Hostname: page-component-cd9895bd7-dzt6s Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-12-26T14:54:30.220Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Rising mass incomes as a condition of capitalist growth: implications for the world economy

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  22 May 2009

Get access

Extract

The rise of capitalism in Western Europe was based on rising mass incomes and a political power relationship favorable to the lower classes, which created opportunities for profitable investment. Nowhere in today's underdeveloped world did such conditions exist before the European expansion; nowhere were they created by the mere fact of integration into the capitalist world system. Thus the periphery has been ever more disadvantaged by its connection with the capitalist center. But the center could and can dispense withthe contribution of the periphery and, indeed, on occasion has done so. A planned restructuring of the productive apparatus and social reform in the Third World are both complex and contradictory processes. The working class in the North has to realize its interest in defending the masses of the Third World. It can do so by linking economic concessions in the North-South dialogue (raw material prices or access to markets) to social reform and the creation of a productive apparatus that permits the rise of mass incomes in the Third World.

Type
Articles
Copyright
Copyright © The IO Foundation 1983

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

References

1. This neglects the “problem of transformation” (of labor values into production costs). This is acceptable in the admittedly unrealistic hypothesis of a system of production where in any department (branch) the organic composition of capital is identical. The implications of this simplification are discussed in Elsenhans, Hartmut, “Egalitarisme social et critique des modes de production dans la péiriphérie…,” in European Association of Development and Training Institutes, Discussion entre MM. les professeurs Emmanuel et Elsenhans (Paris: IEDES, 1981), p. 14.Google Scholar

2. This common simplification depends on the assumption that workers consume their whole income while capitalists invest all their profits.

3. This has an important consequence: in the long term, capitalist growth is not possible if there is only capital deepening. So argues Lenin, (Werke [Berlin: Dietz, 1971–], 3:42)Google Scholar, who hypothesizes that effective demand is created by a rising organic composition of capital. The argument is repeated in Palma, Gabriel, “Dependency, A Formal Theory of Underdevelopment or a Methodology for the Analysis of Concrete Situations of Underdevelopment,” World Development 6, 7–8 (07–08 1978), p. 904.CrossRefGoogle Scholar

4. My thesis comes under attack in Arghiri Emmanuel, “Réonse à Hartmut Elsenhans,” in Emmanuel, , Technologie appropriée ou technologie sous-développée (Paris: PUF, 1981), p. 174Google Scholar. His example fails because it does not incorporate the devaluation of constant capital by productivity increases. My thesis is reinforced if the example is transformed into a quantity system or if it includes the devalorization of capital; cf. Elsenhans, , Abhängiger Kapitalismus oder bürokratische Entwicklungsgesellschaft (Frankfurt: Campus, 1981), pp. 292–98.Google Scholar

5. Cf. Leon, Paolo, Structural Change and Growth: A Set of Hypotheses (Baltimore: Johns Hopkins Press, 1967), p. 142.Google Scholar

6. See Chinn, Leslie Dennis, “Potential Effects of Income Redistribution on Economic Growth Constraints: Evidence from Taiwan and South Korea,” Ph.D diss., University of California, Berkeley, 1974, esp. p. 114Google Scholar; and Pashardes, Panos, “Income Distribution, the Structure of Consumer Expenditure and Development Policy,” Journal of Development Studies 16, 2 (01 1980), pp. 224–45CrossRefGoogle Scholar. See the overview of recent literature in Kleiner, Elmar, “Konsumstruktur, Betriebsgrösse und Überwindung von Unterentwicklung, Dargestellt am Beispiel Sri Lankas,” diss., Economics Faculty, Heidelberg University, 1981.Google Scholar

7. The classic statement is Strassmann, W. Paul, “Economic Growth and Income Distribution,” Quarterly Journal of Economics 70, 3 (08 1956), pp. 426–30.CrossRefGoogle Scholar

8. Felix, David, “Technological Dualism in Late Industrializers: On Theory, History and Policy,” Journal of Economic History 34, 1 (03 1974), p. 218.CrossRefGoogle Scholar

9. Without the inflow of precious metals, prices would have fallen; as noted by Heckscher, Eli F., “The Aspects of Economic History,” in Economic Essays in Honour of Gustav Cassel (London: Allen & Unwin, 1933), p. 718.Google Scholar

10. Coffee, tea, sugar, and tobacco constituted the major share of Britain's imports from Asia, Latin America, Africa, and the West Indies. As a percentage of England and Wales's imports from these regions, the four products represent 76% in 1770; 61% in 1780; 68% in 1790; 71% in 1800; 68% in 1810; 94% in 1820. Calculated from Mitchell, B. R. and Deane, Phyllis, Abstracts of British Historical Statistics (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1972).Google Scholar

11. In the mid 19th century Britain produced 60% of the world's tin, 50% of lead, 75% of copper: Musson, Albert E., The Growth of British Industry (London: Batsford, 1978), p. 102Google Scholar. For coal and oil, see Nef, John U., The Rise of the British Coal Industry (London: Cass, 1966), 1:188243Google Scholar, and Regal, Rudolph August, Energieguellen der Welt (Hamburg: Hanseatische Verlagsanstalt, 1937), pp. 16, 52Google Scholar. Between 1876/80 and 1913, 32% to 40% of all world raw material exports came from Asia, Latin America, Africa, and Oceania; but only 16.3% of African raw material exports (11.9% for Asia, 13.2% for Latin America) were minerals. Agricultural raw materials dominated. Calculated from Yates, Paul Lamartine, Forty Years of Foreign Trade: A Statistical Handbook… (London: Allen & Unwin, 1959), pp. 227–40.Google Scholar

12. If Spain and Portugal are included in the periphery and North American colonies are excluded, the periphery took 41% of British exports in 1700; the figure was 43% in 1797/98. Calculated from Deane, Phyllis and Cole, W. A., British Economic Growth, 1688–1959: Trends and Structures (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1967), p. 87.Google Scholar

13. Marx, Karl, Capital, chap. 24 (MEW 23:741ff).Google Scholar

14. I have demonstrated this point in Elsenhans, , “Englisches Poor Law und egalitäre Agrarreform in der Dritten Welt,” Verfassung und Recht in Übersee 13, 4 (1012 1980), pp. 286–92.Google Scholar

15. Elaborated in my Le rôle des multinationales dans une stratégie de besoins de base, quelques notes (Budapest: IEDES, 1981), pp. 59.Google Scholar

16. For example, Amin, Samir, Le développement inégal (Paris: Minuit, 1973), pp. 2427.Google Scholar

17. Habbakuk, H. J., “English Landownership, 1680–1740,” Economic History Review 10, 1 (11 1939), pp. 25Google Scholar, is the earliest statement of the argument.

18. Bowden, Peter, The Wool Trade in Tudor and Stuart England (London: Macmillan, 1962), p. 5CrossRefGoogle Scholar; Mené, MichelLe, L'économie médiévale (Paris: PUF, 1977), p. 11Google Scholar. Eighty percent of sheep-raising in Britain across the period was done by small peasants.

19. Tawney, Richard, The Agrarian Problem in the Sixteenth Century (London: Longmans, Green, 1912), pp. 289, 343, 348, 366Google Scholar. Mingay, Gordon E., English Landed Society in the Eighteenth Century (London: Routledge & Kegan Paul, 1963), p. 185Google Scholar, shows from the poor rates that poverty was not direst in the 18th century's enclosure regions.

