Hostname: page-component-78c5997874-dh8gc Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-11-19T14:22:42.089Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Economy and Society in an Earlier America

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  03 March 2009

Stuart Bruchey
Affiliation:
Professor of American Economic History at Columbia University, New York, NY 10027.

Abstract

I suggest here that change in a number of social variables, including values, vertical mobility, political and social power, technology and law, appear to be associated with economic growth or decline and that the study of economic history would be enriched by investigations of the nature and timing of those linkages. Illustrative models of the linkages are drawn for the early Middle Ages in Western Europe and for the colonial and antebellum periods of American history.

Type
Papers Presented at the Forty-Sixth Annual Meeting of the Economic History Association
Copyright
Copyright © The Economic History Association 1987

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

References

He would like to thank the following for their helpful comments: Barbara A. Black, Donald Dewey, Sigmund Damond, Louis Henkin, Norman Mint, Erlc L. McKitrick, Richard B. Morris and Alden Vaughan of Columbia University; Vincent P. Carosso of New York University; Joel Colton of Duke University; Tian Kang Go of Chuo University (Tokyo); John Hoigham of the Johns Hopkins University; Jackson Turner Main of the University Colorado; Jerome J. Nadelhalf of the University of Maine; Rosalind Seneca of Drew University, and Frederick D. Williams of Michigan State University.Google Scholar

1 Beard, Charles A., An Economic Interpretation of the Constitution of the United States (New York, 1960), chap, 1 esp. pp. 5, 12.Google Scholar

2 Sharkey, Robert P., Money, Class and Power: An Economic Study of the Civil War and Reconstruction (Baltimore, 1959), chap. 7, esp. p. 293.Google Scholar

3 This standard depiction of medieval conditions hardly requires documentation. For changes in those conditions see de Roover, Raymond, in Lane, Frederic C. and Riemersma, Jelle C., eds., Enterprise and Secular Change (Homewood, 1953);Google Scholar and Baldwin, John, “The Medieval Merchant before the Bar of Canon Law,” Papers in Michigan Academy of Science, Arts, and Letters, 44 (1959).Google Scholar

4 McCusker, John J. and Menard, Russell R., The Economy of British America, 1606–1789: Needs and Opportunities for Study (Chapel Hill, 1985), chap. 3, esp. p. 60.Google Scholar

5 Ibid., pp. 269–70; Jones, Alice Hanson, Wealth of a Nation to Be: The American Colonies on the Eve of the Revolution (New York, 1980), pp. 7879;Google ScholarMenard, Russell R., “Secular Trends in the Chesapeake Tobacco Industry,” Working Papers from the Regional Economic History Research Center (Eleutherian Mills-Hagley Foundation, 1978), vol. 1, no. 3, pp. 134;Google ScholarCarr, Lois G. and Menard, Russell, “Immigration and Opportunity: The Freedman in Early Colonial Maryland,” in Tate, Thad W. and Ammerman, David L., eds., The Chesapeake in the Seventeenth Century: Essays on Anglo-American Society, (Chapel Hill, 1979), pp. 206–42Google Scholar; Shepherd, James F. and Walton, Gary M., Shipping, Maritime Trade, and the Economic Development of Colonial North America (Cambridge, 1972), p. 9;Google ScholarEngerman, Stanley L. and Gailman, Robert E., “U.S. Economic Growth, 1783–1860,” Research in Economic History, 8 (1983), pp. 146.Google Scholar

6 McCusker and Menard, The Economy of British America, pp. 298, 300.Google Scholar

7 Henretta, James, “Families and Farms: Mentalitè in Pre-Industrial America,” William and Mary Quarterly, 35, 3rd ser. (01 1978), pp. 332;CrossRefGoogle ScholarMain, Jackson Turner, The Social Structure of Revolutionary America (Princeton, 1965), p. 18.CrossRefGoogle Scholar

8 Appleby, Joyce, Capitalism and a New Social Order: The Republican Vision of the 1790s (New York, 1984), p. 6.Google Scholar

9 Degler, Carl N., Out of Our Past (New York, 1959), p. 1.Google Scholar

10 Appleby Capitalism and a New Social Order, p. 7. The expression “America was born free” is apparently from Degler, Out of Our Past, p. 5.Google ScholarBailyn, Bernard, Education in the Forming of American Society: Needs and Opportunities for Study (Chapel Hill, 1960).Google Scholar

11 Winthrop, John, “A Modell of Christian Charity,” in Morison, Samuel Eliot, ed., Old South Leaflets, No. 207 (Boston, n.d.), pp. 78.Google Scholar

