Hostname: page-component-5c6d5d7d68-txr5j Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-08-16T15:11:51.751Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Better understanding how uncertainty impacts the economy: Insights from internet search data on the importance of disaggregation

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  21 June 2022

Kalvinder Shields*
Affiliation:
University of Melbourne
Trung Duc Tran
Affiliation:
Reserve Bank of Australia
*
*Corresponding author. Email: k.shields@unimelb.edu.au. Phone: +61 3 9035 5511.
Rights & Permissions [Opens in a new window]

Abstract

We study the impact of uncertainty shocks using a disaggregated model featuring US state-level unemployment, and uncertainty measured using state-level Google search data. Importantly, the model captures spillovers across states and identifies substantial differences in peak responses and time dynamics. Moreover, the importance of national factors in propagating the effect of uncertainty is also heterogeneous across states, but less relevant than state-level factors. These heterogeneous effects are related to state-specific industry compositions and fiscal positions. In addition, we highlight the usefulness of disaggregated data in models of uncertainty and economic activity for the USA, based on the superior ability of the disaggregate model to predict aggregate uncertainty and unemployment.

Type
Articles
Creative Commons
Creative Common License - CCCreative Common License - BY
This is an Open Access article, distributed under the terms of the Creative Commons Attribution licence (http://creativecommons.org/licenses/by/4.0/), which permits unrestricted re-use, distribution, and reproduction in any medium, provided the original work is properly cited.
Copyright
© The Author(s), 2022. Published by Cambridge University Press

1. Introduction

Uncertainty is a major driver in the slow recovery of real economic activity during and after recessions [for surveys, see Bloom (Reference Bloom2014) or Castelnuovo (Reference Castelnuovo2019)]. Most of the existing literature has focused on documenting the aggregate (national) impact of uncertainty on real economic activity [see, e.g. Angelini et al. (Reference Angelini, Bacchiocchi, Caggiano and Fanelli2018); Baker et al. (Reference Baker, Bloom and Davis2016); Bachmann et al. (Reference Bachmann, Elstner and Sims2013); Bloom (Reference Bloom2009); Caggiano et al. (Reference Caggiano, Castelnuovo and Groshenny2014); Carriero et al. (Reference Carriero, Clark and Marcellino2018b); Fernández-Villaverde et al. (Reference Fernández-Villaverde, Guerrón-Quintana, Kuester and Rubio-Ramírez2015); Jurado et al. (Reference Jurado, Ludvigson and Ng2015a); Leduc and Liu (Reference Leduc and Liu2016); Ludvigson et al. (Reference Ludvigson, Ma and Ng2020); Mumtaz and Surico (Reference Mumtaz and Surico2018); Rossi and Sekhposyan (Reference Rossi and Sekhposyan2015) or Scotti (Reference Scotti2016)]. However, the focus on aggregated measures of uncertainty can conceal considerable heterogeneity across areas due to differences, for example, in the composition of production, employment, demographics, and regulations in the financial and public sector. Such differences suggest that greater insights about the role of uncertainty on economic activity can be gained through measuring uncertainty, and identifying its impacts on economic activity, at a more disaggregated area level. Using a model that accommodates potential interactions and spillovers at the disaggregated level, therefore, has the potential to provide new insights into the extent of mitigation or amplification in the transmission of uncertainty across the whole economy.

In this paper, we contribute to the uncertainty literature in a number of ways. First, we propose a novel measure of uncertainty for each of the 51 US states using Google Trends search data (GTU). Along with Bontempi et al. (Reference Bontempi, Golinelli and Squadrani2019) and Castelnuovo and Tran (Reference Castelnuovo and Tran2017), this paper is one of the first to use internet search data to construct an uncertainty index.Footnote 1 The credibility of such an approach to measure uncertainty is illustrated in Castelnuovo and Tran (Reference Castelnuovo and Tran2017) who highlight substantial correlations of the GTU index for the USA as a whole with a variety of different proxies for uncertainty proposed in the literature.Footnote 2 We build on these previous studies by considering the construction and evaluation of disaggregated (state-level) uncertainty indices. We propose that a reliable proxy of uncertainty can be built upon state-specific Google search data on the premise that when economic agents are uncertain about the future, they tend to look for information on the internet. In particular, we focus on uncertainty-related keywords mentioned in the “Beige Books” as published by the Federal Reserve.

The Beige Books gather information on current economic conditions based on interviews with key business contacts, economists, and market experts. Given that the chosen uncertainty-related keywords are those related to influencing business conditions—and that economic agents are more likely to search when there is a higher likelihood of negative economic events—the GTU is most likely to capture the downside risk relevant to the business environment. However, there is also the potential of the index to capture upside risk in the case where firms are looking to make favorable investment decisions in conditions of long-term uncertainty [see Bar-Ilan and Strange (Reference Bar-Ilan and Strange1996) for instance]. Importantly, we find that the GTU index we construct is consistent with other existing uncertainty indices at both the aggregate level as illustrated in Castelnuovo and Tran (Reference Castelnuovo and Tran2017) and with the model-based state-level uncertainty measure in Mumtaz (Reference Mumtaz2018). Therefore, we contend that the use of state-specific Google search data provides real-time, easily accessible and timely information by which to construct measures of uncertainty at the state level for the US economy.

Second, we believe that this is the first paper to explicitly accommodate the dynamic interactions between uncertainty and economic activity across states and across time through a comprehensive and integrated framework. We apply a Global Vector Autoregressive modeling framework [GVAR; elaborated in Garratt et al. (Reference Garratt, Robertson and Wright2006), Dees et al. (Reference Dees, Mauro, Pesaran and Smith2007) and Chudik and Pesaran (Reference Chudik and Pesaran2016)], which jointly models monthly uncertainty and the unemployment rate for the 51 states while allowing for feedback between these variables. The comprehensive specification of this disaggregate model means that we are then able to identify the relative importance of national versus state-specific factors in the propagation of uncertainty shocks on unemployment dynamics at the state level, and their respective associations with a number of state-specific demographic and economic characteristics. Accordingly, existing state-level studies such as Mumtaz et al. (Reference Mumtaz, Sunder-Plassmann and Theophilopoulou2018), Mumtaz (Reference Mumtaz2018) and Shoag and Veuger (Reference Shoag and Veuger2016) are complemented by (1) providing a flexible method for characterizing the evolution over time of the respective state-specific uncertainty and economic activity variables and (2) allowing for relatively complicated forms of interactions and spillover effects between these state-specific variables. Notably, Mumtaz et al. (Reference Mumtaz, Sunder-Plassmann and Theophilopoulou2018) do not measure uncertainty at the state-level but focus only on the impact of national uncertainty on US states, while Mumtaz (Reference Mumtaz2018) and Shoag and Veuger (Reference Shoag and Veuger2016) abstract from state-level feedbacks as well as time dynamics in the propagation of state-level uncertainty.Footnote 3

The importance of disaggregation is relevant to consider in any modeling framework given that the basis of how the economy operates generally involves (highly) interconnected disaggregated units. However, the question of whether a more disaggregate model and particularly, our state-level GTU measures add significant information over an aggregate model will need some formal analysis. First, we judge the statistical adequacy of (linear) aggregate and disaggregate specifications based on the prediction of an aggregate series of interest [see Pesaran et al. (Reference Pesaran, Pierse and Kumar1989) (PPK), Pesaran et al. (Reference Pesaran, Pierse and Lee1994) (PPL) and Van Garderen et al. (Reference Van Garderen, Lee and Pesaran2000) (GLP), for instance]. Second, we investigate the usefulness of the disaggregate model and our state-level GTU uncertainty measures relative to other candidate models through conducting an out-of-sample forecasting exercise. Both analyses provide strong evidence to support the usefulness of disaggregated data in our US state context. The use of a (misspecified) aggregate model therefore would lead us to overlook relevant feedbacks and interactions in the analysis on the impact of uncertainty on the economy.

