed in 1890 and by 1911 the number of modern Japanese banks had risen to 2145.Footnote 55 This compares to only seventeen modern banks having been established by then in China.Footnote 56 Thus, in China, foreign banks generally faced little competition from modern domestic banks before World War I, whereas in Japan financial institutions that fulfilled modern banking functions started to appear in large numbers as early as the late 1870s.

However, arguably the most important financial institution that grew out of the national bank regulations from the viewpoint of foreign banks operation in Japan was the Yokohama Specie Bank (YSB). As Shibusawa explains, this bank was founded in 1879 and specialized in “foreign exchange business, […] act[ing] as a special financial organ for transactions in foreign trade, and […] manag[ing] financial affairs abroad for the Government.” It was established in response to the outflow of specie and the control foreign banks exerted over “the money markets in the treaty ports” and the “rates of exchange and other commercial matters” there, which put Japanese merchants in a disadvantageous position (The control over foreign exchange rates is vividly shown in the contemporary cartoon in Fig. 2).Footnote 57 Nakamura Michita, who became the first president of the YSB, pointed out that “in order to remedy the current situation, we have to establish a big bank that is in the hand of our people, facilitate the operation and supply of silver, strive as much as possible to mediate and make finance smooth between foreign and Japanese merchants, rival and greatly check the foreign banks and gradually reclaim our commercial rights.”Footnote 58 This shows how the establishment of the YSB was specifically aimed at competing with the foreign banks in Japan's treaty ports. As we will see in the following sections, the YSB indeed came to be the foreign banks' main competitor. The Japanese government gave the YSB special status – it was one of the “special banks” (tokushu ginkō) that each served a specific purpose in accordance with the government's strategy – and both controlled and specifically supported it. It provided one third of the Bank's total capital of ¥3 million in silver specie and had the ability to influence the selection of the YSB's leadership and its operations. The YSB also had a close relationship with the Bank of Japan, which provided the YSB with advantageous discounting services at a low interest rate. The YSB opened branches in financial hubs around the world, including in London and Shanghai.Footnote 59 Through the YSB, the Japanese government could also set and control foreign exchange rates.Footnote 60

Figure 2. Political Cartoon titled “The Puppet player” from the January 1875 issue of the Japan Punch. It depicts the manager of the Oriental Bank Corporation controlling the Tael-Yen exchange rate.

Finally, in 1899 the legal environment foreign banks in Japan operated in changed as well. Before 1899, like all foreign institutions, foreign banks in Japan – similar to those in China – operated under extraterritoriality and thus beyond the jurisdiction of the Japanese government. While China only managed to end extraterritoriality in 1943, Japan managed to conclude several treaties in the 1890s that led to the end of extraterritoriality in 1899 – despite the lobbying of foreign businesspeople against this move. This meant that starting in 1899, foreign banks in Japan were subject to Japanese law.Footnote 61 As a result, after 1899, they were not able to enjoy the benefits of extraterritoriality still enjoyed by their counterparts in China, such as the right to issue bank notes or the security of their deposits from the host government mentioned above. This meant that Japanese banks were legally equal to foreign banks and was yet another reason why compared to China Japan provided foreign banks with a less hospitable business environment.

This survey of the development of modern financial institutions in pre-WW1 China and Japan – in particular vis-à-vis foreign banks – shows in detail the difference in financial reform that took place after the first entry of foreign banks into these countries. Japan not only put a much greater emphasis on financial reform during the Meiji Restoration, but also started its endeavor in this regard much earlier than China. The main underlying reason seems to have been that while China first chose to mainly pursue modernization in the fields of military and industry and even during the New Policies reform did not particularly pursue financial reform, Japan focused much more on finance. In addition, what also needs to be kept in mind is that – mainly due to the relative disinterest of the foreign powers in Japan as compared to China – Japan enjoyed a “breathing space” of two to three decades after the 1850s free from Western political interference that made it easier for the Japanese government to enact far-reaching reforms.Footnote 62

As a result, a modern banking sector developed much more quickly in Japan than in China. This alone meant that, unlike in China, foreign banks did not remain the main modern banking institutions for long and were thus given less space to extend their activities beyond their specialty in foreign exchange business. Furthermore, Japanese financial reform also directly and specifically addressed the presence of foreign banks in Japan and sought to restrain their influence and build up Japanese competition with them. This started already during the late Tokugawa era, when only the house of Mitsui was allowed to interact with foreign banks, continued with the establishment of the Yokohama Exchange Company and its note issuance and finally culminated in the establishment of the YSB, which was directly aimed at competing with foreign banks in their speciality, the exchange business. Finally, the early abolition of extraterritoriality in Japan meant that Japanese and foreign banks were on a level playing field legally as well. In contrast, not only did modern Chinese banking reform occur relatively late and remained rudimentary before World War I, but beyond proclamations of wanting to compete with foreign banks little specific measures like the establishment of a special exchange bank along the lines of the Japanese YSB were taken to build up such competition. We will see the consequences of this difference once we look in detail at the business of foreign banks in modern China and Japan in the areas of foreign trade finance and the issuing of public loans on Western capital markets.

Foreign trade finance

If we now first look at the trade finance business of foreign banks in Japan, we see that it was markedly influenced by the appearance of the Yokohama Specie Bank. Prior to the emergence of the YSB, the financing of Japan's foreign trade had been dominated by foreign banks.Footnote 63 In his report on the 1885 trade of Kanagawa prefecture, where Yokohama is located, British consul Russel Robertson explained that the YSB “has again competed strongly with the foreign banks […] and has compelled the foreign banks to ship off to China and India the greater portion of their silver ordinarily required for the payment of exports.”Footnote 64 In January 1887, the British minister to Japan Francis Plunkett also reported to London about the “competition which [the] Japanese Specie Bank in Yokohama is carrying on against the European banks in that Port.” Referring to the last half-yearly report of the YSB, he in particular stressed the “remarkable development which has taken place in the number of foreign bills which have been received by that institution.” These amounted to “upwards of 13.5 millions of dollars, and represents so much business taken out of the hands of the local European banks who formerly had the trade to themselves.”Footnote 65 This shows how much the YSB had already managed to cut into the trade finance business of foreign banks in Japan by this time. According to the foreign banks in Yokohama, the YSB actively undercut their foreign competitors by “buy[ing] at fictitious rates and considerably under the market quotations.”Footnote 66 Supported by the discount facilities provided by the Bank of Japan, the YSB also tried to compete with foreign banks in other ways, such as offering loans at a lower interest rate.Footnote 67 Relying on its vast silver reserves, which, as explained above, had partly been supplied by the Japanese government, the YSB quickly became particularly popular with “Japanese merchants, especially those engaged in ‘direct export,’ which is no doubt attributable to the exceptional facilities the Bank has been lately enabled to offer to its customers through its possession of a superabundance of silver.”Footnote 68

As Figure 3 shows, the YSB managed to break through the monopoly of foreign banks in the financing of Japan's foreign trade, gradually increasing its share of trade finance between 1892 and 1912 and by 1912 handled almost half of it.Footnote 69 Such competition from the YSB, combined with the growth of ordinary Japanese private banks that offered modern banking services, helps explain why the number of foreign banks in Japan remained so limited.