12 Zuckerman, Michael, Peaceable Kingdoms: New England Towns in the Eighteenth Century (New York, 1970);Google ScholarGreven, Philip J. Jr, Four Generations: Population, Land and Family in Colonial Andover, Massachusettes (Ithaca, 1970);Google ScholarHenretta, James A., The Evolution of American Society, 1700–1815: An Interdisciplinary Analysis (Lexington, 1973);Google ScholarSmith, Daniel Scott, “Parental Power and Marriage Patterns: An Analysis of Historical Trends in Massachusetts,” Journal of Marriage and the Family, 35 (08 1973), pp. 419–28;CrossRefGoogle ScholarLockridge, Kenneth A., A New England Town, The First Hundred Years: Dedham, Massachusetts, 1636–1736 (New York, 1970);Google ScholarAllen, David G., In English Ways: The Movement of Societies and the Transferal of English Local Law and Custom to Massachusetts Bay in the Seventeenth Century (Chapel Hill, 1981);Google ScholarRhys Isaac, The Transformation of Virginia, 1740–1790 (Chapel Hill, 1982);Google ScholarGross, Robert A., The Minutemen and Their World (New York, 1976).Google Scholar I also want to express my indebtedness here to the insight of Appleby, Joyce, Capitalism and a New Social Order, esp. pp. 6–8;Google Scholar and to two articles by Henretta, James A., “Families and Farms,” and “The Morphology of New England Society,” Journal of Interdisciplinary History, 2 (Autumn 1971), pp. 379–98.CrossRefGoogle Scholar

13 Henretta, “The Morphology of New England Society,” p. 396.Google Scholar

14 Shammas, Carole, “How Self-Sufficient Was Early America?Journal of Interdisciplinary History, 13 (Autumn 1982), p. 263.CrossRefGoogle Scholar

15 Bruchey, Stuart, ed., The Colonial Merchant: Sources and Readings (New York, 1966), pp. 119–35.Google Scholar

16 Nash, Gary B. makes the point that “It is easy, however, to overstate the operation of a well-oiled set of relationships between superiors and inferiors, and the unresentful acceptance of them as natural. Many urban people deferred because their economic security was bound up with a landlord, employer, or creditor. This was economic clientage and it doubtlessly produced social deference”. The Urban Crucible: Social Change, Political Consciousness, and the Origins of the American Revolution (Cambridge, Mass., 1979), p. 9.CrossRefGoogle Scholar

17 Doerflinger, Thomas M., A Vigorous Spirit of Enterprise: Merchants and Economic Development in Revolutionary Philadelphia (Chapel Hill, 1986).Google Scholar

18 See the sources cited in the bibliography of my Roots of Economic Growth, 1607–1861: An Essay in Social Causation (New York, 1965).Google Scholar

19 See the discussion of these issues in McCusker and Menard, Economy of British America, pp. 258–76, and Jones, Wealth of a Nation to Be, pp. 155–94, 381–88.Google Scholar

20 Main, Gloria L., Tobacco Colony: Life in Early Maryland, 1650–1720 (Princeton, 1982), pp. 54, 62, 87–91, 167–68.Google Scholar

21 Jones, Wealth of a Nation to Be, p. 170.Google Scholar

22 Lipset, Seymour M. and Bendix, Reinhardt, Social Mobility In an Industrial Society (Berkeley, 1960).Google Scholar

23 Berthoff, Rowland, “The American Social Order: A Conservative Hypothesis,” American Historical Review, 65 (04. 1960). pp. 495514.CrossRefGoogle Scholar

24 Sydnor, Charles S., Gentlemen Freeholders, (Chapel Hill, 1952), p. 8;Google ScholarPalmer, R. R., The Age of Democratic Revolution: The Challenge (Princeton, 1959), pp. 188–89.Google Scholar

25 Syrett, Harold C., ed., The Papers of Alexander Hamilton (New York, 19611979), vol. 7, p. 362, quote is from Sept. 1792.Google Scholar

26 These quotations are from East, Robert A., Business Enterprise in the American Revolutionary Era (New York, 1933), pp. 213–14.Google Scholar

27 Fischer, David Hackett, The Revolution ofAmerican Conservatism: The Federalist Party in the Era of Jeffersonian Democracy (New York, 1965), p. 203.Google Scholar

28 This interpretation finds some support in the insight of Nelson, William E.. “There is evidence,” Nelson writes, “that some members of the postrevolutionary generation consciously sought legal protection of property as a means of insuring economic and social stability… The very idea of property, in sum, may have become a code word for a broad constellation of genuine conservative values, including the preservation of upper-class wealth, community stability, and, perhaps even ethnic unity.” Americanization of the Common Law, (Cambridge, Mass., 1975) p. 127.Google Scholar

29 The Life of John Marshall, 4 vols. (Boston, 19161919), vol. 1, p. 26.Google Scholar

30 In a private communication Eric L. McKitrick makes the arresting suggestion that Hamilton may well have had his own vision of growth, of growth led by merchants rather than by manufacturers. David Hume emphasized the importance of the functions performed by the merchant class and “there is clear evidence of Hamilton's having been much influenced by [Hume's] writings in preparing his own papers on the public credit.” Hamilton's appreciation of merchants is unmistakable, but I believe this is not because he viewed them as instruments of growth. Rather, it was because their imports provided the revenues (in the form of duties) that were essential to the financing of government operations and the servicing of the debt.Google Scholar