Moreover, we find that the impact of aggregate uncertainty shocks on unemployment in the disaggregate model, generated as a weighted average of state-level uncertainty shock, is lower compared to the aggregate model, and the dissemination of the uncertainty shocks take almost twice as long relative to the aggregate model. This suggests that the process of aggregation which averages over the heterogeneity in the dynamics concerning the propagation of uncertainty across states, in this context, omits essential dynamics that are significant in driving economic activity at the aggregate level. Although the peak effect is different from a statistical perspective, we still find an important effect of uncertainty shocks in both the models.

In addition, we find that the responses of unemployment in US states to an aggregate uncertainty shock are heterogeneous. The paper provides a narrative to this heterogeneity using various variables capturing state-specific characteristics such as industry composition, fiscal constraints, labor market, and financial frictions in a post-regression analysis. We find that the unemployment rates in states with a larger concentration of the manufacturing industries are affected more by uncertainty shocks, while a larger share of the mining industry mitigates the impact of uncertainty.Footnote 4

In terms of evaluating the relative importance of national factors in propagating the effects of uncertainty shocks on state-level economic activity relative to state-specific factors [see Garratt et al. (Reference Garratt, Lee and Shields2018)], on average, we find the national factors to be less important, although there is significant heterogeneity across states. In general, and as expected, the presence of national factors serves to amplify the effects of uncertainty shocks on state-level unemployment. We then investigate the explanatory power of state-specific characteristics in the heterogeneous importance of the national factors. The results show the relative importance of national influences is greater in states where the real estate sector is greater. It is possible that the larger importance of the national factors in these states reflect the increasing contagion between the financial market and the real estate market during the GFC.Footnote 5 In contrast, we find states with a more active fiscal policy experience a smaller influence of national factors in the impact and propagation of uncertainty shocks. The finding suggests the role of the state government expenditures in offseting the national influences.

The remainder of the paper is organized as follows. Section 2 explains in more detail the construction of the uncertainty index. Section 3 presents the GVAR framework on which this analysis is based. Section 4 outlines the statistical methods for assessing the adequacy of the disaggregate model relative to its aggregate counterpart, investigates the dynamics of the GVAR model, and estimates the impact of uncertainty shocks on economic activity. This section further explores the relative importance of national factors versus state-specific factors in propagating the effect of uncertainty shocks for each state through a decomposition analysis. Section 5 provides a subsequent regression analysis using state-specific characteristics to provide insights into the heterogeneous effects of uncertainty. Section 6 provides some concluding comments.

2. Measuring economic uncertainty

The construction of the uncertainty index is based on the premise that when economic agents, represented by internet users, are uncertain about the future, they tend to look for information on the internet. Under this assumption, the search frequency would be high when the level of uncertainty for a certain topic is high. Google search data is well suited to be the measure of economic uncertainty due to its representative power. According to Comscore (2016), Google has been dominating the online search market in the USA, where its market share has risen 64% in 2016. By exploiting this data-rich environment, the uncertainty index is able to capture the level of uncertainty represented by searchers who are potentially concerned or affected by the state of the economy.

An intuitive example of how to construct a simplified uncertainty index can be found in Appendix 2. It is important to note that, for privacy reasons, Google Trends data does not report the absolute level of queries for a given search term. Instead, Google Trends provides data which gives the frequency of a particular search term relative to the total search volume ranging between 0 and 100. These reported relative search frequencies are constructed as follows. The total search volume for a search term, $R_{{\omega},t,i}$ , where $\omega$ denotes the search term, at time $t,$ for the location it represents, $i,$ is divided by the total searches in that geographical region at a point in time, $\overline{S}$ : $S_{\omega,t,i}=\frac{R_{\omega,t,i}}{\overline{S}_{t,i}}$ .Footnote 6 For exposition purposes, the subscript $i$ is dropped to simplify notation for now.Footnote 7 The resulting numbers are then scaled to a range between 0 and 100, where 100 represents the point where the search frequency is highest, $\text{FI}_{\omega,t}=\frac{100}{M}S_{\omega,t}$ and $M=\max \{S_{\omega,1},S_{\omega,2},\ldots,S_{\omega,T}\}$ . Data are excluded if searches are made by very few people. The downside of Google search data, as noted by Choi and Varian (Reference Choi and Varian2009), is that the exact replication of the data is not feasible due to sampling variability, especially for small-volume search terms. This, however, is not an issue in this study, since small-volume search terms play minimal role after the aggregation process which is outlined in what follows.

The chosen method of aggregating aims to reflect the true search volume relating to each respective search term and, accordingly, a term which is searched more frequently will hold a larger weight in the final aggregated index. As Google only allows the input of a maximum of five different search terms in the Google Trends search engine at any one time, a benchmark term is chosen for the purpose of aggregation since the search frequency provided by Google Trends, $\text{FI}_{\omega,t}$ will alter depending on the choice of the other search terms included in that particular search. This is implemented in the following manner. First, a benchmark term is chosen and entered into the Google Trends search engine together with another search term. The search frequency for the benchmark term in this search is $\text{FI}_{\text{benchmark},t}^{1}$ and the output for the other term is $\text{FI}_{\omega,t}^{1}$ . Second, this process is repeated for the rest of the list of search terms. The frequency of the chosen benchmark term when entered into Google Trends with another search term, $\text{FI}_{\text{benchmark},t}^{2}$ , will not be necessarily the same as the benchmark value in the first step, $\text{FI}_{\text{benchmark},t}^{1}$ as the highest search term in the new combination is automatically set to take a maximum of 100. The search frequency for the remaining search terms in Step 2 is $\text{FI}_{\omega,t}^{2}$ . The true frequency of new search terms (conditional on the search frequency of the benchmark term in Step 1), $\text{FI}_{\omega,t}^{1}$ , is calculated by using the adjusting ratio, $\text{FI}_{\omega,t}^{1}=\text{FI}_{\omega,t}^{2}\times \frac{\text{FI}_{\text{benchmark},t}^{1}}{\text{FI}_{\text{benchmark},t}^{2}}$ .Footnote 8

The Google Trends uncertainty index, $\text{GTU}_{t}$ is the sum of all the scaled search terms where $\overline{\omega }$ is the total number of search terms:

(1) \begin{equation} \text{GTU}_{t}=\sum _{\omega =1}^{\overline{\omega }}\text{FI}_{\omega,t}^{1} \end{equation}

The construction of the index involves identifying which search terms are related to the level of uncertainty in the economy. Our approach is akin to the approach undertaken in Baker et al. (Reference Baker, Bloom and Davis2016) which involved counting the frequency of uncertainty-related words in newspapers. The list of search terms in this paper makes use of the Federal Reserve Bank’s Beige Books. The Beige Book is a summary of economic conditions in the US prepared by the 12 Federal Reserve Districts. Each Federal Reserve Bank gathers anecdotal information on current economic conditions in its District through reports from Bank and Branch directors and interviews with key business contacts, economists, market experts, and other sources. The Beige Book therefore contains valuable information on the factors which contribute to economic agents’ perceptions of uncertainty. When uncertainty is mentioned in a passage, the passage is then examined in more detail to determine the factors which are causing the respective economic agents being interviewed to reveal their uncertainties. These passages are then "human-coded" into a broad set of keywords which are subjectively chosen and which represent such uncertainties. The final set of 85 keywords are presented in Table 1 and form the search terms in Google Trends. Examination of the Beige Book over the past 20 years gives sufficient information on the factors which are accordingly being associated with uncertainty. Consequently, uncertainties are typically related to the banking and finance sector, economic and business conditions, price levels, job market conditions, fiscal and monetary policy, change in regulations, and the housing market.Footnote 9

Table 1. List of search terms

Figure 1 plots the time-varying uncertainty index (GTUit) from 2006M01 to 2018M03, for selected states (i), along with the national uncertainty index, where the national uncertainty index is constructed as the population-weighted average of 51 individual state-level uncertainties in the USA, constructed according to the approach described above. It should be also noted that although the list of search terms is common for all states, the idiosyncratic characteristics of uncertainty measures across different states are driven by differences in perceptions of different sources of uncertainty. While the credibility of the GTU index is illustrated in Castelnuovo and Tran (Reference Castelnuovo and Tran2017) through the strong correlations exhibited with other existing aggregate uncertainty measure, the state-level GTU measures are also found to have considerable correlations with the state-level macroeconomic uncertainty measures constructed in Mumtaz (Reference Mumtaz2018), where the average cross-state correlation is found to be 0.35. In Section 4.2, we conduct a more formal investigation into the usefulness of our state-level GTU measures.