20. Jones, E. L., Agriculture and the Industrial Revolution (Oxford: Blackwell, 1974), pp. 96100Google Scholar; Jones, , “Editor's Introduction” to Agriculture and Economic Growth in England, 1650–1815 (London: Methuen, 1967), p. 9Google Scholar; Jones, , “English and European Agricultural Development, 1650–1750,” in Hartwell, R. M., ed., The Industrial Revolution (Oxford: Blackwell, 1970), p. 59Google Scholar; Slicher van Bath, B. H., The Agrarian History of Western Europe, A.D. 500–1850 (London: Arnold, 1963), pp. 266319.Google Scholar

21. John, A. H., “Farming in Wartime: 1793–1815,” in Jones, E. L. and Mingay, G. E., eds., Land, Labour and Population in the Industrial Revolution (London: Arnold, 1967), p. 29Google Scholar: Jones, , “The Agricultural Labour Market in England, 1793–1872,” Economic History Review 17, 2 (1964), pp. 322–38.CrossRefGoogle Scholar

22. Lazonick, William, “Karl Marx and Enclosures in England,” Review of Radical Political Economy 6, 2 (Summer 1974), p. 36CrossRefGoogle Scholar; Saville, John, “Primitive Accumulation and Early Industrialization in Britain,” Socialist Register 5 (1969), pp. 263–70.Google Scholar

23. Thompson, F. M. L., “Landownership and Economic Growth in England in the Eighteenth Century,” in Jones, E. L. and Wolf, S. J., eds., Agrarian Change and Economic Development: The Historical Problems (London: Methuen, 1969), p. 48Google Scholar: peasants could not be forced to sell their land, because they could always revert to subsistence production. Cf. van Bath, Slicher, Agrarian History, p. 319Google Scholar: rural labor was pulled to industrial work by higher wages, not pushed by pauperization. Moore, Barrington, Social Origins of Dictatorship and Democracy (New York: Beacon, 1966)Google Scholar lacks clarity on this point: “for the ‘surplus’ peasant it made little difference whether the pull from the towns or factories was more important than the push out of his rural world” (p. 29).

24. Wallerstein, Immanuel, The Modern World-System: Capitalist Agriculture and the Origins of the European World-Economy in the Sixteenth Century (New York: Academic Press, 1974), p. 80.Google Scholar

25. Duby, Georges, Krieger und Bauern (Frankfurt: Syndikat, 1977), pp. 182278Google Scholar; Braudel, Fernand, La Méditerranée et le monde méditerranéen à l'époque de Philippe II (Paris: Colin, 1966), 1:67Google Scholar; Anderson, Perry, Lineages of the Absolutist State (London: NLB, 1974), pp. 185205Google Scholar; Anderson, , Passages from Antiquity to Feudalism (London: NLB, 1974), p. 57Google Scholar; Rader, Trout, The Economics of Feudalism (New York: Gordon & Breach, 1971), p. 70Google Scholar. Cf. also Pirenne, Henri, Histoire économique de l'Occident médiéval (Bruges: Desclée de Brower, 1951), p. 397Google Scholar: development occurs where labor is successful, as in 15th and 16th century Flanders, retardation where capital is successful, as in Italy.

Note the passage in Damodar, Dharmanand Kosambi, An Introduction to the Study of Indian History (Bombay: Popular Book Depot, 1956)Google Scholar: “The failure of indigenous feudalism ‘from above' [in 14th century India] to develop new techniques is a basic contrast with medieval European feudalism” (p. 328).

26. Hilton, R. H., The Decline of Serfdom in Medieval England (London: Macmillan, 1969), pp. 3957CrossRefGoogle Scholar; Hilton, , “L'Angleterre éonomique et sociale des XIVe et XVe siècles,” Annales E.S.C. 13, 4 (1012 1958), p. 549Google Scholar; Brenner, Robert, “Agrarian Class Structure and Economic Development in Preindustrial Europe,” Past and Present 55 (02 1976), p. 55.Google Scholar

27. “Although after 1381 the former power structure was formally reestablished, its moral basis was broken. Serfdom rapidly disappeared totally. The attempt to raise a poll tax was not even tried. Government was changed in the 15th century. There followed a time of welfare, never seen before, for the English peasantry.” Franz, Günter, Persönlichkeit und Geschichte (Göttingen: Musterschmidt, 1977), p. 89.Google Scholar

28. Wallerstein, , Modern World-System, p. 37Google Scholar. Cf. also Hilton, R. H., “A Crisis of Feudalism,” Past and Present 75 (08 1978), pp. 613.Google Scholar

29. Deane, Phyllis, The First Industrial Revolution (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1965), p. 30Google Scholar. Marx, , Capital, chap. 23 (MEW 23:703)Google Scholar: “Nevertheless, the situation of the English rural labor has never been better since between 1770 and 1780.”

30. Brenner, , “Agrarian Class Structure,” pp. 6769.Google Scholar

31. The most interesting discussion of the problem is Schöffer, I., “The Second Serfdom in Eastern Europe as a Problem of Historical Explanation,” Historical Studies 9, 3 (1959), pp. 4661.Google Scholar

32. Moore, , Social Origins, pp 3031Google Scholar; Lipson, Ephraim, The Economic History of England, vol. 2Google Scholar: The Age of Mercantilism (London: Black, 1931), p. 383Google Scholar, concludes that agricultural laborers were better off than small proprietors in the 18th century.

33. Gilboy, Elizabeth Waterman, “Demand as a Factor in the Industrial Revolution in England,” in Hartwell, R. M., ed., The Causes of the Industrial Revolution in England (London: Methuen, 1967), pp. 126–31Google Scholar; Hartwell, , “The Rising Standard of Living in England, 1800–1850,” Economic History Review 13, 3 (1961), p. 415CrossRefGoogle Scholar; Hartwell, , “The Standard of Living during the Industrial Revolution: A Discussion,” Economic History Review 16, 1 (1964), pp. 135–44CrossRefGoogle Scholar; Eversley, D. E. C., “The Home Market and Economic Growth in England, 1750–1780,” in Jones and Mingay, Land, Labour and Population, pp. 213–25.Google Scholar

34. Redford, Arthur, Labour Migration in England, 1800–1850, ed. and rev, by Chaloner, W. H. (Manchester: Manchester University Press, 1964), pp. 61189Google Scholar; Gilboy, Elizabeth Waterman, Wages in 18th Century England (New York: Russell and Russell, 1934), pp. 186–98.Google Scholar

35. Wallerstein, , Modern World-System, p. 80Google Scholar. This type of argument normally uses the London building workers' wage index; for a critique of its validity, see Thirsk, Joan, Economic Policy and Projects (Oxford: Clarendon Press, 1978), p. 173.Google Scholar

Note the permanence of class struggles. Strikes and trade unions are reported in 17th century England; see Dobson, C. R., Masters and Journeymen: A Prehistory of Industrial Relations (London: Croom Helm, 1980), pp. 2428, 152Google Scholar; “the most important source of industrial conflict in the 18th century was the money wage rate” (p. 29). Cf. Wadsworth, Alfred P. and de Lacy Man, Julia, The Cotton Trade and Industrial Lancashire, 1600–1780 (Manchester: Manchester University Press, 1931), pp. 340, 369, 381Google Scholar, and Lipson, , Economic History of England, 2:xxxiGoogle Scholar.