Figure 3. Proportion of Foreign Exchange of Japanese Foreign Trade Handled by the Yokohama Specie Bank, 1892–1914 (in %).

Source: Ōkurashō 1940, pp. 478–479.

If we now look at the situation in China, it is not surprising that the business of financing China's foreign trade remained in the hands of foreign banks given the absence of modern Chinese financial institutions that specialized in trade finance. Moreover, none of the few modern Chinese banks that were established before World War I had established branches abroad. Thus, August Reiß, who was an employee of the German Deutsch-Asiatische Bank, a bank that had been active in China and Japan before WWI, in a 1921 essay on the Chinese banking sector described the financing of China's import and export trade as the exclusive business of foreign banks without mentioning any participation by Chinese banks.Footnote 70 In view of the rapidly growing Chinese foreign trade (see Fig. 4), it is not surprising then that China saw such an influx of foreign banks before World War I, who could operate in China without domestic competition. At the same time, it should be pointed out that in comparison with Japan, China's foreign trade was simply larger in absolute terms, as can be seen in Figure 4.Footnote 71 This means that not only the absence of domestic competition but also the generally larger value of foreign trade made China the more attractive market for foreign banks.

Figure 4. Value of Japanese and Chinese Foreign Trade in million Shanghai Taels, 1881–1913.

Source: China: Hsiao Reference Hsiao1974, pp. 22–23 (Haiguan taels converted to Shanghai taels at the rate 1:1.114. See Hsiao Reference Hsiao1974, p. 16. I have used the figures for “imports”, not “net imports”). Japan: Nihon Ginkō Tōkeikyoku Reference Nihon1966, pp. 278–279; Exchange Rate Yen-Shanghai Taels: Asahi Shinbun Reference Asahi1930, pp. 414–415.

Foreign capital markets

Another area of business of foreign banks in both China and Japan was the floating of loans on Western capital markets for the Chinese and Japanese governments. Before the mid- nineteenth century, neither China nor Japan possessed the ability to raise large long-term debt domestically on its own.Footnote 72 As I explained in the first section of this article, before 1914, the Chinese government issued loans worth £149 million on foreign bond markets, while the Japanese government's public foreign loans amounted to £181.4 million. Both governments borrowed relatively small sums before the 1890s and then raised much larger sums between the 1890s and the First World War. In both cases, foreign banks played an important role in the issuing of these loans. However, a closer look at the history of Chinese and Japanese foreign borrowing shows that there existed important structural differences in the pattern of borrowing and the involvement of foreign banks.

Both Japan and China entered Western bond markets during the 1870s. Japan issued its first loan for £1 million at 9% interest in London in 1870. The loan was initially arranged by Horatio Nelson Lay, who had previously worked as a British diplomat in China. He tried to charge the Meiji government an additional 3% interest as a surcharge. In reaction to this, the Meiji government transferred the handling of the loan to the Oriental Bank Corporation. Japan tapped the London bond market once more with the help of the Oriental Bank in 1873, but, unhappy with the high interest rate it had to pay, it thereafter abstained from foreign capital markets.Footnote 73 In largely abstaining from using foreign capital during the early phase of modern economic development, Japan was an exception amongst developing countries.Footnote 74 However, the Japanese government was able to raise capital domestically, having established a “public-loan system, based upon that in vogue in Western countries” shortly after the Meiji restoration of 1868. Matsukata Masayoshi, Japanese minister of finance during the 1880s, lauded the consolidation of previous debts contracted between 1844 and 1871 into new public domestic debt that inaugurated this new system of government borrowing as one of “the greatest reforms brought about since the Restoration.”Footnote 75 Indeed, it allowed Japan to borrow around ¥235 million (~£26 million) in domestic debt between 1873 and 1884.Footnote 76 Japan used domestic borrowing not only to repay old debts and provide pensions, but also to raise capital for the development of railways and the navy.Footnote 77 This explains why Japan was able to abstain from foreign capital markets for such a long time. In addition to the financial reforms already discussed above, the establishment of a system for domestic borrowing thus was another institutional reform that allowed Japan to rely less on foreign banks, in this case as mediators with foreign capital markets.

If we now look at China's early public borrowing, we see a somewhat different development. After the first Chinese loan was floated on the London bond market in 1874, over the next two decades until the end of the Sino-Japanese War in 1895, it issued twenty more public loans on Western capital markets, most of them through the HSBC on the London market.Footnote 78 One reason for this was that, unlike Japan, China faced two large military conflicts before the Sino-Japanese War, the military campaign to reconquer Xinjiang and the Sino-French War of 1884/1885. For these military campaigns alone, China contracted eight of the twenty loans. Four more loans were contracted to finance China's war effort against Japan in the Sino-Japanese War.Footnote 79 Another difference to Japan was that China did not manage to establish a system for raising large sums of capital through domestic borrowing. The Chinese central government tried to issue domestic bonds three times before 1911 with very limited success. Most importantly, in 1898 it attempted unsuccessfully to issue bonds for the repayment of part of the Japanese war indemnity and had to switch back to foreign borrowing thereafter.Footnote 80 Thus, we see in the area of public finance yet another institutional shortcoming of China as compared to Japan that gave foreign banks a greater role in the Chinese economy. Moreover, the demand in China for foreign capital also was an additional factor that could draw foreign banks into the Chinese market. For example, when the German Deutsch-Asiatische Bank decided to enter the Chinese market, it initially did so primarily with the hope of floating Chinese loans for infrastructure projects on the German capital market.Footnote 81 Had China been able to develop an effective mechanism for raising large sums of capital domestically, this would not only likely have meant that it would not have needed to resort to foreign borrowing as much, but it would also have meant that China would have been a less attractive market for foreign financiers and banks.