Figure 1. GTU index for selected states in the USA. Notes: The index is transformed to have a mean of 100 and standard deviation of 30. The shaded area represents the Great Recession.

Uncertainty at the state-level and national-level peaks during the Great Recession and returns to more stable levels post-recession. Both state-level uncertainties and the national-level uncertainty show considerable comovements for much of the time.Footnote 10 However, there are period in which there is considerable divergence—in the cases of California and New York, for example. The deviation in New York in June 2011, for instance, is caused by search terms involving austerity, debt ceiling, health care reform, and unemployment benefits. The list of keywords associated with periods of major deviations can be found in Table A3 of the Appendix.

Figure 2 shows the cross-state correlation plot for uncertainty (top panel) and the quarterly change in the unemployment rate (bottom panel). The figure shows a considerable degree of comovement between uncertainty across states and unemployment across states. Conceptually speaking, the idiosyncratic characteristics of uncertainty measures across different states are driven by differences in perceptions of uncertainty. However, it is also the case that the share of internet users can also contribute to such idiosyncratic behavior. The share of internet users are not homogeneous across states, for instance, 65% of the population use the internet in Alabama, while this statistics reaches 80% in California.

Figure 2. Cross-state uncertainty correlation.

3. The modeling framework

The GVAR framework provides an effective way of modeling interactions and feedbacks at a disaggregate state level; such a framework is not only able to interlink the US economy via a common uncertainty channel effect but also takes into account the unobserved interactions. The full technical details of the GVAR model can be found in Section 4 of the Appendix. In essence, the GVAR model is implemented in two steps. In the first step, each individual model explains the state-specific variable, $x_{it}$ , collected in the $k_{i}\times 1$ vector; conditional on the cross-sectional averages of all the other state variables, denoted, $x_{it}^{\ast }$ , collected in the $k_{i}^{\ast }\times 1$ vector. For each state $i\in 1,\ldots,N$ , a VARX* model is estimated as:

(2) \begin{equation} x_{it}=\alpha _{i0}+\sum _{l=1}^{p_{i}}\Phi _{il}x_{i,t-l}+\sum _{l=0}^{q_{i}}\Lambda _{il}x_{i,t-l}^{\ast }+u_{it} \end{equation}

where $\Phi _{il}$ are $k_{i}\times k_{i}$ coefficient matrices relating to own respective states, $\Lambda _{il}$ are $k_{i}\times k_{i}^{\ast }$ matrices for "foreign" states, and $p_{i}$ and $q_{i}$ are the number of lags for each of these, respectively, and $\Sigma _{u}$ denotes the variance-covariance matrix of $u_{it}.$

In the second step, these individual state models are then linked and solved simultaneously as one large global VAR model (GVAR). The GVAR model is able to link the individual model together as a global system by using some intuitive weighting matrices that determine the interconnectedness among the individual models such as GDP weights, population weights or even distance weights. In this sense, the aggregate variable in the GVAR model is constructed from individual variables rather than being a true aggregate variable. Population weights are chosen because the correlation between the true US unemployment rate and the aggregated unemployment rate, and the correlation between the true US uncertainty and the aggregated uncertainty are higher relative to when other weighting matrices are used.Footnote 11 The GVAR model is given as:

(3) \begin{equation} x_{t}=b_{0}+\sum _{l=1}^r F_{l}x_{t-l}+\epsilon _{t} \end{equation}

where $x_{t}=(x_{0t},x_{1t},\ldots,x_{Nt})^{\prime }$ is the $k\times 1$ vector that collects all the endogenous variables of the system, and $r=\max \{p_i,q_i\}$ .

The GVAR framework therefore allows interactions among different states through three channels: (i) the contemporaneous effect of $x_{it}^{\ast }$ on $x_{it}$ and its lagged values; (ii) the effect of the common exogenous variable on the state-specific variable; and (iii) the contemporaneous dependence of shocks in state $i$ on the shocks in state $j$ .

4. Modeling disaggregated unemployment and uncertainty fluctuations in the USA

4.1 Data

The GVAR framework captures the spillover and feedback effects between uncertainty and unemployment within and across states. The model is estimated using two variables for each state: state-level uncertainty and the state-level unemployment for 51 US states from 2006M01 to 2018M03. Uncertainty for each state is measured according to the method outlined in Section 2 and is in a levels form. Unemployment is measured as the 3-month change in the unemployment rate, measured every month to ensure the stability of the GVAR responses.Footnote 12 The flexibility of this GVAR framework is that it also allows for a relatively parsimonious reduced form representation of the macroeconomy through the accommodation of the effects of aggregate variables—such as interest rates or inflation, for instance, without their necessary explicit inclusion. In essence, to the extent that such aggregate variables are important determinants of state-specific unemployment, their heterogenous effects will be captured through current and lagged values of the starred variables.Footnote 13

Due to the short time span of the Google search data, the maximum $p_{i}$ is 2 and the maximum $q_{i}$ is 1 following Dees et al. (Reference Dees, Mauro, Pesaran and Smith2007).Footnote 14 Based on the Akaike information criterion (AIC), a VARX*(1,1) is fitted to most states. A specification search is also performed on the coefficients and insignificant coefficients for which the absolute value of the $t$ -ratio being less than 1 are excluded from the model.Footnote 15

4.2 Assessing the Adequacy of the Disaggregate Model

4.2.1 Joint significance

The joint significance of the foreign variables

GVAR models allow for potentially important cross-state interaction information that cannot be explicitly captured in more aggregate models. As described earlier, the presence of the starred or foreign variables allow uncertainty and unemployment to be interconnected across states that are represented by the coefficient matrices $\Lambda$ . To investigate the statistical importance of these variables, however, the joint significance of cross-state interactions is calculated through an F-test of the joint significance of starred uncertainty variables and starred unemployment variables in each of the uncertainty and the unemployment equations for each of the individual state models.

Table 2 reports the F-test statistics associated with testing of the following null: $H_{0}:\Lambda _{i0}^{\tau }=\Lambda _{i1}^{\tau }=0$ for $i=1,\ldots,N$ and for $\tau =1,\ldots,4$ .Footnote 16 The table shows that there is significant statistical evidence showing the importance of starred uncertainty and starred unemployment in each of the state-specific equations. In other words, there is evidence of substantial interaction of economic activity and behavior across disaggregate units and therefore gives support to the use of the GVAR modeling approach as an appropriate framework to capture these complex interactions.

Table 2. F-test statistics on the joint significance of national uncertainty ( $us^*$ ) and national unemployment ( $ur^*$ )

Notes: This shows the F-test statistics of the joint significance of national uncertainty ( $us*$ ) and national unemployment ( $ur*$ ) of the state-level uncertainty and unemployment equations $^{***}p\lt 0.01$ , $^{**}p\lt 0.05$ , $^{*}p\lt 0.1$ .