Also note rising wages between 1780 and 1840, although admittedly real wages decline during the Napoleonic Wars. See Flinn, M. W., “Trends in Real Wages, 1750–1850,” Economic History Review 27, 3 (1974), p. 407Google Scholar; Tunzelmann, S. N., “Trends in Real Wages, 1750–1850, Revisited,” Economic History Review 32, 1 (1979), p. 49.Google Scholar

36. Hammerström, Ingrid, “The Price Revolution in the Sixteenth Century: Some Swedish Evidence,” Scandinavian Economic History Review (1957), p. 141Google Scholar; Bog, Ingomar, “Wachstum-sprobleme der oberdeutschen Wirtschaft,” Jahrbuch für Nationalökonomie und Statistik 179 (1966), pp. 498531.Google Scholar

37. Postan, M. M., “Recent Trends in the Accumulation of Capital,” Economic History Review 6, 1 (10 1935), pp. 23CrossRefGoogle Scholar; E. L. Jones, “Industrial Capital and Landed Investment: The Arkwrights in Herefordshire, 1809–1843,” in Jones, and Mingay, , Land, Labour and Population, pp. 6971Google Scholar; Heaton, R., “Financing the Industrial Revolution,” Bulletin of the Business Historical Society 11, 1 (02 1937), pp. 110.CrossRefGoogle Scholar

Evidence is so abundant that it is a mystery that development is still considered dependent on the accumulation of money capital; cf. for the general argument Rodinson, Maxime, Islam et capitalisme (Paris: Seuil, 1966), especially p. 152.Google Scholar

38. On low government incomes in England because of low tax ratios, see Lane, Frederick G., “The Role of Governments in Economic Growth in Early Modern Times,” Journal of Economic History 35, 1 (03 1975), P. 16CrossRefGoogle Scholar. On the relative poverty of preindustrial England, Deane, , First Industrial Revolution, p. 5.Google Scholar

39. Cunningham, W., The Growth of English Industry and Commerce in Modern Times (London: Cass, 1968), p. 345Google Scholar. There is an interesting discussion of the idea of the gentleman in 17th century England in Wright, Lewis B., Middle-Class Culture in Elizabethan England (Ithaca: Cornell University Press, 1935), pp. 121–26, 19Google Scholar. See also van Klaveren, Jacob, “Fiskalismus-Merkantilismus-Korruption, Drei Aspekte der Finanz- und Wirtschaftpolitik des Ancien Régime,” Vierteljahresschrfi für Wirtschafts- und Sozialgeschichte 47, 3 (1960), p. 347.Google Scholar

40. van Klaveren, Jacob, “Die Manufakturen des Ancien Régime,” Vierteljahresschrift für Wirtschafts- und Sozialgeschichte 51, 1 (1964), p. 145Google Scholar; Barkhausen, Max, “Staatliche Wirtschaftslenkung und freies Unternehmertum im westdeutschen… Raum,” Vierteljahresschrift für Wirtschafts- und Sozialgeschichte 45, 2 (1958), p. 236Google Scholar. Cf., from a rich literature, Kellenbenz, Hermann, “Industries rurales en Occident de la fin du Moyen Age au XVIIIe siècle,” Annales E.S.C. 18, 3 (0910 1963), p. 840Google Scholar; Jones, E. L., “Agricultural Origins of Industry,” Past and Present 40 (06 1968), p. 61.CrossRefGoogle Scholar

Those who consider this development an expression of peasant poverty should see Rowlands, Marie B., Masters and Men in the West Midland Metalware Trades before the Industrial Revolution (Manchester: Manchester University Press, 1975)Google Scholar: “Rural industry has often been regarded in the light of the attempt of poor districts to eke out an inadequate living by bye- employments. This was emphatically not the case in the Midlands. It was a case of the response of a community rich in industrial resources to expanding opportunities for profit” (p. 13).

41. Jones, , Agriculture and Industrial Revolution, p. 105Google Scholar; Habbakuk, H. J., “The Long-Term Rate of Interest and the Price of Land in the Seventeenth Century,” Economic History Review 5, 1(1952), pp. 2545Google Scholar; Bairoch, Paul, Le tiers mondedans l'impasse (Paris: Gallimard, 1971), p. 57.Google Scholar

42. Crouzet, François, “Capital Formation in Great Britain during the Industrial Revolution,” in Crouzet, , ed., Capital Formation in the Industrial Revolution (London: Methuen, 1972), pp. 160–80Google Scholar; Bairoch, Paul, Revolution industrielle et sous-developpement, 3d ed. (Paris: Société d' édition enseignement supérieur, 1969), p. 49Google Scholar; Mantoux, Paul, La révolution industrielle au XVIIIe sièle (Paris: Societe nouvelle de librairie et d'édition, 1906), p. 385.Google Scholar

43. Mantoux, , Révolution industrielle, p. 379.Google Scholar

44. For examples, see Bienefeld, Manfred, “The Informal Sector and Peripheral Capitalism,” Bulletin of the Institute for Development Studies, 02 1975, pp. 7172Google Scholar. See also Nihan, Georges, Demol, Erik, and Jondoh, Comlavi, “The Modern Informal Sectors in Lomé,” International Labour Review 117, 6 (0910 1979), p. 634Google Scholar; Nihan, and Jourdain, Robert, “The Modern Informal Sector in Nouakchott,” International Labour Review 118, 5 (1112 1978), p. 716Google Scholar; Lachaud, J. R., “Les lois de fonctionnement du sector informel ‘traditionnel,’Tiers Monde 21, 82 (0405 1980), p. 444CrossRefGoogle Scholar; Oshima, Harry T., “‘Labour- Force Explosion' and the Labor-Intensive Sector in Asian Growth,” Economic Development and Cultural Change 19, 2 (01 1971), p. 178CrossRefGoogle Scholar. The destruction of this sector by unequal income distribution is shown by Peemans, Jean Philippe, “Capital Accumulation in the Congo under Colonialism: The Role of the State,” in Gann, Lewis H. and Duignan, Peter, eds., Colonialism in Africa, vol. 4: The Economics of Colonialism (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1975), p. 188.Google Scholar

45. Eversley, , “Home Market,” pp. 210–19, 259.Google Scholar

46. Cf. Bagchi, Amiyar Kumar, Private Investment in India, 1900–1938 (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1972)CrossRefGoogle Scholar: “One could call capital shy if an enterprise promised a reasonable rate of profit and yet capital was not forthcoming. It is very rare for the critics alleging the lack of enterprise of Indian capitalists to provide concrete examples where the rate of profit was reasonable and yet capital was not forthcoming for investment” (p. 20).

47. Wallerstein, , Modern World-System, p. 133Google Scholar; Anderson, , Passages, p. 34.Google Scholar

48. Walierstein, , Modern World-System. 114Google Scholar. On France's technological superiority in the 17th and 18th centuries, see Wadsworth and Man, Cotton Trade, p. 413. The idea that Spain was less developed than other European countries in the 15th century, often held to account for its later underdevelopment, is misleading, cf. McKay, Angus, Spain in the Middle Ages (London: Macmillan, 1977), p. 77CrossRefGoogle Scholar; Vives, Jaime Vicens, An Economic History of Spain (Princeton: Princeton University Press, 1969), p. 223CrossRefGoogle Scholar. On the decline of Spain because of the demand structure, see Elliott, J. H., “The Decline of Spain,” in Cipolla, Carlo M., ed., The Economic Decline of Empires (London: Methuen, 1970), p. 181.Google Scholar

49. Wallerstein, , Modern World-System, p. 122Google Scholar; cf. Anderson, , Lineages, p. 287.Google Scholar

50. Sidney Pollard writes about French manufactures, “What was often aimed at was technical excellence, either of the product, such as porcelain or furniture, or of the process, as copied from abroad or developed by home scientists. The pursuit of perfection is apt to play havoc with costs and costs were in any case little regarded because subsidies or other privileges would take care of deficits” (The Genesis of Modern Management [Harmondsworth: Penguin, 19681, pp. 63–64). Klaveren, Van, “Manufakturen des Ancien Régime,” p. 191Google Scholar, even shows manufactones pushed out of the market by handicraft production.