31 Ogden v. Saunders, 7 U.S. (12 Wheat), 132, 215 (1827); Sturges v. Crowninshield, 17 U.S. (4 Wheat) 362, 368 (1819).Google Scholar

32 Fletcher v. Peck 3 U.S. (6 Cranch) 86 (1810); Ogden v. Saunders, 7 U.S., 214.Google Scholar

33 Bank of the United States v. Deveaux, 9 U.S. (5 Cranch), 1809, 61.Google Scholar

34 Bank of Augusta v. Earle, 38 U.S. (13 Pet.), 1839, 519; Louisville Rail Road Co. v. Letson, 43 U.S. (2 How.), 1844, 497. I do not wish to imply that this was the end of the matter.Google Scholar

35 Craig v. The State of Missouri, 29 U.S. (4 Pet.) 1830, 410; Briscoe v. The Bank of the Commonwealth of Kentucky, 36 U.S. (11 Pet.), 1837, 257.Google Scholar

36 Ibid., p. 300.

37 The Proprietors of the Charles River Bridge v. The Proprietors of the Warren Bridge, 36 U.S. (11 Pet.), 1837, 420.Google Scholar

38 Horwitz, Morton J., The Transformation of American Law, 1780–1860 (Cambridge, Mass., 1977), p. 134.Google Scholar

39 Dorfman, Joseph, The Economic Mind in American Civilizailon, 1606–1865 (New York, 1946).Google Scholar

40 Syrett, ed., Hamilton Papers, vol. 10, pp. 230–340.Google Scholar

41 Nelson, John R., “Alexander Hamilton and American Manufacturing: A Reexamination,” Journal of American History, 65 (03. 1979), p. 977.CrossRefGoogle Scholar

42 Syrett, ed., Hamilton Papers, vol. 6, pp. 73–78 (January 9, 1790);Google Scholar; Ibid.., 9, pp. 193–94(03 26, 1792.)

43 Nelson, “Alexander Hamilton and American Manufacturing,” pp. 977, 981–82, 986, 994.Google Scholar

44 Letter from Alexander Hamilton to Seton, William, January. 18, 1792. Hamilton Papers, vol. 10, p. 525.Google Scholar

45 “Report on a National Bank,” December. 13, 1790. Hamilton Papers, vol. 7, pp. 325, 331.Google Scholar

46 Holdsworth, John Thom and Dewey, Davis R., The First and Second Banks of the United Stales (Washington, D.C., 1910), p. 45.Google Scholar

47 Wettereau, James O., The Statistical Records of the United Slates (New York, 1985), pp. 229305.Google Scholar Unfortunately, it cannot be determined whether figures are for lodged deposits or for those created by the Bank in extending its loans.

48 Minutes of the Board of Directors, October. 27, 1795. Papers of Wettereau, James O., Special Collections, Rare Book and Manuscripts Library, Columbia University. These minutes are verbatim copies made by Wettereau. The originals are in the Cadwalader manuscripts in the Historical Society of Pennsylvania.Google Scholar

49 Gouge, William M., A Short History of Paper-money and Banking (New York, 1855), p. 61;Google Scholar and members on the Staff, Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System, Banking Studies (Washington, D.C., 1941), pp. 417–18.Google Scholar

50 Van Fenstermaker, J., The Development of American Commercial Banking: 1782–1837 (Kent, 1965), p. 13, appendices A, B.Google Scholar

51 Quoted in Hammond, Bray, Banking and Politics in America Between the Revolution and the Civil War (Princeton, 1957), p. 338.Google Scholar

52 Bruchey, Roots of American Economic Growrh, p. 137.Google Scholar

53 Clark, Victor S., History of Manufactures in the United States, 1607–1860, 3 vols. (Washington, D.C., 1929), vol. 1, pp. 78, 87–88, 175–79;Google ScholarFogel, Robert W., Railroads and American Economic Growth: Essays in Econo, netric History (Baltimore, 1964), pp. 121–27, esp. p. 126.Google Scholar

54 Galiman, Robert E. thinks that the annual rate of advance in per capita product in the 30-odd years before 1840 was “probably a good deal higher than the estimated rate of growth for the whole period, 1710–1840”.Google Scholar He adds: “Rapid rates of growth have been evident in the American record from the early decades of the nineteenth century” in Davis, Lance E., et al. , eds., American Economic Growth, An Economist's History of the United States (New York, 1972), pp. 29, 42.Google Scholar

55 Ward, John William, Andrew Jackson: Symbol for an Age (New York, 1962);Google ScholarWylie, Irwin G., The Self-Made Man in America (New Brunswick, 1954);Google ScholarDiamond, Sigmund, The Reputation of the American Businessman (Cambridge, Mass., 1955);CrossRefGoogle ScholarDorfman, Joseph, The Economic Mind in American Civilization.Google Scholar