The Joint Significance of the State-Specific Uncertainty Variables

Given there are substantial interactions between uncertainty measures across states, we next investigate whether our state-specific uncertainty measures provide meaningful information content in describing the variation in uncertainty above and beyond the information already provided by the aggregate or common factor element. To investigate the statistical importance of the idiosyncratic uncertainty component, therefore, the joint significance is calculated through an F-test of the joint significance of state-specific uncertainty in each of the uncertainty and the unemployment equations for each of the individual state models.

Table 3 reports the F-test statistics associated with testing of the following null: $H_{0}:\Phi _{i1}^{\upsilon }=\Phi _{i2}^{\upsilon }=0$ for $i=1,\ldots,N$ and for $\upsilon =1,2$ .Footnote 17 The table shows that there is significant statistical evidence showing the importance of idiosyncratic uncertainty component in almost all states. On the whole, despite the substantial interaction of economic activity across states, there is evidence that the idiosyncratic components also provide meaningful contributions in explaining fluctuations in state-level economic activity and uncertainty.

Table 3. F-test statistics on the joint significance of state-specific uncertainty ( $us$ )

Notes: This shows the F-test statistics of the joint significance of state uncertainty ( $us$ ) of the state-level uncertainty and unemployment equations $^{***}p\lt 0.01$ , $^{**}p\lt 0.05$ , $^{*}p\lt 0.1$ .

4.2.2 Predictive criteria

This section makes use of a statistical criterion to investigate the usefulness of disaggregate data in understanding the effect of uncertainty at the US state and national level. While a well-specified disaggregated model will generally outperform an aggregate model, if the disaggregate model is misspecified, this may not hold. For instance, a disaggregate model may be misspecified if macroeconomic influences are incorrectly omitted or if measurement errors found in the disaggregate model cancel out in the aggregate. The inclusion of the global variables in the GVAR model means that the first will unlikely to be a problem; however, the second might be potentially relevant due to the sample size of the Google data. The prediction criteria test proposed in PPK assesses the ability of a disaggregate model in predicting an aggregate series of interest, relative to the ability of an aggregate model, under the null that the disaggregate model is true.

In this context, assume that each state, $i,$ is modeled according to the VARX* model specified earlier and that the aggregate model is assumed to be estimated of the following vector form:

(4) \begin{equation} y_{t}=c_{t}+\mathbf{a}y_{t-1}+\mathbf{b}y_{t-2}+\mathbf{e}_{t}. \end{equation}

where $y_{t}=\left (US_{t},UR_{t}\right )$ , $US_{t}=\sum _{i=1}^{s}w_{i}us_{i,t}$ and $UR_{t}=\sum _{i=1}^{s}w_{i}ur_{i,t}$ .Footnote 18

In PPK, the following statistics are used to rank the disaggregate model and the aggregate model:

(5) \begin{equation} s_{a}^{2}=\frac{\mathbf{e_{t}}^{\prime }\mathbf{e_{t}}}{T-\kappa _{a}}, \end{equation}
(6) \begin{equation} s_{d}^{2}=\sum _{i,j=1}^{N}\frac{\sum \limits _{t=1}^{n}(w_{i}u_{it})^{\prime }w_{j}u_{jt}}{T-\kappa _{i}-\kappa _{j}+tr(A_{i}A_{j})} \end{equation}

where $T$ is the number of observations, $\kappa _{a}$ is the number of estimated parameters in the aggregate model, $\kappa _{i}$ is the number of unrestricted parameters in each disaggregate model, and $A_{i}=X_{i}(X_{i}^{\prime }X_{i})^{-1}X_{i}^{\prime }$ , and $X_{i}$ is the matrix which consists of the explanatory variables in the $i$ -th equation. These statistics have the property that on average $s_{a}^{2}\gt s_{d}^{2}$ if the disaggregate model is true. Lee and Shields (Reference Lee and Shields1998) transform $s_{a}^{2}$ and $s_{d}^{2}$ to statistics that are comparable to $R^{2}$ measures:

(7) \begin{equation} r_{a}^{2} =1-\frac{s_{a}^{\text{2}}}{\sum \limits _{t=1}^{T}\left [ y_{t}-\overline{y_{t}}\right ] ^{2}/\left [ T-\kappa _{a}\right ]},\text{ and} \end{equation}
(8) \begin{equation} r_{d}^{2} =1-\frac{s_{d}^{\text{2}}}{\sum \limits _{t=1}^{T}\left [ y_{t}-\overline{y_{t}}\right ] ^{2}/\left [ T-\kappa _{a}\right ]} \end{equation}

where $\overline{y_{t}}$ represents the mean of the aggregate uncertainty and unemployment series, and $r_{a}$ and $r_{d}$ denote the transformed prediction criteria for the aggregate and disaggregate model, respectively. In this case, on average, $r_{a}^{2}$ will be smaller than $r_{d}^{2}$ if the disaggregate model is true. Asymptotically, if the disaggregate model is true, the criterion discussed above will rank the models correctly, on average, but this may not hold in a finite sample. To assess this, following GLP, a simulation experiment can be carried out by simulating the distribution of the test statistic, $D_{ad}=r_{d}^{2}-r_{a}^{2},$ defining the difference between the choice criteria. Accordingly, if the disaggregate model is correctly specified, $D_{ad}\gt 0.$ However, although this will hold asymptotically, this statistic may be smaller than 0 in any particular sample simply because of sample variation.Footnote 19 Given this, GLP suggest calculating a value $d_{ad}^{\ast }(\alpha )$ obtained from the distribution of $D_{ad}$ such that the probability of selecting the disaggregate model when it is true is $(1-\alpha )$ . We do so by first simulating the data 5000 times, assuming that the structure of the disaggregate model is the true data-generating process, and sampling with replacement. At each run, the test statistic is recalculated to obtain the distribution for $D_{ad}$ , and the value of $d_{ad}^{\ast }(\alpha )$ is determined from the left tail of this distribution.

We find significant statistical evidence that the disaggregate model outperforms the aggregate model in terms of its ability to predict aggregate uncertainty and aggregate unemployment as shown in Figure 3. Figure 3 reports the predictive difference between the aggregate model and the disaggregate model in predicting uncertainty (top panel) and unemployment (middle panel)—that is $D_{ad}=r_{d}^{2}-r_{a}^{2}$ along $d_{ad}^{\ast }(\alpha )$ from the simulated distribution ( $\alpha =0.05$ ). The figure clearly shows that the disaggregate model displays a higher ability to predict uncertainty and unemployment compared to the aggregate model, as seen by positive $D_{ad}$ values (in red). Further, once random variation is taken into account, there is still significant evidence to support the use of the disaggregate model, as illustrated by the fact the test statistics for predicting uncertainty and unemployment are both larger and on the right of the left tails of the distribution, $d_{ad}^{\ast }(\alpha )$ .

Figure 3. Prediction criteria. Notes: This figure plots the observed $D_{ad}$ , which is the difference in the prediction criteria test statistic (red line) and $d^*_{ad}(\alpha )$ , which is the left tail of the simulated distribution of the prediction criteria test statistic (dotted blue line) and assesses the ability of the disaggregate model versus the aggregate model in predicting aggregate uncertainty and aggregate unemployment, respectively. The figure also plots the observed $D_{dpard}$ , which is the difference in the prediction criteria test statistic (red line) and $d^*_{dpard}(\alpha )$ , which is the left tail of the simulated distribution of the prediction criteria test statistic (dotted blue line) and assesses the ability of the disaggregate model versus the partial disaggregate model without state-level uncertainty in predicting unemployment.