If we now turn to the period of heavy Chinese and Japanese foreign borrowing between the 1890s and the First World War, we see yet another difference between Japan and China. Despite the fact that Japan borrowed a larger total sum than China during this period, it did only have to tap foreign capital markets eleven times to raise £178 million.Footnote 82 In comparison, China had to float twenty-four loans to raise the sum of around £133 million pounds between the end of the Sino-Japanese War in 1895 and 1913.Footnote 83 Japan raised these loans mainly through one core group of banks that became known as the “London Group” and came to monopolize the floating of Japanese loans on foreign bond markets. Its key members were the HSBC, Parr's Bank in London and, importantly, the YSB.Footnote 84 Japan's ability to borrow such a large sum with a relatively small number of loans certainly was helped by its adoption of the gold standard in 1897, which made it easier to tap foreign capital markets.Footnote 85 Moreover, it reflects the centralization of political power and the control of state finance in the hands of the Japanese central government,Footnote 86 which made it possible to concentrate borrowing on a few important loans. The fact that Japan's foreign borrowing was conducted in such a concentrated manner through a small number of loans and mainly one banking syndicate meant that other foreign banks or syndicates had less of an opportunity to become involved in floating Japanese government loans abroad.Footnote 87 Moreover, the involvement of the YSB in the London group gave the Japanese government greater autonomy in acting in London and showed that Japan was an active participant on Western bond markets and not exclusively dependent on foreign banks.

If we turn to China, we not only see a higher number of smaller loans during this period, but also a larger variety of sources. London remained an important market for Chinese government loans, but Berlin and Paris, and eventually also New York, became important markets for Chinese debt as well. Moreover, no group similar to the London group in the Japanese case emerged. Rather, the Chinese government drew on a lot of different foreign banks and syndicates to borrow foreign capital.Footnote 88 At least in part, this splintering can be explained by the fact that China did not adopt the gold standard and thus found it more difficult to contract loans as large as the Japanese. Moreover, the diffusion of the total borrowed sum into many largely smaller loans also reflects the general political and fiscal devolution of power in the late Qing.Footnote 89 This meant that that foreign capital and the Chinese capacity to borrow was not used in a concentrated manner but rather scattered amongst different interest groups. For example, instead of just borrowing foreign capital to construct one North–South railway trunk line, the Qing borrowed foreign capital to build two.Footnote 90 Thus, compared to Japan, China presented foreign banks with much more opportunity to become involved in the floating of Chinese loans abroad. Moreover, in the absence of a Chinese bank that could internationally represent China along the lines of the YSB, China was also always dependent exclusively on foreign banks for its foreign borrowing. This helps to further explain the greater presence of foreign banks in China as compared to Japan.

Conclusion

As this article has shown, the development of foreign banking in modern China and Japan followed different trajectories. While we see a clear growth in the presence of foreign banks in China, as exemplified in treaty ports such as Tianjin, in the overall number of foreign banks reaching over a dozen by 1908 and in the number of foreign bank offices, the presence of foreign banks in Japan largely stagnated and, in comparison, remained limited. Moreover, in terms of geographical distribution, we saw that foreign banks had a presence in many locations along the China coast, whereas it remained confined to four locations in Japan. These different development trajectories can be traced back to the difference in the modernization paths China and Japan followed after the 1860s. China mainly concentrated on industrial and military modernization at first, and even after the 1890s never made financial reform a priority. On the other hand, Japan put financial reform at the center of its reform effort and created institutions that made them less and less dependent on foreign banks. Allen and Donnithorne correctly trace the more specialized and limited operations of foreign banks in Japan to the importance of financial reform and in particular the establishment of the YSB and the intention of not leaving international financial transactions in the hands of foreigners. However, they undervalue how the YSB was specifically tailored toward competing with foreign banks and how this emphasis on checking the influence of foreign banks can be traced back to the late Tokugawa period. Moreover, they neglect the importance of larger structural reforms, such as fiscal centralization and the establishment of a modern market for domestic debt, and the role the YSB played as a representative of the Japanese government, which also made the Meiji government less dependent on foreign banks compared with China. The resulting smaller business of foreign trade finance and limited demand for foreign lenders by Japan explains why foreign banking remained so limited in Japan, but grew more quickly in China, which remained dependent on foreign banks both for financing its trade and for raising capital.

As Geoffrey Jones, Carlos Davila and Gareth Austin have recently argued, many developing countries “faced […] ‘institutional voids’ in their capital, labor, and other markets.”Footnote 91 In modern China and Japan, we can observe this quite clearly in the banking sector, where in the beginning there existed no financial institutions that could offer modern financial services, in particular relating to the financing of foreign trade and the raising of large sums of capital for government purposes. In both cases, foreign banks first filled this void. However, it was only in Japan that this void was soon filled by the Japanese government through financial reforms, including the establishment of the YSB and the development of a system for raising large sums of capital domestically. As a result, Japan became a much less attractive market for foreign banksFootnote 92.

What does all this tell us about multinational banks in different host countries? In general, the findings of this article add to recent speculation in the business history literature that posits that host economies with weaknesses might be prone to attract multinational companies.Footnote 93 Furthermore, based on the case presented in this article, one might suggest that from the perspective of host countries that wish to limit the presence and influence of multinational banks, implementing specific institutional reforms targeted at addressing this institutional void is a good strategy. Conversely, it might be suggested that from the perspective of multinational banks, a market where a large institutional void still exists presents a market with better prospects for establishing and operating a multinational bank. However, given the limited scope of this article, these can only be speculative suggestions. In order to substantiate such speculations, more comparative research of multinational banks in different host countries along the case and parameters presented in this article are necessary.

Competing interests

None.

Acknowledgements

Research for this article was supported by a Hang Seng Bank Golden Jubilee Education Fund for Research grant. For various kinds of help, I am particularly grateful to John D. Wong, Michael Ng, Simon Bytheway, Hans van de Ven and Grace Ballor. I also thank audiences and panelists at the Association for Asian Studies annual conference 2022 and the World Economic History Congress 2022. I am also grateful to the anonymous reviewers for their comments.

Footnotes

1 On this expansion, see for example Curry et al., Reference Curry, Fung, Harper, Mullineux and Murinde2003; Jones Reference Jones and Jones1990b.

2 For studies that have comprehensively studied the expansion of multinational banks during this period, see Bovykin and Cameron Reference Bovykin and Cameron1991; Jones Reference Jones1990a. For individual histories of specific multinational banks, see for example Jones Reference Jones1986 and Kobrak Reference Kobrak2007. The outstanding example of an extensive study that covers the multinational banks of a nationality comprehensively, is Jones Reference Jones1995. Similar but much shorter studies of multinational banks of a specific nationality can also be found in some of the individual chapters of the two edited volumes by Jones, Bovykin, and Cameron cited above. For studies of multinational banking in a particular host country, see, for example, Malik Reference Malik2018.

3 Wilkins Reference Wilkins1994, quotation on p. 44.

4 Besides Allen and Donnithorne Reference Allen and Donnithorne1962 discussed below, for another comparative study of China and Japan, see, for instance, Moulder Reference Moulder1977. However, Moulder only covers finance and banking very briefly and superficially in passing.

5 For China, see for example: Horesh Reference Horesh2009; King Reference King1988; King Reference King1989; Moazzin Reference Moazzin2020; Moazzin Reference Moazzin2022; Wang Reference Wang1999. For Japan, see Tatewaki, Reference Tatewaki1987; Tatewaki Reference Tatewaki2002.

