Hostname: page-component-586b7cd67f-g8jcs Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-11-25T03:31:55.098Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

A Theoretical Framework for Analyzing Social Costs Of the Tobacco Program

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  28 April 2015

Ruth C. Johnson
Affiliation:
Department of Agricultural Economics and Rural Sociology, The University of Tennessee, Knoxville
B. R. McManus
Affiliation:
Department of Agricultural Economics and Rural Sociology, The University of Tennessee, Knoxville

Extract

Government control of tobacco production through output restrictions and price supports began with the Agricultural Adjustment Act of 1933. The primary goals of the program through the years have been to stabilize tobacco prices and to improve farm income. The tobacco program came under public scrutiny after the U. S. Surgeon General's Report on Smoking and Health in 1964 [11] and the report this year [12]. Critics charge that tobacco production policies of the U. S. Department of Health, Education, and Welfare are inconsistent or even in direct opposition. These issues present a policy dilemma. A theoretical framework is devised for analyzing social costs of the tobacco program and application of the framework to current policy issues is examined.

Type
Research Article
Copyright
Copyright © Southern Agricultural Economics Association 1979

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

References

[1]Bradford, Garnett I. and Thompson, James F.. “Impact of Eliminating the Tobacco Price-Support Supply-Control Program,” Social and Economic Issues Confronting the Tobacco Industry in the Seventies. Lexington: University of Kentucky, 1972, pp. 271293.Google Scholar
[2]Chromarty, W. A.An Econometric Model of the United States Agriculture,” Journal of the American Statistical Association, Volume 54, September 1959, pp. 556574.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
[3]Johnson, Paul R.The Social Cost of the Tobacco Program,” Journal of Farm Economics, Volume 47, May 1965, pp. 242255.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
[4]Keller, Luther H. and Culver, James. “Lease and Transfer of Burley Tobacco Quota Between Farms,” Tennessee Farm and Home Science Progress Report 100, October-November-December 1976, pp. 1518.Google Scholar
[5]Langham, Max R.A Theoretical Framework for Viewing Pollution Problems,” Southern Journal of Agricultural Economics, Volume 3, December 1971, pp. 18.Google Scholar
[6]Maier, Frank H.Consumer Demand for Cigarettes Estimated from State Data,” Journal of Farm Economics, Volume 37, November 1955, pp. 690704.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
[7]Mann, Jitendar S.Techniques to Measure Social Benefits and Costs in Agriculture: A Survey,” Agricultural Economics Research, Volume 29, October 1977, pp. 115126.Google Scholar
[8]Sackrin, S. M.Factors Affecting the Demand for Cigarettes,” Agricultural Economics Research, Volume 14, July 1962, pp. 8188.Google Scholar
[9]Tweeten, Luther. Foundations of Farm Policy. Lincoln: University of Nebraska Press, 1970, pp. 188, 243, 499522.Google Scholar
[10]U. S. Department of Agriculture. Agricultural Statistics. Washington, D. C., 1977, p. 98.Google Scholar
[11]U. S. Department of Health, Education, and Welfare. Smoking and Health, Report of the Advisory Committee to the Surgeon General. Washington, D. C.: USPHS Publication No. 1103, 1964.Google Scholar
[12]U. S. Department of Health, Education, and Welfare. Smoking and Health, A Report of the Surgeon General. Washington, D. C., 1979.Google Scholar