In the second exercise, we specifically investigate the value-added of our state-level measures of uncertainty in the disaggregate model, which again tests for the importance of the explanatory power of state-level measures of uncertainty above and beyond that of the common component. The previous exercise showed that a disaggregate model with state-level uncertainty measures and the state-level unemployment outperforms the aggregate model in terms of predicting aggregate variables. We further investigate whether the same disaggregate model outperforms a partial disaggregate model, which does not feature state-level measures of uncertainty, in terms of predicting the aggregate unemployment variable, under the null that the full disaggregate model is true. We find significant statistical evidence that the full disaggregate model outperforms the partial disaggregate model as shown in the bottom panel of Figure 3. This is reflected in the figure by a positive $D_{dpard}$ value (in red). Further, once random variation is taken into account, there is still significant evidence to support the use of the disaggregate model, as illustrated by the fact the test statistics for predicting unemployment are both larger and on the right of the left tail of the distribution, $d_{dpard}^{\ast }(\alpha )$ .

4.2.3 Forecast performance

Table 4 presents the out-of-sample forecast performance in terms of both point forecasts, as measured by the Root Mean Squared Errors (RMSEs) and density forecasts, as measured by the Average Log Scores (ALSs) of various models in predicting aggregate unemployment at the 1-month, 3-month, 6-month, and 1-year forecast horizons in purely statistical terms. We perform the out-of-sample evaluation using a rolling window estimation scheme over two sample horizons. In the first exercise, we use half the sample period (from 2006M01 to 2012M01) as the initial sample size and forecast using a rolling window until 2015M02 (which represents 3/4 of the total sample size). In the second, observations up to 2015M02 are used as the initial period to form out-of-sample forecasts for the remaining sample. The GVAR model in equation (3) is used as the benchmark to illustrate the usefulness of our disaggregate framework as well as of our state-level GTU measures. A value less than 1 represents a superior forecasting performance. The table reports the improvement or deterioration in forecast performance of the GVAR model relative to other forecasting models, namely (i) disaggregate model of state-level unemployment using only unemployment variables (DISU); (ii) a partially disaggregated model using state-level measures of unemployment alongside the aggregate GTU measure of uncertainty (GTU); (iii)–(vi) as the model in (ii) but respectively using the EPU [Baker et al. (Reference Baker, Bloom and Davis2016)], the VIX, a measure of macroeconomic uncertainty (JLN) [Jurado et al. (Reference Jurado, Ludvigson and Ng2015a)] and a measure of financial uncertainty (LMN) [Ludvigson et al. (Reference Ludvigson, Ma and Ng2020)], in place of the GTU as the aggregate measures of uncertainty. The statistical significance of the improvement is tested using the Giacomini and White (Reference Giacomini and White2006) test of equal forecast performance.

Table 4. Evaluation of out-of-sample point and density forecasts

Notes: The upper (lower) panel reports the out-of-sample RMSE (Average Log Scores—ALS) ratio of the GVAR model relative to the RMSE (ALS) of other models. A ratio $\lt$ 1 indicates that the GVAR model outperforms other models. A " $^*$ " denotes that the RMSE (ALS) ratio for the GVAR model statistically outperforms the other models at the 10% level of significance through applying the Giacomini and White (Reference Giacomini and White2006) test of equal forecast performance. We perform the out-of-sample evaluation using a rolling window estimation scheme. $T$ is the total sample size and is out of 1 (100%) and $t0$ is the training sample size.

The top half of Table 4 presents the forecasting performance using the RMSE criterion and shows that there is not much evidence from the point forecasts. The GVAR outperforms the diasaggrate model using unemployment only (DISU) and the partially disaggregated models in the case of the measure of macroeconomic uncertainty (JLN). Only in the latter case, however, the performance is statistically significant. The bottom half of the table presents the forecasting results using the density-based ALS. The results show that the extra complexity of GVAR stemming from our state-level uncertainty measures has an important impact on forecast performance. The GVAR benchmark outperforms in five of the six models, and the forecast performance is statistically significant. There is therefore strong evidence to support the usefulness of the disaggregate model in a broad sense and, in particular, the usefulness of our measures of state-level uncertainty over and beyond the information provided by other uncertainty measures that are only available at the aggregate level.

4.3 Dynamic Impulse Response Analysis

The identification of exogenous variations of the uncertainty shock is achieved via the widely adopted time-ordering assumption. A recent paper by Carriero et al. (Reference Carriero, Clark and Marcellino2018a) shows that macroeconomic uncertainty can be considered as exogenous when assessing its effects on the US economy. Nonetheless, our general conclusions are robust to this time-ordering assumption (see Section 8 of the Appendix for further details). In addition, it is noticed that the construction of our uncertainty index includes terms such as "unemployment benefit" or "unemployment extension" which may raise endogeneity concerns. We find that it is not the case since the average correlation between the original uncertainty and the index without these unemployment-related keywords gives the value close to 0.99. In addition, following Garín et al. (Reference Garín, Lester and Sims2019), we also find that the GTU index is uncorrelated with other shocks such as total factor productivity, oil price, fiscal, or monetary policy shocks. The ordering implies that uncertainty does not respond to the unemployment shock in the impact period while allowing unemployment to respond to the uncertainty shock (while still allowing uncertainty shocks between states to be correlated). This also assigns the maximum possible effect to the uncertainty shocks and provides an upper bound on the measure of the effect of uncertainty.

Consider the GVAR(2) model in equation (3), the moving average representation is given by:

(9) \begin{equation} x_{t}=\epsilon _{t}+A_{1}\epsilon _{t-1}+A_{2}\epsilon _{t-2}+\ldots \end{equation}

and $A_{s}$ can be defined recursively as:

(10) \begin{equation} A_{s}=F_{1}A_{s-1}+F_{2}A_{s-2},\ \ s=1,2,\ldots \end{equation}

with $A_{0}$ $=I$ , $A_{s}=0$ for $s\lt 0$ .

The time-ordering assumption of the shocks allows us to separate the effects of the uncertainty shocks, denoted as $\delta _{t}=(\epsilon _{1t},\epsilon _{3t},\ldots,\epsilon _{101t})$ , from the total shocks to the GVAR by regressing $\epsilon _{t}$ on $\delta _{t}$ and writing $\epsilon _{t}=\bar{D}\delta _{t}+\tilde{\epsilon _{t}}$ . In this case, equation (9) can be rewritten in terms of "orthogonal" uncertainty shocks and other unemployment-related shocks:

(11) \begin{equation} x_{t}=\left [ \bar{D}\delta _{t}+\tilde{\epsilon _{t}}\right ] +A_{1}[\bar{D}\delta _{t-1}+\tilde{\epsilon }_{t-1}]+A_{2}[\bar{D}\delta _{t-2}+\tilde{\epsilon }_{t-2}]+\ldots \end{equation}

The impulse response function for the GVAR model can then be written as:

(12) \begin{equation} \text{IRF}(x_{t};\;u_{it},h)=\frac{e_{i}^{\prime }A{_{h}}\bar{D}\Sigma _{\delta }\bar{D}^{\prime }e_{j}}{\sqrt{e_{j}^{\prime }\Sigma _{u}e_{j}}},h=0,1,2,\ldots ;\; i,j=1,2,\ldots,2N \end{equation}

where $\Sigma _{\delta }$ denotes the variance–covariance matrix of the uncertainty shocks, $\delta _{t},$ $e_{i}$ , and $e_{j}$ are $2N\times 1$ selection vectors with unity in their $i$ -th $,$ $j$ -th elements, respectively, and zeros elsewhere, and $h$ is the horizon of the impulse. For an aggregate shock, $e_{i}$ is a vector of aggregate weights in the elements of $j=2,4,6,\ldots,2N,$ in the case of a national unemployment shock for instance, where the weights sum to 1 and where population weights are chosen to be consistent with the construction of the starred variables in the GVAR model. Given the identification assumption, the effect of a one-standard-deviation population-weighted aggregate uncertainty shock on the (weighted aggregate) unemployment variable in the GVAR model can be seen in Figure 4. For illustrative purposes, this figure also reports the traditional orthogonalized impulse response function for the bivariate VAR aggregate model showing the impact of an orthogonal uncertainty shock (defined through a Cholesky decomposition) on the unemployment variable.