51. Klaveren, Van, “Manufakturen des Ancien Régime,” pp. 159–65Google Scholar; Laforce, J. Clayburn, “Royal Factories in Spain, 1700–1800,” Journal of Economic History 24, 3 (09 1964), pp. 337–63CrossRefGoogle Scholar; Feuerwerker, Albert, China's Early Industrialisation (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1958), p. 26.CrossRefGoogle Scholar

52. Dhoquois, Guy, “Les étapes de la formation algérienne,” Revue algérienne des sciences juridiques, économiques et politiques 5, 2 (06 1968)Google Scholar, criticizes Wittfogel thus: “Les pays anglosaxons avaient rédecouvert la notion plus tôt mais de façon travestie dans le livre de K. Wittfogel [Oriental Despotism], … car l'auteur poursuivait un but anticommuniste en confondant en quelque sort socialisme et mode de production asiatique” (p. 375). But see Wittfogel, K. A., Wirtschaft und Gesellschaft Chinas (Leipzig: C. L. Hirschfeld, 1931), pp. 410–58.Google Scholar

53. In this respect the discussion among African sociologists is of great interest. Cf. Beattie, J. H. M., “Bunyoro, An African Feudality,” in Dalton, George, ed., Tribal and Peasant Economics: Readings in Anthropology (Garden City, N. Y.:Natural History Press, 1967), who shows (p. 90)Google Scholar that African feudalism emerges as a stage in the centralization of the state and not as a form of decay, which she supposes to be the case in Europe. See also Smaldone, Joseph P., “Firearms in the Central Sudan,” Journal of African History 13, 4 (1972), p. 591.CrossRefGoogle Scholar

54. Moore, , Social Origins, p. xv.Google Scholar

55. Amin, , Développement inégal, p. 44.Google Scholar

56. Wallerstein, , Modern World-System, p. 84.Google Scholar

57. Hymer, Stephen, The International Operation of National Firms (Cambridge: MIT Press, 1976), pp. 17, 25, 32, 91.Google Scholar

58. The mechanism is simple: high profit rates in growth industries lead to growth in these sectors, eventually to price cuts with a subsequent lowering of the profit rate. Even oligopolies tend toward average profit rates; see Borrelly, Rolande, Les disparités sectorielles des taux de profit (Grenoble: Presses Universitaires de Grenoble, 1975), p. 25.Google Scholar

59. Moran, Theodore H., “Foreign Expansion as an ‘Institutional Necessity’ for US Corporate Capitalism,” World Politics 25, 3 (04 1973), p. 378.CrossRefGoogle Scholar

60. Luxemburg, Rosa, Die Akkumulation des Kapitals (Berlin: Vereinigung internationaler Verlagsanstalten, 1923), chaps. 26, 27.Google Scholar

61. Lenin, , Werke, 3:245 (chap. 4)Google Scholar. Lenin does not specifically refer to a falling profit rate; its implication in his work is drawn out by Leucate, Christian, “Internationalisation du capital et imperialisme,” Critique de l'économie politique 19 (0103 1975), pp. 108ff.Google Scholar

62. Amin, , Développement inégal, p. 72Google Scholar; Marx, Capital, chap. 20 (MEW 24:399). The solution has already been analyzed positively by Hofman, Werner, Theorie der Wirtschaftsentwicklung: Vom Merkantilismus bis zur Gegenwart (Berlin: Duncker & Humblot, 1966), p. 165.Google Scholar

63. Luxemburg, , Akkumulation, pp. 89ff, 403.Google Scholar

64. Ibid, pp. 116, 441.

65. Ibid., p. 92. The argument has been refined by Denis, Henri, “Le rôle de ‘débouchés préalables' dans Ia croissance économique de I'Europe occidentale et des Etats-Unis,” Cahiers de l'ISEA, 05 1961, pp. 6875Google Scholar; Denis, , “Marchés nouveaux et accumulation du capital,” L'homme et la soclété 22 (1012 1971), p. 104.Google Scholar

66. For the same argument see Wolfstetter, Elniar, Wert, Profurate und Beschäfligung (Frankfurt: Campus, 1977), pp. 212ffGoogle Scholar; Holländer, Heinz, “Das Gesetz des tendenziellen Falle der Profitrate,” Mehrwert 6 (1975), pp. 109ffGoogle Scholar; Bortkiewicz, L. von, “Wertrechnung und Preisrechnung im Marxschen System [3d part],” Archiv für Sozialwissenschaft und Sozialpolitik 25, 3 (1907), pp. 456ffGoogle Scholar; Schmitt-Rink, Gerhard, “Kapitalintensität und Kapitalmobilität im Marxschen Modell,” Schmollers Jahrbuch 87, 2(1967), p. 146Google Scholar; Okishio, Nobuo, “Technical Changes and the Rate of Profit,” Kobe University Economic Review 6, 1 (1961), pp. 8590Google Scholar; Roemer, John E., “Continuing Controversy on the Falling Rate of Profit, Fixed Capital, and Other Issues,” Cambridge Journal of Economics 3, 4 (1979), p. 393.CrossRefGoogle Scholar

67. If the equation represents the average product of an economy, produced with the average organic composition of capital, problems of the transformation of labor values into production prices do not emerge. If labor productivity increases uniformly in all sectors, all quantity measures would have to be divided by the same deflator, that is, the inverted value of the index of labor productivity.

68. Zeitlin, Irving M., Capitalism and Imperialism: An Introduction to Neo-Marxian Concepts (Chicago: Markham, 1972), pp. 4ffGoogle Scholar. Kay, Geoffrey, Development and Underdevelopment: A Marxist Analysis (London: Macmillan, 1975), p. 143Google Scholar, neglects the requirement that innovation reduce costs. His equation π = (s ÷ v) + (1 + (c ÷ v)) seems to indicate that if the organic composition of capital is rising, the profit rate will fall. But he does not take into account the conditions under which the organic composition of capital rises.

69. Ford, A. G., “British Investment in Argentina and Long Swings,” Journal of Economic History 31, 3 (09 1971), pp. 650–63CrossRefGoogle Scholar, notes that capital was exported to Argentina when the European economies were expanding. Aldcroft, Derek H. and Richardson, Harry W., in The British Economy, 1870–1939 (London: Macmillan, 1969), observe that “Home and foreign investment (1870–1914) tended to move together and the link of the two was the behaviour of exports” (p. 27).CrossRefGoogle Scholar

70. Percentage of capital exported to the Third World up to 1914: Britain, 37.9%; France, 34.5%; Germany, 31.1%; United States, 54%. See Feis, Herbert, Europe the World's Banker (New Haven: Yale University Press, 1930), pp. 23, 46, 70Google Scholar; Woodruff, William, America's Impact on the World (London: Macmillan, 1975), p. 340.CrossRefGoogle Scholar

71. Industrialized countries produced 96.7% of their own coal (1910) and 99% of their own iron ore (1913): my calculations, from data supplied by the German Statistical Office.

72. There are two arguments. The first is the importance of North America in world basic food exports (wheat): see League, of Nations, Le cours et les phases de la dépression économique mondiale (Geneva, 1931), p. 47Google Scholar. The second involves high wages for seasonal labor in the Argentine wheat economy c. 1890–1910: Diaz-Alejandro, Carlos F., Essays on the Economic History of the Argentine Republic (New Haven: Yale University Press, 1970), p. 43Google Scholar: Platt, D. C. M., Latin America and British Trade, 1808–1914 (London: Black, 1972), pp. 126ff.Google Scholar

73. Ambirajan, S., Classical Political Economy and British Policy in India (London: Cambridge University Press, 1978), p. 262CrossRefGoogle Scholar; Jenks, Leland Hamilton, The Migration of British Capital to 1875 (New York: Knopf, 1927), pp. 213, 219, 413–15.Google Scholar

74. Latham, A. J. H., The Depression and the Developing World (London: Croom Helm, 1981), p. 70Google Scholar; Dickens, Paul D., American Direct Investments in Foreign Countries, 1936 (Washington: USGPO, 1938), p. 26Google Scholar; Fleisig, Heywood, “The United States and the Non-European Periphery during the Early Years of the Great Depression,” in van der Wee, Herman, ed., The Great Depression Revisited (The Hague: Nijhoff, 1972), p. 160.Google Scholar

75. This is simply the formula for price-neutral wage increases. For the literature, see Elsenhans, , Abhängiger Kapitalismus, p. 39, fn. 27.Google Scholar

76. In 1970, 18% of German firms mentioned low labor costs, 82% mentioned security of markets (Pohle, Wolfgang, “Direct Investment as Seen by German Industry,” Intereconomics, 10 1971, p. 314)CrossRefGoogle Scholar. By 1979, 64% of German firms mentioned low labor costs as a motive for relocation, 70% mentioned security of markets (Handelsblatt, 7 August 1979).