6 Allen and Donnithorne Reference Allen and Donnithorne1962, Chapters 6 and 13 and conclusion. The first quotation is from the conclusion, the second from chapter 13. Their insistence that not only the presence of foreign banks in Japan was more “limited” but their function also more “specialized” seems to mainly stem from the attention they pay to the issuing of currency by foreign banks in China. However, the notes issued by foreign banks were of much less importance to the Chinese economy than previously thought. See Horesh Reference Horesh2009. Thus, I mainly focus my attention in this article to the financing of foreign trade and the floating of loans on foreign capital markets, two areas of business that foreign banks had a major involvement in in both China and Japan. With regards to sources, the only exception of a Chinese language source used by Allen and Donnithorne is their use of a source by Mou Shou-yu from 1947 (for which they do not provide the original Chinese title) when discussing banking in the 1930s. As for Moulder's (Reference Moulder1977) comparison of China and Japan, Moulder only briefly notes the “much more circumscribed” role of foreign banks in Japan. See Moulder Reference Moulder1977, p. 141. There, she explains: “[Foreign banks] could not make profits on handling revenues placed in security for indemnities because there were no indemnities, nor on handling revenues placed in security for loans, because security was not demanded. And because there was little foreign manufacturing or other business enterprise in Japan, they were also deprived of profits from holding the accounts of such firms, making loans, and the like.” She does not elaborate in more detail though and rather narrates it as part of her larger thesis about the greater autonomy Japan enjoyed from the Western-dominated global economic system. On Moulder also see my discussion of “breathing space” below and footnote 62.

7 This article also builds on my work on foreign banks in modern China, in which I point out that foreign banks in China benefitted from the “institutional void” left open by the lack of modern Chinese financial institutions. There, I also briefly make a comparison with Japan and comment that due to Japanese reforms “foreign banks played a much more limited role in the Japanese economy”. See Moazzin Reference Moazzin2022, especially the conclusion (quotation on p. 270). For the concept of the “institutional void”, see Austin et al., Reference Austin, Dávila and Jones2017 and the conclusion of this article.

8 Wang Reference Wang1999, p. 14; Hamashita Reference Hamashita1974, p. 230.

10 Baster Reference Baster1934; Tamagna Reference Tamagna1942, p. 24; Cheng Reference Cheng2003, pp. 17–18.

11 Hamashita Reference Hamashita1974, pp. 230–231; Cheng Reference Cheng2003, p. 18.

12 On currency, see Horesh Reference Horesh2009. On loans to Chinese banks and acceptance of Chinese deposits, see Moazzin Reference Moazzin2020.

14 Horesh Reference Horesh2009, pp. 11, 13–14; Moazzin Reference Moazzin2020.

15 King Reference King1988, pp. 547–559.

16 Moazzin Reference Moazzin2022, chapters 2 and 6.

17 Hongkong Daily Press 1889, pp. 478–484; Hongkong Daily Press 1914, pp. 780–800.

19 King Reference King1988, pp. 548–549, 553, 557; King Reference King1989, pp. 244–245, 312, 377, 451, 454–455.

20 Moazzin Reference Moazzin2022, Appendix 2. The table in the appendix is based on Tōa Dōbun Shoin Daigaku Reference Tōa Dōbun1908, pp. 811–814 and Hong Kong Daily Press 1908. There is further evidence that even more foreign banks had entered China by then. See Moazzin Reference Moazzin2022, pp. 99–102, 239–241.

21 MacKenzie Reference MacKenzie1954, pp. 94–95.

22 Tatewaki Reference Tatewaki1987, pp. 27, 30.

23 Footnote Ibid., pp. 81, 89, 98, 108.

24 Footnote Ibid., p. 39. It should be pointed out that, unlike Moazzin (Reference Moazzin2022), Tatewaki (Reference Tatewaki1987, Reference Tatewaki2002) does not view the Nederlandsche Handel-Maatsschappij as a foreign bank before 1913/14.

25 Fox Reference Fox1969, pp. 380–381; Tatewaki Reference Tatewaki1987, chapter 3.

26 MacKenzie Reference MacKenzie1954, 95–99.

27 Tatewaki Reference Tatewaki1987, 41.

28 Footnote Ibid., chapters 2 and 3.

29 Ōkurashō rizaikyoku 1900, Gaikoku ginkō meikan: pp. 1–2. This source provides information on the state of banking in Japan on the last day of 1899.

30 Tatewaki Reference Tatewaki2002, pp. 1–12,14–22, 31–32, 38–42.

31 Ōkurashō ginkōkyoku 1914, pp. 386–387. This source provides information on the state of banking in Japan on the last day of 1913. I have not counted the Anglo-Japanese Bank, which decided to leave Japan in 1913. See Tatewaki Reference Tatewaki2002, pp. 31–32.

32 Bytheway Reference Bytheway2014, pp. 87–106; Suzuki Reference Suzuki1994, pp. 198–199.

33 For the total number of offices in China, see Moazzin Reference Moazzin2022, Appendix 2. On the sources used in this appendix, also see footnote 20. As stated in the Appendix, the minor ports of Harbin, Jilin, Changchun, Kulun, and Tieling are not included.

34 Cheng Reference Cheng2003, pp. 10–16; 20–23.

35 Xia Reference Xia1982, pp. 679–690.

36 Xie Reference Xie2000, pp. 3–4. In this article, all translations of quotations from Chinese and Japanese sources are my own. I translate yinhang as “modern banks”. On the terminology, see Cheng Reference Cheng2003, p. 17.

38 On the role of nationalism and rivalry with foreign banks as a driving force behind the establishment of the first modern Chinese bank more broadly, see Cheng Reference Cheng2003, pp. 23–25.

39 Zhang Reference Zhang2003, p. 293.

40 Footnote Ibid., 295–300.

41 Rowe Reference Rowe2009, pp. 214–216.

42 Xia Reference Xia1992, pp. 184–185. Xia lists banking as one of the industries that was brought up before 1895 but was only pursued, “with great power and at great scale”, between 1895 and 1901. However, he only specifically discusses the establishment of the Imperial Bank of China in this context, whose limited impact on the banking system is discussed below. See Xia Reference Xia1992, pp. 471–472.

43 Rowe Reference Rowe2009, pp. 255–262; Zhou Reference Zhou2002, pp. 116–123; Zhou Reference Zhou2000, pp. 407–412; Ichiko Reference Ichiko, Fairbank and Liu1980.