Figure 4. Aggregate uncertainty shocks on aggregate unemployment. Notes: This figure compares the IRFs of a one-standard-deviation aggregate uncertainty shock in the GVAR model to the VAR model. The GVAR IRFs are the weighted response of each state unemployment to an aggregate uncertainty shock in the GVAR model, where the aggregate shock is defined in equation (12) through using population weights. The VAR IRFs are constructed via the Cholesky decomposition where uncertainty is placed first. Unemployment is defined as the quarterly change in unemployment rate. The confidence interval is the bootstrapped IRFs at $\pm 1$ s.d.

Although the effects of the respective uncertainty shocks on unemployment in both the aggregate model and the disaggregate model are similar, we find that the impact of an aggregate uncertainty shock in the disaggregate model is significantly smaller than in the aggregate model when we look at the peak response of unemployment. We find that the quarterly change in unemployment rate in the disaggregate model goes up by 0.015% point at peak, compared to 0.045% point in the aggregate model. Since unemployment is modeled as the quarterly change in the unemployment rate, we could recover the response of the actual unemployment rate to provide intuitive interpretations on the effect of uncertainty shocks. We find that the peak effect of uncertainty shock in the disaggregate GVAR model causes the unemployment rate to go up by 0.1% points. On the other hand, the unemployment rate goes up by 0.28% points in the aggregate model at peak. These findings are within the bounds of the measures documented in the literature.Footnote 20

On the whole, even after assigning uncertainty to have maximum effects due to the time-ordering assumption, our results are shown to be at the more conservative end of the impact of uncertainty on economic activity. In terms of the dynamics, both impulse responses tend to start dying away after 2 years, although, the GVAR model, despite providing a smaller peak response effect, shows a far more prolonged process of dissemination of the initial shock taking approximately double the time of the impulse response from the VAR model which rapidly disseminates after approximately 2 years.

In sum, both modeling frameworks point to the significant effect of uncertainty on unemployment. The use of an aggregate model, however, shown to be misspecified in the previous section, accordingly averages over relevant feedbacks and interactions through the process of aggregation in the analysis of the impact of uncertainty on the economy and therefore overestimates the effects of uncertainty shocks relative to the disaggregate model. The aggregate model also underestimates the time it takes for the uncertainty shock to work its way through the system. As a result, the disaggregate model shows the effect of an uncertainty shock on unemployment to be statistically and significantly smaller than that according to the aggregate model and with a relatively far more prolonged dynamic response.

We close this section by observing whether there are any spatial patterns apparent in the heterogeneous responses of state-level unemployment to an aggregate uncertainty shock. In a heatmap of the USA, Figure 5 presents the median estimate of the peak response of state-level unemployment to a one-standard-deviation aggregate uncertainty shock. We find that unemployment increases in all states in response to an increase in US-wide uncertainty. The findings are also consistent to those documented in Mumtaz et al. (Reference Mumtaz, Sunder-Plassmann and Theophilopoulou2018) who find that real income declines in all states in response to an increase in US-wide uncertainty (even without accommodating for state-level uncertainty). The figure also shows that the magnitude of the increase in unemployment is largest in the coastal states. On the other hand, unemployment in more central states in the USA seems to be less affected. These heterogeneous responses in the response of unemployment to uncertainty shocks could potentially be driven by cross-state variations in financial and fiscal conditions, the industry mix, and the labor market. We investigate this in more detail in Section 5.

Figure 5. US heatmap—peak response of state-level unemployment to an aggregate uncertainty shock. Notes: This figure presents the median estimate of the peak response of state-level unemployment to a one-standard-deviation aggregate uncertainty shock.

4.4 Decomposition Analysis: State versus National Influences

In this section, we explore, for each state, the relative importance of national influences relative to state-specific influences of a national uncertainty shock on state-level economic activity. This section follows Garratt et al. (Reference Garratt, Lee and Shields2018) and characterizes the dynamic effects of specified shocks by using the variance-based persistence profile (PP) measure proposed by Lee and Pesaran (Reference Lee and Pesaran1993). The PP is used to measure the long-run response of the level series to shocks and trace out the accumulated response over time to characterize the system dynamics.

At time horizon $h$ , the PPs are defined by the $2N\times 2N$ matrix $P(h)$ and as $h\rightarrow \infty$ , converges to the following persistence matrix, in which the $(i,j)$ -th element is given by:

(13) \begin{equation} p_{ij}=\frac{e_{i}^{\prime }A(1)\Sigma _{\epsilon }A(1)^{\prime }e_{j}}{\sqrt{(e_{i}^{\prime }A(0)\Sigma _{\epsilon }A(0)^{\prime }e_{i})(e_{j}^{\prime }A(0)\Sigma _{\epsilon }A(0)^{\prime }e_{j}})}, \qquad \qquad i,j=1,\ldots,2N, \end{equation}

where $p_{ij}$ measures the infinite horizon effect of system-wide shocks to variables in the system. For instance, the permanent impact on unemployment in each state of a system-wide shock which causes the unemployment variable in each state to rise by 1 standard error on impact can be captured by considering the measures $p_{ii},$ where $i=2,4,6,\ldots 2N$ and where $i=j$ .

For the sake of brevity, the full technical details of the decomposition can be found in Section 11 of the Appendix. In this analysis, two decompositions of the persistence measure $p_{ii}$ are of interest. The first concerns the part due to orthogonalized uncertainty shocks on state unemployment dynamics relative to other unidentified unemployment-related shocks ( $p^U_{ii}$ ), and this decomposition makes use of the orthogonalization of uncertainty shocks as described in the previous section. The second concerns the decomposition of the dynamic propagation of these uncertainty shocks ( $p^U_{ii}$ ) into the components due to national dynamics ( $p^{NU}_{ii}$ ) relative to state-specific dynamics ( $p^{SU}_{ii}$ ), focusing on the infinite horizon effect on state-specific unemployment.

Figure 6 reports the ratio: $\frac{p_{ii}^{NU}}{p_{ii}^{U}}$ in a heatmap of the USA, which gives the relative importance of national dynamics versus both state and national dynamics, as modeled in equation (3), in terms of respective measures of the persistent effect of the above-defined uncertainty shocks on state-specific unemployment. The persistence measures are scaled by a standard error state-specific unemployment shock on impact. A simple correlation between the statistics for each state represented in Figure 5 and those in Figure 6 gives a value of 0.4 showing that national influences play a clear role in propagating the effects of uncertainty. On average, the uncertainty shocks transmitted through the channels associated with national elements account for 37% of the total variation in state-specific unemployment and the remaining 63% is attributed to the purely state-specific channel abstracting entirely from national dynamics. However, the figure also shows that there is a significant degree of heterogeneity across the US states. The figure also shows that the more central states in the USA seem to be less affected by national dynamics in the influence of uncertainty on economic activity—such as in the states of Texas, New Mexico, or Colorado, for instance. On the other hand, unemployment in the eastern states tend to be far more influenced by national elements in the propagation of uncertainty shocks. Factors that might explain such heterogeneity could include state-specific characteristics such as the state-level industry composition, fiscal constraints, labor market constraints, and financial frictions. We explore these patterns in terms of potential pointers toward an economic narrative in more detail in the next section.

Figure 6. US heatmap—relative importance of national uncertainty. Notes: This figure plots $\frac{p^{NU}_{ii}}{p^U_{ii}}$ , which measures the relative importance of national influences in propagating uncertainty shocks on state $i$ ’s unemployment.

