Hostname: page-component-78c5997874-94fs2 Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-11-03T13:38:11.036Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Legal and Economic Development: The Missing Links

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  02 January 2018

Abstract

Image of the first page of this content. For PDF version, please use the ‘Save PDF’ preceeding this image.'
Type
Review Essay
Copyright
Copyright © University of Miami 1993

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

References

Arrow, K. (1975) “Innovations in Large and Small Firms,” in Rosen, Joshua (ed.) Entrepreneurship. Lexington, MA: D.C. Heath.Google Scholar
Arrow, K. (1962) “Economic Welfare and the Allocation of Resources for Invention,” in the Rate and Direction of Inventive Activity. Universities-National Bureau Committee for Economic Research, Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Balassa, B. (1978) “Exports and Economic Growth: Further Evidence.” Journal of Development Economics 5, 2.Google Scholar
Bhagwati, J. (1978) Foreign Exchange Regimes and Economic Development: Anatomy and Consequences of Exchange Control Regimes. Cambridge, MA: Ballinger Press.Google Scholar
Buscaglia, E. Jr. (1993) Law, Technological Progress, and Economic Development (Working Paper in International Studies 1-93-5). Stanford, CA: The Hoover Institution, Stanford University.Google Scholar
Buscaglia, E. Jr. (1992) “Now that Argentina's Stable, It's Time for a Revolution.” The Wall Street Journal (28 August): A12.Google Scholar
Buscaglia, E. Jr. (1991) “Delineation of Property Rights and Economic Growth” (Working Paper Series #91-2). Berkeley, CA: University of California, Program in Law and Economics.Google Scholar
Coase, R. (1992) “The Institutional Structure of Production.” American Review 82, 4 (September): 713719.Google Scholar
Cooter, R. and Ulen, T. (1988) Law and Economics. New York, NY: Harper Collins.Google Scholar
David, P. (1975) Technical Change, Innovation, and Economic Growth. Cambridge, MA: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Denison, E. (1979) Accounting for Slower Economic Growth. Washington, DC: The Brookings Institution.Google Scholar
De Soto, H. (1986) El Otro Sendero. Lima, Peru: Editorial El Barranco.Google Scholar
Kreuger, A. (1978) Foreign Exchange Regimes and Economic Development: Liberalization Attempts and Consequences. Cambridge, MA: Ballinger Press.Google Scholar
Landau, R. (1990) “Capital Investment: Key to Competitiveness and Growth.” The Brookings Review (Summer): 5256.Google Scholar
Lucas, R. (1988) “On the Mechanics of Economic Development.” Journal of Monetary Economics 22: 342.Google Scholar
Mowery, D. and Rosenberg, N. (1989) Economic Growth. New York, NY: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Nelson, R. (1991) “Capitalism as an Engine of Progress.” Research Policy 3.Google Scholar
Nelson, R. and Winter, S. (1982) An Economic Theory of Economic Change. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.Google Scholar
North, D. (1990) Institutions, Institutional Change, and Economic Performance. Cambridge, MA: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
North, D. and Weingast, B. (1989) “The Evolution of Institutions Governing Public Choice in 17th Century England.” Journal of Economic History 49: 803832.Google Scholar
Olson, M. (1965) The Logic of Collective Action. Cambridge, England: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Pejovich, S. (1982) “Karl Marx, Property Rights School, and the Process of Social Change.” Kylos 35, 3: 383397.Google Scholar
Prebisch, R. (1950) Economic Development of Latin America and its Principal Problems. Lake Success, NY: United Nations.Google Scholar
Ratliff, W. (1992) “The Same Monkey in Managua” (International Studies Working Paper). Stanford, CA: The Hoover Institution, Stanford University.Google Scholar
Richards, T. (1988) “Intellectual Property Rights: Reconciling Divergent Views,” in Walker, Charles and Bloomfield, Mark (eds.) Intellectual Property Rights and Capital Formation in the Next Decade. London, England: University Press of America.Google Scholar
Rosenberg, N., Landau, R., and Mowery, D. (1990) Technology and the Wealth of Nations. Stanford, CA: Stanford University Press.Google Scholar
Schultz, T. (1964) Transforming Traditional Agriculture. New Haven, CT: Yale University Press.Google Scholar
Simon, H. (1991) “Organizations and Markets,” The Journal of Economic Perspectives 5, 2 (Spring).Google Scholar
Simon, H. (1986) “Rationality in Psychology and Economics,” in Hogarth, Robin M. and Reder, Melvin (eds.) The Behavioral Foundations of Economic Theory [supplement to the Journal of Business 59: S209-S24].Google Scholar
Singer, H. (1950) “The Distribution of Trade between Investing and Borrowing Countries,” American Economic Review 40: 470485.Google Scholar
Solow, R. (1957) “Technical Change and Aggregate Production Function.” Review of Economics and Statistics VI: 234256.Google Scholar
Stone, A. and Paredes, R. (1992) “Measuring the Costs of Doing Business in Latin America” (mimeo; unpublished). Washington, DC: The World Bank.Google Scholar
Syrquin, M. and Chenery, H. (1989) “Three Decades of Industrialization.” The World Bank Economic Review 3, 2:145181.Google Scholar
Teece, D. (1989) “Intellectual Property and Strategic Management” (unpublished manuscript; July). Berkeley, CA: University of California, Center for Research in Management.Google Scholar
Teece, D. (1986) “Profiting from Technological Innovation,” Research Policy 15, 6: 285306.Google Scholar
Williamson, O. (1985) The Economic Institutions of Capitalism. New York, NY: The Free Press.Google Scholar
Winter, S. (1987) “Know-How and Competence as Strategic Assets,” in Teece, David (ed.) The Competitive Challenge. Cambridge, MA: Ballinger.Google Scholar