44 Cheng Reference Cheng2003, pp. 25–36, quotation on p. 36; Kong Reference Kong1991, p. 362; Miyashita Reference Miyashita1941, p. 41. Miyashta gives the number of seventeen modern Chinese banks established before 1911. In terms of the Imperial Bank of China's competing with foreign banks, Cheng explains that its note issuance remained small compared to foreign banks and also only gives a few examples of the IBC providing loans to foreign trade firms, which does not seem to suggest that the Imperial Bank of China became an important player in the financing of China's foreign trade. In fact, from Cheng's description and his source (Zhongguo Renmin Yinhang Shanghai shi fenhang jinrong yanjiu shi 1982, pp. 149–150), it is unclear how these trading firms actually used these loans and whether they constituted the actual financing of international trade. Shiroyama (Reference Shiroyama, Nishimura and Sugawara2020), discussed below, does not mention the Imperial Bank of China in the context of the international banking activities of Chinese banks.

45 Such competition really only set in during the post-WW1 era. See Cheng Reference Cheng2003, chapter 3.

46 In contrast, they seem to have had little contact with piaohao. See Moazzin Reference Moazzin2020.

47 Allen Reference Allen1981, p. 45; Bratter Reference Bratter1931, p. 13; Dai-ichi Ginko 1902, pp. 1–3.

48 Schiltz Reference Schiltz2006, pp. 183–184.

49 Tamaki Reference Tamaki1994a, p. 18.

50 Shibusawa Reference Shibusawa, Ōkuma and Huish1910, pp. 487–490, quotations on p. 489; Tamaki Reference Tamaki1994a, chapters 3 and 5. Tamaki notes the Japanese intention to not leave banking to foreigners. This is also noted by Allen and Donnithorne, though only with regards to the YSB. See, Allen and Donnithorne Reference Allen and Donnithorne1962, pp. 213, 216.

51 Shibusawa Reference Shibusawa, Ōkuma and Huish1910, pp. 491–495, quotation on p. 494.

52 Footnote Ibid., 490; Tatewaki Reference Tatewaki1987, p. 57.

54 Ōkurashō 1905, p. 122; Nihon Ginkō Reference Nihon1982, pp. 27–29; Tamaki Reference Tamaki1994a, p. 64; Shibusawa Reference Shibusawa, Ōkuma and Huish1910, pp. 517–518.

55 Ōkurashō 1905, p. 122; Ōkurashō 1917, pp. 118, 125.

56 Miyashita Reference Miyashita1941, p. 41.

57 Shibusawa Reference Shibusawa, Ōkuma and Huish1910, pp. 509–510, quotations from p. 509; Tōkyō Ginkō Reference Tōkyō1981, pp. 27–28. As Shibusawa points out, the YSB began its business in 1880.

58 Quoted in Tōkyō Ginkō Reference Tōkyō1981, p. 28.

59 Tamaki Reference Tamaki1994a, pp. 47, 70; Tamaki Reference Tamaki1994b, pp. 73–80, 110–111; Hirschmaier and Yui Reference Hirschmaier and Yui1975, p. 183. Hirschmaier and Yui note that the only special bank that did not “perform specific tasks” was the Bank of Japan.

60 Bratter Reference Bratter1931, p. 163.

61 Tatewaki Reference Tatewaki2002, 1. On extraterritoriality in Japan and China, see Kayaoğlu Reference Kayaoğlu2010, particularly chapters 3 and 5.

62 For this argument, see Norman Reference Norman2014, p. 46; Moulder Reference Moulder1977, particularly pp. 97, 201.

63 Tatewaki Reference Tatewaki2002, pp. 22–23; Bratter Reference Bratter1931, p. 163.

64 Robertson Reference Robertson1886, p. 7.

65 Plunkett to Salisbury (19 January 1887), The National Archives (United Kingdom), CO 129/235, p. 336.

67 Tamaki Reference Tamaki1994b, pp. 79–80.

68 “Summary of News”, North-China Herald (8 October 1884), p. 374. On the new competition the YSB presented for foreign Banks, also see Tatewaki Reference Tatewaki2002, p. 13; Tatewaki Reference Tatewaki1987, p. 57.

69 On this point also see Tatewaki Reference Tatewaki2002, pp. 22–23. For some reason, Tatewaki however claims that in 1899 the YSB financed more than half of Japan's foreign trade without giving a source for this claim.

70 Reiß Reference Reiß and Hellauer1921, 168–176. On the Deutsch-Asiatische Bank, see Moazzin Reference Moazzin2022. The earliest overseas office of a modern Chinese bank (not including modern banks established by overseas Chinese or traditional Chinese remittance houses that handled remittances of Chinese migrants) that Shiroyama (Reference Shiroyama, Nishimura and Sugawara2020) mentions in her study of the international banking activities of Chinese banks is the Bank of China's London Office, which was established in November 1929. As she explains, the Shanghai Commercial and Savings Bank (SCSB), the other modern Chinese bank she discusses, commenced operations in foreign exchange in 1917, but through agency agreements with other banks abroad. According to Shiroyama, the SCSB was the second modern Chinese bank to commence exchange business, with the first being the Zhongfu Bank, established in 1916 (On the Zhongfu Bank, see Jin and Sun Reference Jin and Sun2001, p. 23). For a contemporary source that explains the plans for the opening of the Bank of China's London office in 1929 and its status as the first foreign office of a modern Chinese bank (woguo yinhang), see “中國銀行籌設倫敦分行” “Zhongguo Yinhang choushe Lundun fenhang” [“The Bank of China Plans to Establish a London Office”], Zhongyang yinhang xunbao 12 (1929): 23 (while Shiroyama speaks of an “agency”, the contemporary article uses the Chinese word fenhang, i.e. “branch”, for the London office). It was only during the 1930s that modern Chinese banks were able to compete in handling China's international financial relations. See Hou Reference Hou1965, 54. Also see Allen and Donnithorne Reference Allen and Donnithorne1962 (pp. 34, 102, 106), who, commenting on Chinese financial institutions before the emergence of modern Chinese banks, point to their insufficiency for the financing of international trade.

71 On the greater size of China's foreign trade, also see Moulder Reference Moulder1977, p. 97.

72 See He Reference He2013. He sees this ability as a key feature of the modern fiscal state that Meiji Japan managed to develop but Qing China did not.

73 Bytheway Reference Bytheway2014, pp. 89–90.

74 Macpherson Reference Macpherson1995, p. 27.

75 Matsukata Reference Matsukata, Ōkuma and Huish1910, pp. 372–373, quotations on p. 373; also see Stead Reference Stead1904, pp. 355–356. While Matsukata emphasizes the importance of converting old debt and establishing a modern public-loan system, the establishment of a functioning market for domestic debt was also helped by the modernization of the financial market of Japan and Japanese policies for stabilizing the currency already discussed to some extent above, including the establishment of the Bank of Japan. See Nakabayashi Reference Nakabayashi, Yun-Casalilla, O'Brien and Comin2012, pp. 389–390. In addition, the centralization of government finance was important for enabling the Meiji government to service the domestic debt. See He Reference He2013, p. 127.