5. An exploration into the heterogeneity of state-level responses and national influences

This section uses state-specific characteristics for an investigation into factors potentially important when considering (i) the heterogeneous responses of state-level unemployment to a US-wide uncertainty shock as detailed in Section 4.3, and (ii) the heterogeneous importance of national influences in the role of the propagation of uncertainty shocks on state-level unemployment as described in Section 4.4. The analysis follows the regression specifications employed in Mumtaz et al. (Reference Mumtaz, Sunder-Plassmann and Theophilopoulou2018):

(14) \begin{equation} \rho _{i}=c+\beta X_{i}+R_{i}+\eta _{i},\qquad \qquad i=1,\ldots,N \end{equation}

where the dependent variable is given, respectively, by (i) $\rho _{i}=\text{response}_{i}$ reflecting the peak response of state $i$ ’s unemployment to a US-wide uncertainty shock when considering the heterogeneous responses of unemployment as plotted in Figure 5, and (ii) $\rho _{i}=\frac{p_{ii}^{NU}}{p_{ii}^{U}}$ when considering the relative importance of national influences in propagating uncertainty shocks on state $i$ ’s unemployment, $c$ denotes the intercept, $X_{i}$ include the explanatory variables depicting state-specific characteristics, and $R_{i}$ denote regional dummies according to the US Bureau of Economic Analysis. Following Lewis and Linzer (Reference Lewis and Linzer2005), the standard errors are White-corrected standard errors to account for the fact that the dependent variables are generated.

The testing strategy follows that employed in Mumtaz et al. (Reference Mumtaz, Sunder-Plassmann and Theophilopoulou2018) and involves specifying explanatory variables capturing various sets of influences and investigating their respective explanatory power through sequential regressions. The regression specifications and testing strategy are described below. In terms of the explanatory variables, we specify five sets of regressors. The first set represents the industry structure for each state and contain information on the state-level GDP share of the Agriculture, Construction, Finance, Government, Manufacturing, Mining, and Real Estate. The second set accounts for the degree of financial frictions. Following Carlino and DeFina (Reference Carlino and DeFina1998), financial frictions are defined as the percentage of each state’s loans made by small banks.Footnote 21 In addition to small banks’ loans, the home ownership rate is also included to account for cross-state differences in the housing market. The third set measures the labor market frictions by using data on the percentage of workers represented by unions for each state and the right-to-work (RTW), which is a dummy variable for whether a state has "right-to-work" legislation as of 2016. The fourth set captures the level of the fiscal condition by using data on the state-level debt–GDP ratio, intergovernmental transfers, and the state-level spending–GDP ratio. Finally, the fifth set considers the share of internet users across different US states and serves as a robustness check given our internet-data-based measure of uncertainty.

5.1 Heterogeneity of State-Level Responses of Unemployment

The regression strategy involves starting with an initial regression of $\rho _{i}=\text{response}_{i}$ and solely considering the first set of explanatory variables which includes variables representing state industry structures and relevant variables. Starting with just one industry variable, and retaining only if statistically significant (at the 10% level of significance), other industry variables are introduced sequentially in subsequent regressions, once again retaining significant variables in the regression. In the following regressions, additional control variables from the other sets of regressors are introduced one by one in sequential regressions and only retained if statistically significant. Table 5 reports the coefficients from these sequential regressions.

Table 5. Heterogeneity analysis on the response of state-level unemployment to an aggregate uncertainty shock

Notes: $\text{response}_i$ is defined in Section 4.3 and represents the peak state-level response of unemployment to an aggregate uncertainty shock. White-corrected standard errors are in parentheses $^{***}p\lt 0.01, ^{**}p\lt 0.05, ^{*}p\lt 0.1$ .

Table 6. Heterogeneity analysis on the importance of national influences in propagating uncertainty shocks

Notes: $\frac{p^{NU}_{ii}}{p^U_{ii}}$ is defined in Section 4.4 and represents the relative importance of national uncertainty shocks in propagating uncertainty shocks. White-corrected standard errors are in parentheses $^{***}p\lt 0.01$ , $^{**}p\lt 0.05$ , $^{*}p\lt 0.1$ .

Table 5 Column 1 presents our benchmark regression result from the first sequence of regressions relating the estimated responses $\rho _{i}$ to variables accounting for the structure of industry in each state where only the remaining significant industry variables are reported.Footnote 22 The column shows that only the share of the manufacturing and the mining industry have a robust and significant relationship with the responses of unemployment rate to an increase in US-wide uncertainty. These findings on the industry mix are completely consistent with those reported in Mumtaz et al. (Reference Mumtaz, Sunder-Plassmann and Theophilopoulou2018). We find that states with a higher concentration of the manufacturing industry experience a larger increase in unemployment after an increase in US-wide uncertainty. While speculative, this is consistent with the precautionary saving channel of uncertainty shocks causing a reduction in demand for manufacturing goods. On the other hand, we find that states with a larger mining industry experience a relatively smaller increase in unemployment. As documented in many studies such as Jo (Reference Jo2014), Mumtaz et al. (Reference Mumtaz, Sunder-Plassmann and Theophilopoulou2018) or Tran (Reference Tran2021), for instance, there is evidence that an uncertainty shock results in an increase in the price of some commodities. If this is the case, then the increase in commodity prices could be a contributing factor in negating the negative effects of uncertainty in states with a higher mining share of industry.

Column 2 and Column 3 of Table 5 show that the variables reflecting the housing market (Home Vacancy or Home Ownership) are not significant and are thus excluded from the subsequent regression specifications. Columns 4–10 present the results of sequentially including variables reflecting: labor market conditions (i.e. Right to Work or Union Membership); financial conditions; and the fiscal condition (state-level debt, state-level spending, and intergovernmental transfers). We find that none of these variables exhibit a statistically significant relationship with the responses of unemployment to state-level uncertainty—with Manufacturing and Mining still remaining significant in most of these regressions. There is good evidence, therefore, to support the results reported in Column 1. Findings from these subsequent regressions (Column 2 onward), however, are in contrast to the results in Mumtaz et al. (Reference Mumtaz, Sunder-Plassmann and Theophilopoulou2018) who report a significant association between the effect of uncertainty and the state-level housing market, the fiscal condition, and the financial constraint. The difference in findings could be due to differences in the sample period (Mumtaz et al. (Reference Mumtaz, Sunder-Plassmann and Theophilopoulou2018) cover the period 1960Q1–2014Q1) and also the fact that the authors study the response of quarterly real income growth to an uncertainty shock. When we use unemployment as a measure of real economic activity and in a framework accommodating state interactions and feedbacks, the relationship between these variables and uncertainty shocks is weaker.

In summary, the benchmark estimates and the detailed robustness checks suggest the following results. First, states with a higher concentration of the manufacturing industry experience a larger increase in unemployment when impacted by an uncertainty shock. Second, states with a higher concentration of the mining industry appear to be affected less by this shock.

5.2 Heterogeneity of National Influences in the Propagation of Uncertainty Shocks

In this section, we employ the same regression and testing strategy as described in the previous section, with the dependent variable now $\rho _{i}=\frac{p_{ii}^{NU}}{p_{ii}^{U}}.$ Again, starting with a set of sequential regressions involving the first set of variables reflecting the industry structure (and as detailed in the Appendix), we end up with an industry mix involving Government and Real Estate remaining as the significant variables as the initial baseline regression and as reported in Column 1 of Table 6. To this baseline regression, we add Home Vacancy in Column 2 and Home Ownership in Column 3. Given the statistical significance of Home Vacancy, we keep it in the regression specification and add in sequentially Right to Work in Column 4, Union membership in Column 5, and the degree of financial frictions in Column 6. None of these latter three variables prove to be statistically significant. Home Vacancy also drops out with the inclusion of the measure of state-level debt.Footnote 23 We subsequently add in a measure of intergovernmental transfers as reported in Column 9. Although we find that the measure of intergovernmental transfers is statistically significant, we exclude this variable from the regression on the grounds that it takes on a value of almost 0, reduces the overall goodness-of-fit of the model as seen by the adjusted $R^{2}$ measure in Columns 8–10, and its inclusion takes away from the significance of the share of the government sector which has been a robust explanatory variable in all the other regressions.

