Hostname: page-component-586b7cd67f-t8hqh Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-11-28T08:43:41.007Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Early Sales of Bordeaux grands crus*

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  08 June 2012

Philippe Mahenc
Affiliation:
LERNA-INRA, Manufacture des Tabacs, 21 Allée de Brienne, 31000 Toulouse,France and University of Perpignan. Email: mahenc@univ-perp.fr
Valérie Meunier
Affiliation:
University of Aarhus, School of Economies and Management, Building 322, 8000 Aarhus C,Denmark. Email: vmeunier@econ.au.dk.

Abstract

En primeur sales of Bordeaux grands crus occur every spring on the Bordeaux marketplace and represent the main source of supply for wine merchants. We address two specific issues related to the en primeur strategy. First, we study whether en primeur prices are good estimates of wines' qualities, as well as how they may reveal any relevant information to uninformed buyers. Second, we consider which roles en primeur sales may play between traders, given the market informational and competitive structures. (JEL classification: D42, D82, L15.)

Type
Articles
Copyright
Copyright © American Association of Wine Economists 2006

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

References

Akerlof, G. A. (1970). The market for ‘lemons”: qualitative uncertainty and the market mechanism. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 84, 488500.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Allaz, B. and Vila, J.-L. (1993). Cournot competition, forward markets and efficiency. Journal of Economic Theory, 59, 116.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Anderson, R. W. (1984). The industrial organization of futures markets: a survey. In Anderson, R.W. (ed.), The Industrial Organization of Futures Markets. Lexington, Mass.: Lexington Books.Google Scholar
Anderson, R. W. and Danthine, J-P. (1983). Hedger diversity in futures markets. Economic Journal, 93, 370389.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Anderson, R. W. and Sundaresan, M. (1984). Futures markets and monopoly. In: Anderson, R. (ed.), The Industrial Organization of Futures Markets. Lexington, Mass.: Lexington Books.Google Scholar
Ashenfelter, O. and Jones, G. (1998). The demand for expert opinion: Bordeaux wine. Working Paper, presented at the 6th Annual Meeting of the Vineyard Data Quantification Society, October 2–3 1998.Google Scholar
Bagwell, K. and Riordan, M. H. (1991). High and declining prices signal product quality. American Economic Review, 81, 224239.Google Scholar
Combris, P., Lecocq, S. and Visser, M. (1997). Estimation of a hedonic price equation for Bordeaux wine: does quality matter?. Economic Journal, 107, 390402.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Danthine, J-P. (1978). Information, futures markets and stabilizing speculation. Journal of Economic Theory, 17, 7998.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Di Vittorio, A. and Ginsburgh, V. (1996). Des enchères comme révélateurs du classement des vins. Journal de la Société Statistique de Paris, 137, 1949.Google Scholar
Gergaud, O. and Ginsburgh, V. (2001). Endowments, production technologies and the quality of wines. Is it possible to produce wine on paved roads? Working Paper, presented at the 9th Annual Meeting of the Vineyard Data Quantification Society, May 2001.Google Scholar
Grossman, S. J. (1977). The existence of futures markets, noisy rational expectations and informational externalities. Review of Economic Studies, 44, 431449.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hadj Ali, H. and Nauges, C. (2003). Vente en primeur et investissement: une etude sur les grands crus de Bordeaux. Economie et Prévisions, 159, 93103.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Landon, S. and Smith, C.E. (1997). The use of quality and reputation indicators by consumers: the case of bordeaux wine. Journal of Consumer Policy, 20, 289323.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Mahenc, P. (2004). The influence of informed buyers in markets susceptible to the lemons problem. American Journal of Agricultural Economics, 86, 649659.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Mahenc, P. and Meunier, V. (2003). Forward markets and signals of quality. RAND Journal of Economics, 34, 478494.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Mahenc, P. and Sálanié, F. (2004). Softening competition through forward trading. Journal of Economic Theory, 116, 282293.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Milgrom, P. and Roberts, J. (1986). Price and advertising signals of product quality. Journal of Political Economy, 94, 796821.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Nelson, P. (1970). Information and consumer behavior. Journal of Political Economy, 78, 311329.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Nelson, P. (1974). Advertising as information. Journal of Political Economy, 81, 729754.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Newbery, D. M. G. (1984). The manipulation of futures markets by a dominant producer. In: Anderson, R. (ed.), The Industrial Organization of Futures Markets. Lexington, Mass.: Lexington Books.Google Scholar
Newbery, D. M. G. and Stiglitz, J.E. (1981). The Theory of Commodity Price Stabilization. Oxford: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Renvoisé, G. (1994). Le monde du Vin, Art ou Bluff. Rodez: Editions du Rouergue.Google Scholar
Schmalensee, R. ( 1978). A Model of Advertising and Product Quality. Journal of Political Economy, 86, 485503.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Shapiro, C. (1983). Premiums for high quality products as rents to reputation. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 98, 659680.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Spence, M. (1973). Job market signaling. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 85, 355379.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Spence, M. (1976). Informational aspects of market structure: an introduction. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 90, 591597.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Tirole, J. (1988). The Theory of Industrial Organization. Cambridge, Mass.: MIT Press.Google Scholar
Voss, R. (2002). 2001: An en primeur Odyssey. Wine Enthusiast, July 2002.Google Scholar