77. The most important point is the continual rise of non-American foreign direct investment. See González, Etanislao, “La situación actual del capitalismo y las nacionalizaciones,” Nueva Ciencia (1975), p. 208.Google Scholar

78. The share of transnationals in manufactured exports from the Third World is rather low. See Hone, Angus, “Multinational Corporations and Multinational Buying Groups: Their Impact on the Growth of Asia's Exports of Manufactures,” World Development 2, 2 (02 1974), p. 146CrossRefGoogle Scholar; Nayyar, Deepak, “Transnational Corporations and Manufactured Exports from Poor Countries,” Economic Journal 88, 2 (03 1978), p. 71CrossRefGoogle Scholar; Vernon, Raymond, Storm over the Multinationals (Cambridge: Harvard University Press, 1977), p. 93Google Scholar. Jenkins, Rhys, in “The Export Performance of Multinational Corporations in Mexican Industry,” Journal of Development Studies 15, 3 (04 1979), p. 104CrossRefGoogle Scholar, shows that locally owned industry concentrates in more traditional manufactured exports. Helleiner, G. K. now admits the point, in “Structural Trends of Third World Trade,” Journal of Development Studies 15, 2 (04 1979)CrossRefGoogle Scholar. German foreign direct investment in Third World countries is especially low in textiles and shoe production, which are important items of German manufactured imports from the Third World: Kiera, Hans Georg, “Die deutsehen Direktinvestitionen in Entwicklungsländern,” Mitteilungen des Rheinisch- Westfälischen Instituts für Wirtschaftsforschung 24, 1 (1975), p. 50.Google Scholar

79. For the literature, see Elsenhans, , Abhängiger Kapitalismus, p. 40, fn. 29. Cf. above, notes 11, 71, 72.Google Scholar

80. Gilboy, Elizabeth Waterman, “Times Series and the Derivation of Demand and Supply Curves: A Study of Coffee and Tea,” Quarterly Journal of Economics 48, 3 (08 1934), pp. 672–85CrossRefGoogle Scholar; Kenwood, A. G. and Lougheed, A. L., The Growth of the International Economy (London: Allen & Unwin, 1971), p. 33Google Scholar. German imports of tropical fruit were 60 grams per capita in 1840, 4300 g. per capita in 1913: Bitter, Wilhelm, Die wirtschaftliche Eroberung Mittelamerikas durch den Bananentrust, 2d ed. (Darmstadt: Wissenschaftliche Buchgesellschaft, 1971), p. 11Google Scholar. Cf. also Roth, Hans, Die Übererzeugung der Welthandelsware Kaffee im Zeitraum von 1790–1929 (Jena: V. G. Fischer, 1929), p. 100Google Scholar; Hammond, John L. and Hammond, Barbara, The Rise of Modern Industry, 5th ed. (London: Methuen, 1937), p. 22.Google Scholar

81. The dependence of the rate of profit on growth rate and intensity of competition is shown by Sass, Werner, “Das sektorale Profitratengfille in der westdeutschen Industrie,” Wirtschaftsdienst 56, 5 (05 1976), pp. 255–59.Google Scholar

82. Helleiner, G. K., “Manufactured Exports from Less Developed Countries and Multinational Firms,” Economic Journal 83, 2 (03 1973), p. 43CrossRefGoogle Scholar; Vernon, Raymond, Sovereignty at Bay (London: Longman, 1971), p. 108Google Scholar. For the case of electronics, see Emerson, Craig, “Transnational Corporations in the Consumer Electronics Industry of Developing Countries,” Economic Bulletin for Asia and the Pacific 29, 2 (12 1978), pp. 5074.Google Scholar

83. This, and the competitiveness of Indian textiles sold by the British East India Company on world markets, are well documented. See Ghosal, H. R., Economic Transition in the Bengal Presidency, 1793–1833 (Calcutta: K. L. Mukhopadhyay, 1966), pp. 38Google Scholar; Mukerjee, Radhakamal, The Economic History of India (Allahabad: Kitab Mahal, 1967), pp. 117, 121, 173Google Scholar; Jathar, Ghanesh Bhaskar and Beri, Shridhar Govind, Indian Economics: A Comprehensive and Critical Survey, 8th ed. (Madras: Oxford University Press, 1947), 1:168Google Scholar; Hossain, Hameeda, “The Alienation of Weavers: Impact of the Conflict between the Revenue and Commercial Interests of the East India Company,” Indian Economic and Social History Review 16, 3 (0709 1979), pp. 327–29CrossRefGoogle Scholar; Chapman, S. D., The Cotton Industry in the Industrial Revolution (London: Macmillan, 1972), p. 16CrossRefGoogle Scholar; Thomas, P. J., Mercantilism and East India Trade (London: Cass, 1963), p. 39Google Scholar; Ellison, Thomas, The Cotton Trade of Great Britain … (London: E. Wilson, 1886), pp. 739Google Scholar. On how small were technological differences between the Indian and English textile industries, see Wadsworth, and Man, , Cotton Trade, p. 151Google Scholar; Baines, Edward, History of the Cotton Manufactures in Great Britain, 2d ed. (1835; rpt., London: Cass, 1966), p. 101Google Scholar; Alavi, Hamza, “India, Transition from Feudalism to Colonial Capitalism,” Journal of Contemporary Asia 10, 4 (1980), p. 384.CrossRefGoogle Scholar

84. Chaudhuri, K. N., “Treasure and Trade Balances: The East India Company's Export Trade, 1660–1720,” Economic History Review 21, 4 (1968), pp. 497–98Google Scholar; Chaudhuri, , “The East India Company and the Export of Treasure in the Early Seventeenth Century,” Economic History Review 16, 1 (1963), pp. 2338.CrossRefGoogle Scholar

85. See Mantoux, , Révolution industrielle, pp. 191ffGoogle Scholar; Ghosal, , Economic Transition, pp. 2627Google Scholar; Thomas, P. J., Mercantilism and the East India Trade (London: Cass, 1963), p. 98.Google Scholar

86. Many proclaim the characteristic feature in such tributary modes of production is unitary rural communities; but those communities were an artifact of British administrators in colonial India, because the community could be held responsible collectively for the individual tax liabilities of its members. Cf. Dumont, Louis, Religion, Politics and History in India (The Hague: Mouton, 1970), pp. 114–20Google Scholar; Krader, Lawrence, The Asiatic Mode of Production (Assen: Van Gorcum, 1975), p. 64.Google Scholar

87. On the general argument, see Rosdolsky, R., “The Distribution of the Agrarian Product in Feudalism,” Journal of Economic History 11, 3 (Summer 1951), pp. 264–65CrossRefGoogle Scholar. Cf. also Pillai, P. Panmanabha, Economic Conditions in India (London: Routledge, 1925)Google Scholar: “In summing up the economic characteristics of India in the 17th century, we notice that the predominant features were inadequate production and faulty distribution” (p. 11).