76 The figure is calculated from the table listing major Japanese government bond issues during this period in Hiroshi Reference Hiroshi2014, p. 94. As already mentioned, Japan only contracted one foreign public loan during this period. This was a £2.4 million loan issued in London. For the loan details, see Suzuki Reference Suzuki1994, p. 198. The pound figure was calculated with the exchange rate for 1884 using Rodney Edvinsson's Historical Currency Converter on Historicalstatistics.org.

77 It should be pointed out though that private capital also seems to have played an important role in Japanese economic development (for example in railway development), see Bytheway Reference Bytheway2014, p. 88.

78 King Reference King1988, pp. 548–549, 557.

80 Van de Ven Reference Van de Ven2014, pp. 141–142; Zhou Reference Zhou2002, pp. 193–194.

81 Moazzin Reference Moazzin2022, chapter 1. There, I also explain the role of Chinese demand for foreign capital in the establishment of the Deutsch-Asiatische Bank.

82 Suzuki Reference Suzuki1994, pp. 198–199.

83 King Reference King1989, pp. 244–245, 312, 377, 451, 454–455. Also see footnote 19.

84 Bytheway Reference Bytheway2014, p. 97.

87 It should be pointed out though that despite the dominance of the London group and London market in the issuing of Japanese debt, Japan also floated debt on the German, French and American market during this period, though even in these cases often together with the London group. See Bytheway Reference Bytheway2014, pp. 91–94.

88 For an overview of public loans between 1895 and 1913, see King Reference King1989, pp. 244–245, 312, 377, 451, 454–455. For more details on individual loans, see Kuhlmann Reference Kuhlmann1982, pp. 26–90.

89 Fairbank and Goldman Reference Fairbank and Goldman2006, p. 238; Rowe Reference Rowe2009, pp. 204–207; Von Glahn Reference Von Glahn2016, chapter 9.

90 Moazzin Reference Moazzin2022, chapter 4; Kuhlmann Reference Kuhlmann1982.

91 Austin et al., Reference Austin, Dávila and Jones2017, p. 542.

92 As pointed out in footnote 7, on the connection between this institutional void and the success of foreign banks in pre-WWI China, also see Moazzin Reference Moazzin2022, particularly the conclusion. There, some adjacent literature is also discussed (see pp. 18–19n52 and pp. 67–68n44) and a brief comparison with Japan is made. In Moazzin Reference Moazzin2022, I also discuss that after 1914 the rise of modern Chinese banks and financial reform led to the shrinking of the institutional void once occupied by foreign banks. On comments by Cheng (Reference Cheng2003) and Allen and Donnithorne (Reference Allen and Donnithorne1962) on the connection between financial reform and the rise of modern banks and the position of foreign banks in China, see Moazzin Reference Moazzin2022, p. 271n12.

