Article contents
Economic dimensions of armed groups: profiling the financing, costs, and agendas and their implications for mediated engagements
Published online by Cambridge University Press: 01 December 2011
Abstract
This article introduces the various economic dimensions of armed groups and explores the implications of their engagement through mediation and dialogue. It looks specifically at the financing, operational costs, and economic agendas of armed groups and brings together examples from Angola, Kosovo, Sudan, Colombia, and other places. It emphasizes that information about available financing and operational costs is critical for assessing the financial and operational strength of an armed group. It also highlights the need to understand armed groups in the broader context of their evolution and the changes that organizational and territorial expansions require with regards to financing strategies. Overall, the economic dimensions of armed groups should be approached with an open mind so that issues such as financing, costs, and economic agendas can be perceived as opportunities, and not necessarily as a problem for peace.
- Type
- Todays Armed Groups: Structure, Actions and Strategic Options
- Information
- International Review of the Red Cross , Volume 93 , Issue 882: Understanding armed groups and the applicable law , June 2011 , pp. 333 - 352
- Copyright
- Copyright © International Committee of the Red Cross 2011
References
1 Empirical sovereignty is associated with the criteria of statehood identified in Article 1 of the 1933 Montevideo Convention on Rights and Duties of States: a permanent population, a defined territory, a government, and the capacity to enter into relations with other state. While de facto states may have empirical aspects of sovereignty, they lack juridical sovereignty associated with international recognition because their territory is already part of an existing and recognized state. See Scott Pegg, International Society and the De Facto State, Ashgate, Aldershot, 1989, p. 26. Dov Lynch, Engaging Eurasia's Separatist States: Unresolved Conflicts and the De Facto States, United States Institute of Peace Press, Washington DC, 2004, p. 16.
2 Paul Collier and Hoeffler, Anke, ‘On the economic causes of civil war’, in Oxford Economic Papers, Vol. 50, No. 4, 1998, pp. 563–573Google Scholar; Mats Berdal and David M. Malone (eds), Greed and Grievance: Economic Agendas in Civil Wars, Lynne Rienner, Boulder, CO, 2000; Karen Ballentine and Jake Sherman (eds), The Political Economy of Armed Conflict: Beyond Greed and Grievance, Lynne Rienner, Boulder, CO, 2003; Paul Collier and Nicholas Sambanis (eds), Understanding Civil War: Evidence and Analysis, Volume 1: Africa, The World Bank, Washington DC, 2005; Cynthia J. Arnson and I. William Zartman (eds), Rethinking the Economics of War: The Intersection of Need, Creed, and Greed, Woodrow Wilson Center Press, Washington, DC, 2005.
3 Ian Bannon, ‘Preface’, in P. Collier and N. Sambanis, above note 2, p. xi.
4 Charles H. Anderton and John R. Carter, Principles of Conflict Economics: A Primer for Social Scientists, Cambridge University Press, Cambridge, 2009; Ron Smith, Military Economics: The Interaction of Power and Money, Palgrave Macmillan, Basingstoke, 2011.
5 Michael Howard, War in European History, Oxford University Press, Oxford, 1976, pp. 85, 98.
6 Charles Tilly, Coercion, Capital and European States, ad 990–1992, Blackwell, Oxford, 1992, pp. 74–76, 96.
7 John Keegan, A History of Warfare, Pimlico, London, 1993, p. 329.
8 The ‘roving bandit’ is a predator who loots while sweeping through various territories to accumulate personal riches; the ‘stationary bandit’ stays in one territory and provides protection to some parts of the population in return for local investments that increase the bandit's wealth. See Olson, Mancur, ‘Dictatorship, democracy, and development’, in American Political Science Review, Vol. 87, No. 3, 1993, p. 568CrossRefGoogle Scholar.
9 Jean-Christophe Rufin, ‘Les économies des guerres dans les conflits internes’, in François Jean and Jean-Christophe Rufin (eds), Économie des guerres civiles, Hachette, Paris, 1996, pp. 21–23.
10 Ibid.
11 Charles P. Kindleberger, A Financial History of Western Europe, Oxford University Press, Oxford, 1993, p. 7.
12 James D. Tracy, A Financial Revolution in the Habsburg Netherlands: Renten and Renteniers in the County of Holland, 1515–1565, University of California Press, Berkeley, 1985, pp. 218, 221.
13 Jeremy Weinstein, Inside Rebellion: The Politics of Insurgent Violence, Cambridge University Press, Cambridge, 2007, pp. 20–21.
14 For an overview of financing methods, see Wennmann, Achim, ‘The political economy of conflict financing: a comprehensive approach beyond natural resources’, in Global Governance, Vol. 13, No. 3, 2007, pp. 431–436Google Scholar.