88. The classic formulation of this dynastic cycle is that of Ibn Khaldoun in the 14th century: Discours sur l'histoire universelle [Al Muqaddima], trans. Monteil, Vincent (Paris: Sindbad, 1968) 2:570–72Google Scholar. See Divitcioglu, Sencer, “Modèle économique de la société ottomane, les 14e et 15e siècles,” La Pensée, 04 1969, p. 51Google Scholar; Reischauer, Edwin O. and Fairbank, John K., East Asia: The Great Tradition (Boston: Houghton Mifflin, 1960), p. 117.Google Scholar

89. The monopolistic character of industry is shown in Heichelheim, Fritz, An Ancient Economic History from the Palaeolithic Age to the Migrations of the Germanic, Slavic, and Arabic Nations (Leiden: Sijthoff, 1958), 1:173Google Scholar; Inalcik, Halil, “Capital Formation in the Ottoman Empire,” Journal of Economic History 29, 1 (03 1969), pp. 115–17, 135.CrossRefGoogle Scholar

90. Duvall, Raymond D., “Dependence and Dependencia Theory,” International Organization 32, 1 (Winter 1978), p. 72.CrossRefGoogle Scholar

91. Social systems were authoritarian wherever Europeans arrived in today's Third World countries. Cf. Verlinden, Charles, Les origines de la civilisation atlantique (Neufchatel: Baconnière, 1966), p. 65.Google Scholar

92. Surplus was primarily extracted from India's rulers: see Moreland, W. H., India at the Death of Akbar: An Economic Study (Delhi: Atam Ram, 1962), p. 65Google Scholar; Maddison, Angus, Class Structure and Economic Growth: India and Pakistan since the Moghuls (London: Allen & Unwin, 1971), p. 13Google Scholar. Nevertheless, the most convincing argument is the reorientation of Indian industrial production to mass consumption goods after the British conquest: see Ghosal, , Economic Transition, p. 23Google Scholar; Hossain, , “Alienation of Weavers,” p. 345Google Scholar; Komarov, E. N. and Grasche, W. I., “Einige Angaben über die gesellschaftliche Arbeitsteilung und die ökonomische Struktur des Handwerks in Indien,” in Ruben, Walter, ed., Die ökonomische undsoziale Entwicklung Indiens: Sowjetische Beiträge zur indischen Geschichte (Berlin: Akademie-Verlag, 1961), 2:152Google Scholar; Davey, Brian, The Economic Development of India (Nottingham: Spokesman, 1975), pp. 4083.Google Scholar

93. Kindleberger, Charles P., “Foreign Trade and Economic Growth: Lessons from Britain and France, 1850–1913,” Economic History Review 13, 3 (1961), p. 290Google Scholar; Hilferding, Rudolph, Das Finanzkapital (1909; rpt. Frankfurt: Europäische Verlagsanstalt, 1968), p. 416.Google Scholar

94. Berrill, K., “International Trade and the Rate of Economic Growth,” Economic History Review 12, 3 (1960), p. 356.CrossRefGoogle Scholar

95. See on this point the literature cited in Elsenhans, , Abhängiger Kapitalismus, p. 124, fn. 17.Google Scholar

96. Benachenhou, Abdellatif, “Le renversement de la problématique ricardienne des coûts comparés dans la théorie économique contemporaine,” Revue algérienne des sciences juridiques, économiques et politiques 8, 4 (12 1971), p. 925Google Scholar. For the same argument about Poland's 17th and 18th century grain exports, see Kula, Witold, Theorie économique du système féodal (The Hague: Mouton, 1970), p. 96CrossRefGoogle Scholar; about the U.S. South, Huertas, Thomas, “Damnifying Growth in the Antebellum South,” Journal of Economic History 39, 1 (03 1979), p. 95CrossRefGoogle Scholar; about Portugal, , Silva, José Gentil da, “L'autoconsommation au Portugal,” Annales E.S.C. 24, 2 (0304 1969), p. 254.Google Scholar

97. Caporaso, James A., “Introduction: Dependence and Dependency in the Global System,” International Organization 32, 1 (Winter 1978), p. 2.Google Scholar

98. On Hong Kong, see Hsia, Ronald and Chan, Larry, “Industrialisation and Income Distribution in Hong Kong,” International Labour Review 117, 4 (0709 1978), p. 476Google Scholar. See also Lee, Eddy, “Egalitarian Peasant Farming and Rural Development: The Case of South Korea,” World Development 7, 4–6 (0406 1979), p. 513.CrossRefGoogle Scholar

99. Chudson, Walter A. and Wells, Louis T., Acquisition of Technology from Multinational Corporations by Developing Countries (New York: United Nations, 1974), pp. 615Google Scholar; Pack, Howard, “The Substitution of Labor for Capital in Kenyan Manufacturing,” Economic Journal 86 (03 1976), p. 56CrossRefGoogle Scholar. The most important evidence is the high content of second-hand technology in transnational' Third World production, which is often criticized: Salama, Pierre, “Specificités de l'internationalisation du capital en Amérique latine,” Tiers Monde 19 (0406 1978), p. 293.CrossRefGoogle Scholar

100. The explanation is that bureaucrats and engineers prefer the most modern technology: Hawrylyshyn, Oli, “Capital-Intensity Biases in Developing Country Technology Choice,” Journal of Development Economics 5, 3 (09 1978), pp. 217–23CrossRefGoogle Scholar; Hawrylyshyn, , “Non-Economic Biases towards Capital-Intensive Techniques in Less Developed Countries,” Zeitschrift für Nationalökonomie 37, 1–2 (1977), pp. 123–49CrossRefGoogle Scholar. The preference, however, may be due to corruption: see Winston, Gordon C., “The Appeal of Inappropriate Technologies,” World Development 7, 8–9 (08–09 1979), p. 840CrossRefGoogle Scholar. On the inefficiency of state enterprises in the Third World, see Elsenhans, , Abhängiger Kapitalismus, p. 103, In. 125Google Scholar; p. 154, fn. 130; pp. 204–6, fns. 53, 56, 59, 61.

101. Palma, , “Dependency,” pp. 889910Google Scholar. Lall, Sanjaya, “Is Dependency a Useful Concept in Analyzing Underdevelopment?”, World Development 3, 11–12 (11–12 1975), argues that “undesirable effects of dependent growth are general aspects of capitalist growth” (p. 808)CrossRefGoogle Scholar. See also Ramos, Joseph, “A Heterodoxical Interpretation to the Employment Problem in Latin America,” World Development 2, 7 (07 1974), pp. 4758CrossRefGoogle Scholar, and Schoeller, Wolfgang, Weltmarkt und Reproduktion des Kapitals (Frankfurt: Europäische Verlagsanstalt, 1976), p. 266.Google Scholar

102. Transnational Corporations in World Development: A Re-Examination (New York: United Nations, 1978), p. 91.Google Scholar

103. Bequele, Assefa and Freeman, David H., “Employment and Basic Needs: An Overview,” International Labour Review 118, 3 (0506 1979), p. 316Google Scholar; Sabolo, Yves, “Industrialisation, Exports and Employment,” International Labour Review 119, 4 (0709 1980), p. 484Google Scholar. Third World unemployment in the year 2000 will be about 700 million: Dritter Bericht zur Entwicktungspolitik der Bundesregierung (Bonn: Bundesministerium für Wirtschaftliche Zusammenarbeit, Entwicklungspolitik, November 1977), p. 9.Google Scholar

104. Emmanuel, , Technologie appropriée, p. 52Google Scholar. Drucker's, Peter F. views that multinationals are interested in the multiplier effects of their investment is correct but politically irrelevant: see his “Multinationals and Developing Countries: Myths and Realities,” Foreign Affairs 53, 1 (10 1974), p. 136.CrossRefGoogle Scholar

105. Phelps, Dudley Maynard, Migration of Industry to South America (New York: McGraw-Hill, 1936), p. 318.Google Scholar

106. Lehmann, David, “Political Incorporation versus Political Stability: The Case of the Chilean Agrarian Reform, 1965–1970,” Journal of Development Studies 7, 4 (07 1971), argues in a parallel fashion: “There are many reasons why Latin American capital ought, in their own ‘purely’ economic interests, to favor such an egalitarian small peasant reform, but there seems to be one powerful reason for their resistance to it: to bring about a substantial change in agrarian structures involves a social and political mobilization of the peasantry which would, they think, eventually threaten urban and industrial property rights and this reason is not without foundation” (p. 373)CrossRefGoogle Scholar. I show that expatriate capital may be more inclined to take such risks than locally based capital in my Frankreichs Algerienkrieg, 1954–1962 (Munich: Hanser, 1974), p. 624.Google Scholar