93 Jones Reference Jones2005, p. 260.

References

Allen, G.C. (1981) A Short Economic History of Modern Japan, 4th edn. London: Macmillan.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Allen, G.C. and Donnithorne, A. (1962) Western Enterprise in Far Eastern Economic Development, China and Japan. London: Allen & Unwin.Google Scholar
Asahi, Shinbun. (1930) 日本経済統計総観 Nihon keizai tōkei sōkan [Overview of Japanese Economic Statistics]. Osaka: Asahi Shinbun.Google Scholar
Austin, G., Dávila, C. and Jones, G. (2017) The alternative business history: business in emerging markets. Business History Review 91(3), 537–69.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Baster, A.S.J. (1934) The origins of the British exchange banks in China. Economic History (Supplement to the Economic Journal) 3(9), 140151.Google Scholar
Bovykin, V.I. and Cameron, R. (1991) International Banking, 1870–1914. New York: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Bratter, H. (1931) Japanese Banking. Washington: Government Printing Office.Google Scholar
Bytheway, S.J. (2014) Investing Japan : Foreign Capital, Monetary Standards, and Economic Development, 1859–2011. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Asia Center.Google Scholar
Cheng, L. (2003) Banking in Modern China: Entrepreneurs, Professional Managers, and the Development of Chinese Banks, 1897–1937. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Curry, E., Fung, J. and Harper, I. (2003) Multinational banking: historical, empirical and case perspectives. In Mullineux, AW and Murinde, V (eds.), Handbook of International Banking. Cheltenham: Edward Elgar, 2759.Google Scholar
Dai-ichi Ginko. (1902) A Short History of the Dai-ichi Ginko. Tokyo: Tokyo Printing Co.Google Scholar
Fairbank, J.K. and Goldman, M. (2006) China: A New History, Second Enlarged Edition. Cambridge, MA: Belknap.Google Scholar
Fox, G. (1969) Britain and Japan 1858–1883. Oxford: Clarendon P.Google Scholar
Gordon, A. (2003) A Modern History of Japan: From Tokugawa Times to the Present. Oxford: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Hamashita, T. 濱下武志. (1974) 十九世紀後半, 中国における外国銀行の金融市場支配の歴史的特質: 上海における金融恐慌との関連において Jukyuseiki-kohan, Chugoku niokeru Gaikoku-Ginko no Kinyushihai no Rekishi-teki-Tokushitsu: Shanhai niokeru Kinyukyoko tono Kanren Nioite [The historical characteristics of the domination of the financial market by foreign banks in China during the second half of the 19th century: with regards to the financial crisis in Shanghai]. Shakaikeizaishi gaku 40(3), 228245.Google Scholar
He, W. (2013) Paths Toward the Modern Fiscal State: England, Japan, and China. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hiroshi, K. 釜江廣志. (2014) 戦前債券市場と引受シ団の変遷 Senzen saiken shijō to hikiuke shidan no hensen [The Prewar bond market and the changes in the underwriting syndicates]. Tōkyō keidai gakkaishi 281, 93141.Google Scholar
Hirschmaier, J. and Yui, T. (1975) The Development of Japanese Business, 1600–1981. London: Allen & Unwin.Google Scholar
Hongkong Daily Press. (1889) The Chronicle & Directory for China, Corea, Japan, The Phillipines, Cochin-China, Annam, Tonquin, Siam, Borneo, Straits Settlements, Malay States, &c. For the Year 1889. Hong Kong: Hong Kong Daily Press.Google Scholar
Hongkong Daily Press. (1908) The Directory & Chronicle for China, Japan, Corea, Indo-China, Straits Settlements, Malay States, Siam, Netherlands India, Borneo, the Philippines, &c. for the Year 1908. Hong Kong: The Hongkong Daily Press.Google Scholar
Hongkong Daily Press. (1914) The Directory & Chronicle for China, Japan, Corea, Indo-China, Straits Settlements, Malay States, Siam, Netherlands India, Borneo, the Philippines, &c. For the Year 1914. Hong Kong: Hong Kong Daily Press.Google Scholar
Horesh, N. (2009) Shanghai's Bund and Beyond: British Banks, Banknote Issuance, and Monetary Policy in China, 1842–1937. New Haven, Ct: Yale University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hou, C. (1965) Foreign Investment and Economic Development in China, 1840–1937. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hsiao, L. (1974) China's Foreign Trade Statistics, 1864–1949. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Asia Center.Google Scholar
Ichiko, C. (1980) Political and Institutional Reform 1901–11. In Fairbank, JK and Liu, KC (eds). The Cambridge History of China Vol. 11. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 375415.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ishii, K. (2002) British-Japanese rivalry in trading and banking. In Hunter, E and Sugiyama, S (eds.), The History of Anglo-Japanese Relations, 1600–2000: Volume IV: Economic and Business Relations. New York: Palgrave, 110132.Google Scholar
Jin, P. 金普森 and Sun, S. 孫善根. (2001) 寧波大辭典 Ningbo dacidian [Great Dictionary on Ningbo]. Ningbo: Ningbo chubanshe.Google Scholar
Jones, G. (1986) Banking and Empire in Iran: Volume 1: The History of the British Bank of the Middle East. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Jones, G. (ed.). (1990a) Banks as Multinationals. London: Routledge.Google Scholar
Jones, G. (1990b) Banks as multinationals. In Jones, G (ed.). Banks as Multinationals. London: Routledge, 112.Google Scholar
Jones, G. (1995) British Multinational Banking, 1830–1990. Oxford: Clarendon Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Jones, G. (2005) Multinationals and Global Capitalism: From the Nineteenth to the Twenty-First Century. Oxford: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Kayaoğlu, T. (2010) Legal Imperialism: Sovereignty and Extraterritoriality in Japan, the Ottoman Empire, and China. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
King, F.H.H. (1988) The History of the Hongkong and Shanghai Banking Corporation: Volume 1, The Hongkong Bank in Late Imperial China 1864–1902: On an Even Keel. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
King, F.H.H. (1989) The History of the Hongkong and Shanghai Banking Corporation: Volume 2, The Hongkong Bank in the Period of Imperialism and War, 1895–1918: Wayfoong, the Focus of Wealth. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
King, F.H.H. (1991) Extra-Regional Banks and Investment in China. In Cameron, R and Bovykin, I (eds.), International Banking 1870–1914. Oxford: Oxford University Press, 371405.Google Scholar
Kobrak, C. (2007) Banking on Global Markets: Deutsche Bank and the United States, 1870 to Present. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Kong, X. 孔祥賢. (1991) 大淸銀行行史 Daqing Yinhang hangshi [History of the Daqing Bank]. Nanjing: Nanjing daxue chubanshe.Google Scholar
Kuhlmann, W. (1982) China's Foreign Debt, 1865–1982. Hannover.Google Scholar
MacKenzie, C. (1954) Realms of Silver: One Hundred Years of Banking in the East. London: Routledge.Google Scholar
Macpherson, W.J. (1995) The Economic Development of Japan, 1868–1941. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Malik, H. (2018) Bankers and Bolsheviks: International Finance and the Russian Revolution. Princeton: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Matsukata, M. (1910) Japan's Finance. In Ōkuma, S and Huish, MB (eds.), Fifty Years of New Japan (Kiakoku Gojūnen Shi), 2nd edn., vol. 1. London: Smith, Eleder & Co, 359389.Google Scholar
Miyashita, T. 宮下忠雄. (1941) 支那銀行制度論 Shina ginkō seidoron [A Discussion of the Banking System of China]. Tokyo: Ganshodo shoten.Google Scholar
Moazzin, G. (2020) Sino-foreign business networks: foreign and Chinese banks in the Chinese banking sector, 1890–1911. Modern Asian Studies 54(3), 9701004.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Moazzin, G. (2022) Foreign Banks and Global Finance in Modern China: Banking on the Chinese Frontier, 1870–1919. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Moulder, F. (1977) Japan, China, and the Modern World Economy: Toward a Reinterpretation of East Asian Development ca. 1600 to ca. 1918. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Nakabayashi, M. (2012) The Rise of a Japanese Fiscal State. In Yun-Casalilla, B, O'Brien, PK and Comin, F (eds.), The Rise of Fiscal States: A Global History, 1500–1914. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 378409.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Nihon, Ginkō Tōkeikyoku. (1966) 明治以降本邦主要経済統計 Meiji ikō honpō shuyō keizai tōkei [Major Economic Statistics of Our Country since the Meiji Period]. Tokyo: Nihon shinyō chōsa.Google Scholar
Nihon, Ginkō 日本銀行. (1982) 日本銀行百年史1 Nihon Ginkō hyakunenshi 1 [One Hundred-Year History of the Bank of Japan 1]. Tokyo: Nihon Ginko.Google Scholar
Norman, E.H. (2014) Japan's Emergence as a Modern State: Political and Economic Problems of the Meiji Period. 60th Anniversary Edition. Vancouver: UBC Press.Google Scholar
Ōkurashō. (1905) The Fifth Financial & Economic Annual of Japan. Tokyo: Government Printing Office.Google Scholar
Ōkurashō. (1917) The Seventeenth Financial & Economic Annual of Japan. Tokyo: Government Printing Office.Google Scholar
Ōkurashō. (1940) 明治大正財政史 第 17 巻 Meiji Taishō Zaiseishi Dai 17 kan [Financial History of the Meiji and Taisho eras, Volume 17]. Tokyo: Zaisei Keizai Gakkai.Google Scholar
Ōkurashō rizaikyoku 大蔵省理財局. (1900) 銀行総覧 第 7 回 Ginkō sōran dai 7 kai [Bank Compendium No. 7]. Tokyo: Hakubunkaku.Google Scholar
Ōkurashō rizaikyoku 大蔵省理財局. (1908) 銀行総覧 第 15 回 Ginkō sōran dai 15 kai [Bank Compendium No. 15]. Tokyo: Kumada insatsusho.Google Scholar
Ōkurashō ginkōkyoku 大蔵省銀行局. (1914) 銀行総覧 第 21 回 Ginkō sōran dai 21 kai [Bank Compendium No. 21]. Tokyo: Sanshu sain satsusho.Google Scholar
Reiß, A. (1921) Das Bankwesen in China. In Hellauer, J (ed.). China: Wirtschaft und Wirtschaftsgrundlagen. Berlin: Walter de Gruyter & Co., 168184.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Robertson, R. (1886) Report for the Year 1885 on the Trade of Kanagawa. London: Harrison and Sons.Google Scholar
Rowe, W. (2009) China's Last Empire: The Great Qing. Cambridge, MA: Belknap.Google Scholar
Schiltz, M. (2006) An ‘Ideal bank of issue’: the Banque Nationale de Belgique as a model for the Bank of Japan. Financial History Review 13(2), 179196.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Shibusawa, E. (1910) The Development of Banking in Japan. In Ōkuma, S and Huish, MB (eds.). Fifty Years of New Japan (Kiakoku Gojūnen Shi), 2nd edn., vol. 1. London: Smith, Eleder & Co., 486532.Google Scholar
Shiroyama, T. (2020) Chinese international banking. In Nishimura, Takeshi and Sugawara, Ayumu (eds.), The Development of International Banking in Asia. Tokyo: Springer, 309336.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Stead, A. (1904) Japan by the Japanese. London: W. Heinemann.Google Scholar
Summary of News. North-China Herald (8 October 1884), p. 374.Google Scholar
Suzuki, T. (1994) Japanese Government Loan Issues on the London Capital Market, 1870–1913. London: Athlone.Google Scholar
Tamagna, F.M. (1942) Banking and Finance in China. New York: Inst. of Pacific Relations.Google Scholar
Tamaki, N. (1994a) Japanese Banking. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Tamaki, N. (1994b) 日本金融史 : 安政の開国から高度成長前夜まで Nihon kin'yūshi: Ansei no kaikoku kara kōdo seichō zen'ya made [Financial History of Japan: From the Ansei Period's opening of the Country to the Eve of Rapid Growth]. Tokyo: Yūhikaku.Google Scholar
Tatewaki, K. 立脇和夫. (1987) 在日外国銀行史: 幕末開港から条約改正まで Zainichi gaikoku ginkōshi: bakumatsu kaikō kara jōyaku kaisei made [A History of Foreign Banks in Japan: From the End of the Tokugawa Period to the Changing of the Treaties]. Tōkyō: Nihon Keizai Hyōronsha.Google Scholar
Tatewaki, K. 立脇和夫. (2002) 在日外国銀行百年史: 1900–2000年Zainichi gaikoku ginkō hyakunenshi: 1900–2000-nen [Hundred-year History of Foreign Banks in Japan, 1900–2000]. Tōkyō: Nihon Keizai Hyōronsha.Google Scholar
The National Archives, Kew, United Kingdom.Google Scholar
Tōa Dōbun, Shoin Daigaku (comp). (1908) 志那経済全書 Shina keizai zensho [Compendium about the Chinese Economy], Vol. 6, 3rd edn. Tōkyō: Tōa Dōbunkai.Google Scholar
Tōkyō, Ginkō. (1981) Yokohama shōkin ginkō zenshi, Vol 2. Tokyo: TōkyōoGinkō.Google Scholar
Van de Ven, H.J. (2014) Breaking with the Past: The Maritime Customs Service and the Global Origins of Modernity in China. New York: Columbia University Press.Google Scholar
Von Glahn, R. (2016) The Economic History of China: From Antiquity to the Nineteenth Century. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Wang, J. 汪敬虞. (1999) 外國資本在近代中國的金融活動 Waiguo ziben zai jindai zhongguo de jinrong huodong [The Financial Activities of Foreign Capital in Modern China]. Beijing: Renmin Chubanshe.Google Scholar
Wilkins, M. (1994) Comparative hosts. Business History 36(1), 1850.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Xia, D. 夏東元, (ed.). (1982) 鄭觀應集(上冊)Zheng Guanying ji (shangce) [Collected Works of Zheng Guanying, First Volume]. Shanghai: Shanghai renmin Chubanshe.Google Scholar
Xia, D. 夏東元. (1992) 洋務運動史 Yangwu yundong shi [History of the Foreign Affairs Movement]. Shanghai: Huadong shifan daxue chubanshe.Google Scholar
Xie, J. 謝俊美. (2000) 盛宣懷檔案資料選輯之五:通商銀行 Sheng Xuanhuai dang'an ziliao xuanji zhiwu: zhongguo tongshang yinhang [Selected Archival Materials on Sheng Xuanhuai, Part Five: Tongshang Bank]. Shanghai: Shanghai renmin Chubanshe.Google Scholar
Zhang, G. 張國輝. (2003) 中國金融通史:第二卷 Zhongguo jinrong tongshi: Di er juan [General History of Chinese Finance: Volume Two]. Beijing: Zhongguo jinrong Chubanshe.Google Scholar
Zhongguo Renmin Yinhang Shanghai shi fenhang jinrong yanjiu shi 中國人民銀行上海市分行金融研究室. (1982) 中國第一家銀行: 中國通商銀行的初創時期 (一八九七年至一九一一年) Zhongguo diyi jia yinhang: Zhongguo Tongshang Yinhang de chuchuang shiqi (yibajiuqinian zhi yijiuyiyi nian) [China's first modern Bank: The early period of the Imperial Bank of China (1897 to 1911)]. Beijing: Zhongguo shehui kexue chubanshe.Google Scholar
中國銀行籌設倫敦分行 Zhongguo Yinhang choushe Lundun fenhang [The Bank of China Plans to Establish a London Office]. Zhongyang yinhang xunbao 12(1929): 23.Google Scholar
Zhou, Y. 周育民. (2000) 晚淸財政與社會變遷 Wanqing caizheng yu shehui bianqian [Late Qing Finance and Social Change]. Shanghai: Shanghai renmin Chubanshe.Google Scholar
Zhou, Z. 周志初. (2002) 晚清財政經濟研究Wanqing caizheng jingji yanjiu [A Study of Late Qing Public Finance and Economy]. Jinan: Qilu shushe.Google Scholar
Figure 0