15 J. Weinstein, above note 13, pp. 20–21, 171–172, 328–329.
16 An exception is the Database of Transnational and Non-state Armed Groups that gathers information about fifty armed groups, including on financing strategies. It was established by the Graduate Institute of International and Development Studies in Geneva and the Program on Humanitarian Policy and Conflict Research at Harvard University. The database can be accessed on request by contacting the Centre on Conflict, Development and Peacebuilding (CCDP) of the Graduate Institute (ccdp@graduateinstitute.ch).
17 Small Arms Survey, Small Arms Survey 2001: Profiling the Problem, Oxford University Press, Oxford, 2001, p. 117.
18 United Nations Security Council (UNSC), Additional Report of the Monitoring Mechanism on Sanctions against UNITA, UN Doc. S/2002/486, 26 April 2002, para. 199. UNSC, Supplementary Report of the Monitoring Mechanism on Sanctions Against UNITA, UN Doc. S/2001/966, 12 October 2001, paras. 234–247.
19 Christian Dietrich, ‘UNITA's diamond mining and exporting capacity’, in Jakkie Cilliers and Christian Dietrich (eds), Angola's War Economy: The Role of Oil and Diamonds, Institute for Security Studies, Pretoria, 2000, pp. 275–294.
20 This figure has been based on revenue estimates of Kosovo Albanians living abroad calculated by the Government of Kosovo in Exile.
21 Interview with Naip Zeka, Former Administrator of Financing the Parallel System of Governance in Kosovo, Pristina, 28 July 2005; interview with Isa Mustafa, Former Minister of Finance in Exile, Pristina, 27 July 2005.
22 A. Wennmann, above note 14.
23 Mark Duffield, ‘Globalization, transborder trade, and war economies’, in M. Berdal and D. M. Malone, above note 2, pp. 69–90. See also Alexander Ramsbotham and I. William Zartman (eds), Accord, Paix Sans Frontières: Building Peace Across Borders, Vol. 22, Conciliation Resources, London, 2011.
24 Singer, Peter W., ‘Corporate warriors: the rise of the privatized military industry and its ramifications for international security’, in International Security, Vol. 26, No. 3, 2001, pp. 186–220CrossRefGoogle Scholar; David Shearer, Private Armies and Military Intervention, International Institute for Strategic Studies, London, 1998.
25 Black market prices for an AK-47 in Albania increased from USD 40 to USD 300 between spring 1997 and spring 1998, peaking at USD 650 in autumn 1998 before decreasing to USD 125 a year later when the Kosovo conflict terminated. Small Arms Survey, Small Arms Survey 2002: Counting the Human Cost, Oxford University Press, Oxford, 2002, p. 69.
26 The estimation tool is fully developed in Achim Wennmann ‘Grasping the financing and mobilization cost of armed groups: a new perspective on conflict dynamics’, in Contemporary Security Policy, Vol. 30, No. 2, 2009, pp. 265–280.
27 The differences in these cost estimates are based on the use of different price ranges. Weapons prices range between USD 40 and USD 250, ammunition prices between USD 0.05 and USD 0.5, and income per soldier between USD 2,000 and USD 10,000 per year. See ibid., pp. 267–271.
28 Ibid.
29 Paul Collier and Hoeffler, Anke, ‘Greed and grievance in civil war’, in Oxford Economic Papers, Vol. 56, No. 4, 2004, p. 564Google Scholar.
30 See Aidan Hartley, ‘The art of darkness’, in The Spectator, 27 January 2001, available at: http://findarticles.com/p/articles/mi_qa3724/is_200101/ai_n8941934/ (last visited 30 September 2011).
31 Mary B. Anderson, Do No Harm: How Aid Can Support Peace – or War, Lynne Rienner, Boulder, CO, 1999.
32 ICRC, ‘Amid war and crime: humanitarian aid in high-risk environments – interview with Dominik Stillhart’, 9 April 2010, available at: http://www.icrc.org/eng/resources/documents/interview/hum-aid-in-high-risk-env-interview-090410.htm (last visited 15 September 2011).
33 Alex Vines, ‘Angola: forty years of war’, in Peter Batchelor and Kees Kingma (eds), Demilitarisation and Peace-Building in Southern Africa – Volume II: National and Regional Experiences, Ashgate, Aldershot, 2004, p. 87.
34 Assis Malaquias, ‘Angola: how to lose a guerrilla war’, in Morten Bøås and Kevin C. Dunn (eds), African Guerrillas: Raging Against the Machine, Lynne Rienner, Boulder, CO, 2007, pp. 212–215.
35 Achim Wennmann, ‘Conflict financing and the recurrence of intra-state armed conflict’, PhD thesis, University of Geneva and Graduate Institute of International Studies, Geneva, 2007, pp. 203–204.
36 Taylor B. Seybolt, ‘Major armed conflicts’, in Stockholm International Peace Research Institute Yearbook 2000, Oxford University Press, Oxford, 2000, p. 32.