107. The argument is that capitalist enterprises need markets for capital-intensively produced products: Cardoso, Fernando Henrique, “Brasilien, Die Widersprüche der assozierten Entwicklung,” in Sonntag, Heinz Rudolph, ed., Latinamerika: Faschismus oder Revolution (Berlin: Rotbuch Verlag, 1974), p. 53Google Scholar; RIO Report, Reshaping the International Order: A Report of the Club of Rome (New York: Dutton, 1976), p. 40.Google Scholar

108. H, Albert O.irschman, “Investment Policies and Dualism in Underdeveloped Countries,” American Economic Review 47, 4 (09 1957), p. 561.Google Scholar

109. Shams, Rasul, “Employment Policies in Developing Countries,” Intereconomics, 12 1976, p. 339CrossRefGoogle Scholar. Cf. Stewart, Frances, “Technology and Employment in LDCs,” World Development 2, 3 (03 1974), pp. 4045CrossRefGoogle Scholar. For further literature, see Elsenhans, , Abhängiger Kapitalismus, p. 109, fn. 135Google Scholar. Graciela Chichilnisky does not contradict my assertion because she does not consider one aspect of growth from foreign direct investment—expanding internal markets: “Terms of Trade and Domestic Distribution: Export-Led Growth with Abundant Labor,” Journal of Development Economics 7, 4 (December 1979), pp. 178–79.Google Scholar

110. Effective state control has long been observed: Lewis, Cleona, America's Stake in International Investments (Washington: Brookings, 1938), p. 507Google Scholar; Penrose, Edith, “Profit-Sharing between Producing Countries and Oil Companies in the Middle East,” Economic Journal 69 (06 1959), p. 253CrossRefGoogle Scholar; Penrose, , “The State and Multinational Enterprises in Less-Developed Countries,” in Dunning, John H., ed., The Multinational Enterprise (London: Allen & Unwin, 1971), p. 231Google Scholar; U.N., Transnational Corporations, p. 7Google Scholar; Emerson, , “Transnational Corporations,” p. 68Google Scholar. Even critics of the power of the transnationals admit that state control of transnational affiliates is increasing: Newfarmer, Richard S. and Mueller, Willard F., Multinational Corporations in Brazil and Mexico (Washington, D.C.: USGPO, 1975), p. 100Google Scholar; Fajnzylber, Fernando and Tarragdó, Trinidad MartínezLas empresas transnacionales (Mexico City: Fundo de Cultura Económica, 1976), p. 132.Google Scholar

111. Hirschman, Albeit mentions the importance of opportunity costs of production, to which level foreign investors can be taxed in host countries: “Beyond Asymmetry: Critical Notes on Myself as a Young Man and Some Other Old Friends,” International Organization 32, 1 (Winter 1978), p. 49CrossRefGoogle Scholar. Cf. Theodore Moran, “Multinational Corporations and Dependency,” Ibid., p. 100; Waltz, Kenneth, “The Myth of National Independence,” in Kindleberger, Charles P., ed., Power and Money (London: Macmillan, 1970), p. 212.Google Scholar

112. Barnet, Richard and Müller, Ronald, Global Reach: The Power of the Multinational Corporations (New York: Simon & Schuster, 1974), p. 193.Google Scholar

113. Krasner, Stephen D., “The Great Oil Sheikdown,” Foreign Policy no. 13 (Winter 1973), p. 135Google Scholar; Barnet, and Müller, , Global Reach, p. 100.Google Scholar

114. Krasner, Stephen D., “US Commercial and Monetary Policy,” International Organization 31, 3 (Autumn 1977), p. 699.CrossRefGoogle Scholar

115. Ample evidence on this point is given in Elsenhans, , Abhängiger Kapitalismus, pp. 1420, 74–77, 118–22Google Scholar. The theory appears in Elsenhans, , “Die Staatsklasse/Staatsbourgeoisie in den unterentwickelten Ländern zwischen Priviligierung und Legitimationszwang,” Verfassung und Recht in Übersee 10, 1 (1977), pp. 2940CrossRefGoogle Scholar; and in “Zur Rolle der Staatsklasse bei der Überwindung von Unterentwicklung,” in Schmidt, Alfred, ed., Strategien gegen Unterentwicklung: Zwischen Weltmarkt und Eigenständigkeit (Frankfurt: Campus, 1976), pp. 250–65.Google Scholar

116. Frieden, Jeff even argues that to maintain legitimacy governments have to increase their indebtedness for industrialization and that commercial banks are the source for such funds: “Third World Indebted Industrialization,” International Organization 35, 3 (Summer 1981)CrossRefGoogle Scholar. I would add that governments will not go bankrupt and will not be forced to pay back (e.g., the banks' behavior vis-à-vis Argentina in the 1982 Falklands War). But banks must get their money back. This is possible if raw materials rents are appropriated; debt is then passed over to consumers in Western industrialized countries. Thus commercial banks may become an ally for increasing Third World raw material prices, just as oil companies and the U.S. government have favored predictably rising oil prices since the early 1970s. Cf. Elsenhans, , Erdöl für Europa (Hamburg: Hoffmann & Campe, 1974), pp. 1822.Google Scholar

117. See Elsenhans, , Abhängiger Kapitalismus, pp. 8190, 109–117.Google Scholar

118. I start from the consideration that there is sufficient aggregate demand in the Third World; otherwise inflation would not be possible. Demand, however, does not correspond to productive capacities: cf. Strassmann, W. Paul, Technological Change and Economic Development (Ithaca: Cornell University Press, 1968), p. 15.Google Scholar

119. The following argument is based on Elsenhans, , “Agrarverfassung, Akkumulationsprozess und Demokratisierung,” in Elsenhans, , ed,. Agrarreform in der Dritten Welt (Frankfurt: Campus, 1979), esp. pp. 512–69.Google Scholar

120. One unit of income transferred from the rich to the poor diminishes the rich's food grain demand by 0.02 units and increases the poor's food grain demand by 0.59 units. There is no income transfer without an increase in agricultural production: Mellor, John W., “Food Price Policy and Income Distribution in Low-Income Countries,” Economic Development and Cultural Change 27, 1 (10 1978), pp. 2425.CrossRefGoogle Scholar

121. Cf. Elsenhans, , Abhängiger Kapitalismus, p. 64Google Scholar; Elsenhans, , “Agrarverfassung,” p. 539.Google Scholar

122. Elsenhans, , “Agrarverfassung,” p. 512.Google Scholar

123. Cf. Robinson, Warren C., “Types of Disguised Rural Unemployment and Some Policy Implications,” Oxford Economic Papers 21, 4 (11 1969), p. 383CrossRefGoogle Scholar; Rawski, Thomas G., “Economic Growth and Employment in China,” World Development 4, 8–9 (0809 1976), p. 777.Google Scholar

124. Georgescu-Roegen, N., “Economic Theory and Agrarian Economics,” Oxford Economic Papers 12, 2 (02 1960), pp. 3239.CrossRefGoogle Scholar

125. If marginal labor produces less than it consumes, total product increases but surplus does not. See Elsenhans, , “Agrarverfassung,” pp. 553, 559–61.Google Scholar

126. On noncommercial capital formation by surplus labor in the Third World, see Levi, John, “Traditional Agricultural Capital Formation,” World Development 7, 12 (12 1979), p. 1061.CrossRefGoogle Scholar

127. Popkin, Samuel L., The Rational Peasant: Political Economy of Rural Society in Vietnam (Berkeley: University of California Press, 1979), pp. 33, 251Google Scholar; Elsenhans, , “Agrarverfassung,” pp. 540–46.Google Scholar