Figure 1. Number of foreign bank offices in Chinese and Japanese Cities in 1908. Bars indicate location and number of foreign banks in that location.Source: Moazzin 2022, Appendix 2 (The appendix does not include the ports of Changchun, Harbin, Tieling, Jilin and Kulun); Ōkurashō rizaikyoku 1908, pp. 416–418 (The latter source provides the state of foreign banks in Japan on the last day of 1907).

Figure 1

Figure 2. Political Cartoon titled “The Puppet player” from the January 1875 issue of the Japan Punch. It depicts the manager of the Oriental Bank Corporation controlling the Tael-Yen exchange rate.

Figure 2

Figure 3. Proportion of Foreign Exchange of Japanese Foreign Trade Handled by the Yokohama Specie Bank, 1892–1914 (in %).Source: Ōkurashō 1940, pp. 478–479.

Figure 3

Figure 4. Value of Japanese and Chinese Foreign Trade in million Shanghai Taels, 1881–1913.Source: China: Hsiao 1974, pp. 22–23 (Haiguan taels converted to Shanghai taels at the rate 1:1.114. See Hsiao 1974, p. 16. I have used the figures for “imports”, not “net imports”). Japan: Nihon Ginkō Tōkeikyoku 1966, pp. 278–279; Exchange Rate Yen-Shanghai Taels: Asahi Shinbun 1930, pp. 414–415.