37 Achim Wennmann, The Political Economy of Peacemaking, Routledge, London, 2011, pp. 30–32.
38 R. Thomas Naylor, Wages of Crime: Black Markets, Illegal Finance, and the Underworld Economy, Cornell University Press, Ithaca, NY, 2002, pp. 45–47, 53–54. Achim Wennmann, ‘Conflict economies’, in Vincent Chetail (ed.), Post-Conflict Peacebuilding: A Lexicon, Oxford University Press, Oxford, 2009, pp. 80–81; James Cockayne, ‘Chapter ten: crime, corruption and violent economies’, in Mats Berdal and Achim Wennmann (eds), Ending Wars, Consolidating Peace: Economic Dimensions, Institute for International and Strategic Studies, Adelphi Series, Vol. 50, Nos. 412–413, Routledge, London, 2010, pp. 193–198. The list of categories given here is drawn from these studies.
39 R. T. Naylor, above note 38, pp. 45–47, 53–54.
40 Claire Metelits, Inside Insurgency: Violence, Civilians, and Revolutionary Group Behaviour, New York University Press, New York, 2010, pp. 100–102.
41 Kimberly Marten, Zisk, ‘Warlordism in a comparative perspective’, in International Security, Vol. 31, No. 3, 2007, pp. 58CrossRefGoogle Scholar and 72.
42 Philippe Le Billon, The political economy of war: what relief agencies need to know, Humanitarian Practice Network, Paper No. 33, Overseas Development Institute, London, 2000, p. 4.
43 William Reno, ‘Bottom-up statebuilding?’, in Charles T. Call with Vanessa Wyeth (eds), Building States to Build Peace, Lynne Rienner, Boulder, CO, 2008, p. 143.
44 Rapley, John, ‘The new Middle Ages’, in Foreign Affairs, Vol. 85, No. 3, 2006, p. 95CrossRefGoogle Scholar.
45 Christopher Cramer, Civil War is Not a Stupid Thing: Accounting for Violence in Developing Countries, Hurst and Company Publishers, London, 2006, p. 197.
46 I. W. Zartman, ‘Need, creed, and greed in intrastate conflict’, in C. J. Arnson and I. W. Zartman, above note 3, p. 262.
47 David Keen, The Economic Functions of Civil War, International Institute for Strategic Studies, Adelphi Paper No. 320, Oxford University Press, Oxford, 1998, p. 12.
48 Ibid., p. 11.
49 Reno, William, ‘War, markets, and the reconfiguration of West Africa's weak states’, in Comparative Politics, Vol. 29, No. 4, 1997, p. 496CrossRefGoogle Scholar.
50 Wennmann, Achim, ‘Getting armed groups to the table: peace processes, the political economy of conflict and the mediated state’, in Third World Quarterly, Vol. 30, No. 6, 2009, pp. 1123–1138CrossRefGoogle Scholar.
51 I. William Zartman, Ripe for Resolution: Conflict and Intervention in Africa, Oxford University Press, Oxford, 1985, pp. 232–236.
52 Christine Batruch, ‘Oil and conflict: Lundin Petroleum's experience in Sudan’, in Alyson J. K. Bailes and Isabel Frommelt (eds), Business and Security: Public–Private Sector Relationships in a New Security Environment, Oxford University Press, Oxford, 2004, pp. 159–160.
53 Voice of America ‘Peace agreement will “lead to a new and prosperous Sudan” says rebel leader’, 30 May 2004, available at: http://www.voanews.com/english/news/a-13-a-2004-05-30-11-1-67348442.html (last visited 5 November 2008).
54 A. Wennmann, above note 37, p. 82.
55 Achim Wennmann, Wealth sharing beyond 2011: economic issues in Sudan's north–south peace process, CCDP Working Paper 1, Graduate Institute of International and Development Studies, Geneva, 2009, p. 16.
56 Alex De Waal, Fixing the political marketplace: how can we make peace without functioning state institutions?, Fifteenth Christen Michelsen Lecture, Bergen, 15 October 2009, p. 8, available at: http://www.cmi.no/file/?877 (last visited 14 October 2011).
57 The following paragraphs have been inspired by a conversation with Thomas Biersteker and joint work on countering the financing of terrorism.
58 For more information on the Kimberley Process, see http://www.kimberleyprocess.com/home/index_en.html (last visited 15 September 2011).
59 Thomas J. Biersteker and Sue E. Eckert, ‘Introduction: the challenge of terrorist financing’, in Thomas J. Biersteker and Sue E. Eckert (eds), Countering the Financing of Terrorism, Routledge, London, 2008, pp. 2–6.
60 Scott Atran, Talking to the Enemy: Faith, Brotherhood and the (Un)Making of Terrorists, HarperCollins, New York, pp. 207–208.
- 7
- Cited by