128. For the literature, see Elsenhans, , Abhängiger Kapitalismus, p. 194, fn. 3.Google Scholar

129. We do not therefore deduce basic needs from academic discussion: cf. Morris, Morris David, Measuring the Condition of the World's Poor (New York: Pergamon, 1979), who says that “Current standards of calorie requirements still seem to be quite ethnocentric” (p. 27).Google Scholar

130. Cf. Elsenhans, , “Politische Ökonomie und wirtschaftliche Entwicklung in der Dritten Welt,” in Planerhandbuch [working title] (Eschborn: Gesellschaft für Technische Zusammenarbeit, forthcoming)Google Scholar. For a slightly different approach, see Dell, Sidney, “Basic Needs or Comprehensive Development,” World Development 6, 3 (03 1978), p. 306.Google Scholar

131. For my general approach, see Elsenhans, , “Die Überwindung von Unterentwicklung durch Massenproduktion für Massenbedarf,” in Nohlen, Dieter and Nuscheler, Franz, eds., Handbuch der Dritten Welt, 2d rev. ed. (Hamburg: Hoffman & Campe, 1982), pp. 152–82Google Scholar. See also Mehmet, Ozay, Economic Planning and Social Justice in Developing Countries (London: Croom Helm 1978), p. 178Google Scholar; Kofi, Tetteh A., “Peasants and Agrarian Economic Development,” in Yansané, Aguibou, ed., Decolonization and Dependency (Westport: Greenwood, 1980), p. 280Google Scholar; Pinto, Anibal, “El modelo de desarrollo reciente de America Latina,” in Serra, José, Desarrollo latinoamericano: Ensaios críticos (Mexico: Fondo de Culture Económica, 1974), p. 49.Google Scholar

132. The decisive point in the role of this modern sector is its product mix, not its creation of employment. The sector helps overcome underdevelopment if its products raise productivity and employment in agriculture and small-scale industry. Cf. Evans, Peter B. and Timberlake, Michael, “Dependence, Inequality and Growth of the Tertiary: A Comparative Analysis of the Less Developed Countries,” American Sociological Review 45, 4 (08 1980), p. 584CrossRefGoogle Scholar. These authors hold that the relationship between dependence and inequality is a function of the kind of modern sector that is created.

133. Amin, Samir, “Le modèle théoretique d'accumulation et de développement dans le monde contemporain,” Tiers Monde 13 (1012 1972), pp. 703–26CrossRefGoogle Scholar. Thomas, Clive Y., Dependence and Transformation (New York: Monthly Review Press, 1974), pp. 255–59.Google Scholar

134. Dell, Sidney, A Latin American Common Market (London: Oxford University Press, 1966), p. 7.Google Scholar

135. Lele, Uma, “Rural Marketing in China: A Comparative Perspective,” World Development 6, 5 (05 1978), p. 664CrossRefGoogle Scholar; Perkins, Dwight, “Meeting Basic Needs in the People's Republic of China,” World Development 6, 5 (05 1978), p. 565CrossRefGoogle Scholar; Blecher, Marc and Meisner, Mitch, “Economic Growth and Equality in Rural China,” Comparative Political Studies 12, 2 (01 1981), p. 523.Google Scholar

136. Yields per hectare increased from 1972/3 to 1977/8 (in %) thus:

Calculated from data in Annuaire statistique de l'Algérie, 1979 (Algiers: Direction des statistiques et de la comptabilité nationale, 1982), pp. 234–38.Google Scholar

The inefficiency of the public marketing boards is notorious, even in Algeria: see Bouzidi, A., “Productivité du travail dans l'économie algérienne et problèmes de commercialisation des produits agricoles,” Revue algérienne des sciences juridiques, économiques et politiques 14, 4 (12 1977), esp. pp. 512–18.Google Scholar

137. Oshima, , “‘Labor-Force Explosion,’” p. 168.Google Scholar

138. Benachenhou, Abdellatif, “Réflexions sur la poiitique des revenus en Algérie,” Revue algérienne des sciences juridiques, économiques et politiques 12, 1 (03 1975), pp. 1920Google Scholar. The “rate of exploitation” may be higher because low-paid, low-skilled labor is employed; cf. Antoine, Philippe and Labbé, Dominique, “Inflation et développement en Algérie,” Revue algérienne des sciences juridiques, économiques et politiques 13, 3 (09 1976), p. 530.Google Scholar

139. RIO Report, Reshaping the International Order, pp. 129–30.Google Scholar

140. As called for by “Was tun, Dag Hammerskjöld Bericht 1975,” Neue Entwicklungspolitik (Wiener Institut für Entwicklungsfragen) 1, 2–3 (1975), pp. 7, 43Google Scholar: RIO Report, Reshaping the International Order, p. 74.Google Scholar

141. Cf. Elsenhans, , Abhängiger Kapitalismus, pp. 212–18.Google Scholar

142. Stepan, Alfred, The State and Society: Peru in Comparative Perspective (Princeton: Princeton University Press, 1978), p. 85.Google Scholar

143. For the literature, see Elsenhans, , Abhängiger Kapitalismus, p. 216, fn. 13; p. 220, fn. 28.Google Scholar

144. Petras, James, “State Capitalism and the Third World,” Development and Change 8, 1 (01 1977), p. 13.CrossRefGoogle Scholar

145. Sklar, Richard L., “Political Science and National Integration: A Radical Approach,” Journal of Modern African Studies 5, 1 (1967), p. 8.CrossRefGoogle Scholar

146. I am interested in potential support from powerful groups in the center, not just that the rich countries may experience “self-doubt.” Cf. Lewis, John P., “Oil, Other Scarcities and the Poor Countries,” World Politics 27, 1 (10 1974), p. 86.CrossRefGoogle Scholar

147. Gilpin, Robert, U.S. Power and the Multinational Corporation (New York: Basic, 1975), p. 8CrossRefGoogle Scholar; Krasner, Stephen D., “State Power and the Structure of International Trade,” World Politics 28, 3 (04 1976), pp. 317–47.CrossRefGoogle Scholar

148. Ahnefeld, Adolf, Gebert, Dietmar, and Walter, Norbert, “Die konjunkturelle und währungspolitische Lage der westlichen Industrieländer zur Jahresmitte 1975,” Die Weltwirtschaft 1 (1975), p. 1Google Scholar; Lorenz, Detlef, “Ursachen und Konsequenzen des Neomerkantilismus,” in Woll, Arthur, ed., Internationale Anpassungsprozesse (Berlin: Duncker & Humblot, 1981), p. 32Google Scholar; Ferrer, Aldo, “La crisis del sistema trilateral y América Latina,” in Hill, Eduardo and Tomassini, Luciano, eds., América Latina y el Nuevo Orden Económico Internacional (Santiago, Chile: Corporatión de Promotión Universitária, 1979), pp. 9698.Google Scholar

149. Katzenstein, Peter J., “Domestic and International Forces and Strategies of Foreign Economic Policy,” International Organization 31, 3 (Autumn 1977), p. 593.Google Scholar

150. Cf. Elsenhans, , Abhängiger Kapitalismus, p. 55, fn. 5Google Scholar. See also Deubner, Christian, “Zur Internationalisierung der westdeutschen Bekleidungsindustrie,” WSI-Mitteilungen 32, 1 (1979), pp. 3445.Google Scholar

151. Cf. note 99 above.

152. Vernon, Raymond, “Storm over the Multinationals: Problems and Prospects,” Foreign Affairs 55, 2 (01 1977), p. 257.CrossRefGoogle Scholar

153. Elsenhans, , “Social Consequences of the NIEO,” in Jahn, Egbert and Sakamoto, Yoshikazu, eds., Elements of World Instability (Frankfurt: Campus, 1981), pp. 8695Google Scholar. The argument is not identical with the explanation of the crisis of the American labor movement advanced by Barnet, and Müller, (Global Reach, p. 323)Google Scholar. The standard of living does not require high wages in the industrial countries, which would mean high subsistence costs; rather, the productive capacity of the economy requires high consumption capacity.