Our preferred specification is as in Column 8. The results in this column shows that only the government sector, the real estate industry, and the state-level of fiscal conditions are robust in terms of statistical significance in terms of the association the relative importance of the national influences in propagating uncertainty shocks. We find that states with a higher concentration of the real estate industry reflect a tendency for a state to experience a larger impact through national influences in propagating uncertainty shocks. The finding of the relatively greater importance of the national factors is consistent an increased degree of contagion between the financial market and the real estate market during the GFC, reflecting the housing bubble and the subprime mortgage lending crisis [Caporin et al. (Reference Caporin, Gupta and Ravazzolo2021)].

On the other hand, states with a more active fiscal policy experience less of an influence from the national factors in the propagation of uncertainty shocks. We find a negative and statistically significant relationship between the importance of national influences in propagating uncertainty shocks and the share of the government sector and the size of the state-level debt. Our conjecture on the negative association between an active fiscal policy and the importance of national influences in propagating uncertainty shocks is further solidified when we replace state-level debt by state-level spending in Table 6 Column 11. We find that there is a significant association between state-level spending and the importance of national factors in the propagation of uncertainty shocks. Finally, the inclusion of the share of internet users in Column 12 does not affect the results of our preferred specification.

In summary, the results from our preferred regression specification and detailed robustness checks suggest the following: the relative importance of national factors in the propagation of uncertainty shocks tends to be (i) smaller in states with a more active fiscal policy and (ii) greater in states with a larger concentration of the real estate industry.

6. Conclusion

Economic uncertainty is a salient and increasingly complex feature of the global economy. Therefore, it is important to understand how it can be better incorporated into macroeconomic models. One key and underexplored aspect is the role of spatial disaggregation, since local areas can differ greatly in their economic composition and therefore in their transmission mechanisms. This paper estimates the impact of uncertainty shocks in a disaggregate model featuring US state-level economic activity and uncertainty proxies, where internet search data is used as proxies for uncertainty. The disaggregate framework of analysis is in the context of the GVAR model which is able to characterize the evolution of state-specific variables while incorporating interactions and spillover effects across states.

We find there is strong evidence to support the usefulness of disaggregated data in models of uncertainty and economic activity for the USA, based on the ability of the disaggregate model to predict aggregate uncertainty and unemployment. The use of a disaggregate model accommodates and captures relevant feedbacks and interactions in the analysis on the impact of uncertainty on the economy—which the misspecified aggregate model omits. As a result, the disaggregate model exhibits significantly smaller effects of uncertainty shocks on the economy with a far more prolonged dissemination of these shocks compared to the aggregate model.

There is a large degree of heterogeneity across states in the respective responses of unemployment to a national uncertainty shock and also in the respective importance of national influences in propagating uncertainty shocks. Cross-sectional regression results suggest that the responses of unemployment are positively associated with the share of the manufacturing industry and negatively associated with the concentration of the mining industry. We also find that national influences are relatively less important than the state-specific influences in propagating the effect of uncertainty shocks and found to be positively associated with the size of the real estate industry and negatively associated with states exhibiting a more active fiscal policy, a greater share of the government sector, and higher levels of debt and spending. Further analysis on providing an economic commentary on the mechanisms underlying these results is certainly warranted and could provide important insights in informing state and national policies to mitigate the negative effects of uncertainty on the economy.

Footnotes

This paper was previously circulated under the title “Uncertainty in a Disaggregate Model: a Data Rich Approach using Google Search Queries.” The authors would like to thank Giovanni Caggiano, Efrem Castelnuovo, Andrea Carriero, Punnoose Jacob, Mariano Kulish, James Morley, Anella Munro, Viet H. Nguyen, Kian Ong, Giovanni Pellegrino, Guido Turnip, Tugrul Vehbi, Benjamin Wong, and participants at the University of Melbourne Brown Bag Seminar, the 2017 International Association of Applied Econometrics (IAAE) Conference, the 2017 Australian Conference of Economists, the 2017 Workshop of the Australasian Macroeconomics Society, the Reserve Bank of New Zealand Round Table and the 2019 Sydney Macroeconomic Workshop for helpful feedback that has greatly improved this manuscript. The authors also gratefully acknowledge financial support by the Australian Research Council via the Discovery Grant DP160102281, the University of Melbourne Faculty Grant & Research Scholarship and the IAAE Travel grant. The usual disclaimers apply. The views expressed in this paper are those of the authors and should not be attributed to the Reserve Bank of Australia.

1 Bontempi et al. (Reference Bontempi, Golinelli and Squadrani2019) use Google search data to measure aggregate uncertainty in the USA and Italy, while Castelnuovo and Tran (Reference Castelnuovo and Tran2017) measure uncertainty in the USA and Australia.

2 For instance, Castelnuovo and Tran (Reference Castelnuovo and Tran2017) consider the VXO used in Bloom (Reference Bloom2009), the EPU index constructed by Baker et al. (Reference Baker, Bloom and Davis2016), the macroeconomic uncertainty index proposed by Jurado et al. (Reference Jurado, Ludvigson and Ng2015a), the financial uncertainty index constructed by Ludvigson et al. (Reference Ludvigson, Ma and Ng2020), the subjective interest rate uncertainty proposed by Istrefi and Mouabbi (Reference Istrefi and Mouabbi2017), the categorical measure of monetary policy-related uncertainty produced by Baker et al. (Reference Baker, Bloom and Davis2016), the real-time, real activity-related uncertainty index constructed by Scotti (Reference Scotti2016), and the real-time measure of uncertainty based on the distribution of the forecast errors of real GDP constructed by Rossi and Sekhposyan (Reference Rossi and Sekhposyan2015).

3 Shoag and Veuger (Reference Shoag and Veuger2016) work within a cross-sectional regression framework, find a causal role for uncertainty in increasing unemployment at the state level over the 2007–2009 recession period; Mumtaz et al. (Reference Mumtaz, Sunder-Plassmann and Theophilopoulou2018) and Mumtaz (Reference Mumtaz2018), respectively, use national- and state-level model-based measures of uncertainty and associate state-level structural factors with findings of heterogeneity in the impact of uncertainty on measures of real economic activity.

4 Several studies such as Jurado et al. (Reference Jurado, Ludvigson and Ng2015b) and Mumtaz et al. (Reference Mumtaz, Sunder-Plassmann and Theophilopoulou2018) find that oil prices tend to increase in response to higher uncertainty. It is therefore possible that higher oil prices help to ameliorate the negative effects of uncertainty in states where a larger share of GDP is accounted for the mining industry.

5 See Caporin et al. (Reference Caporin, Gupta and Ravazzolo2021) for example.

6 Depending on specific search term, the frequency could either be daily, weekly, or monthly. This paper deals with the monthly search frequency.

7 Subsequently, for state-level uncertainty, i will denote the name of the respective state.

8 Bontempi et al. (Reference Bontempi, Golinelli and Squadrani2019) use both Bayesian aggregation and the common-term aggregation approach and find substantial correlations between the two approaches when constructing a Google uncertainty index for the USA and Italy.

9 These categories are more or less similar to Baker et al. (Reference Baker, Bloom and Davis2016) who have the following policy categories: Fiscal policy, monetary policy, health care, national security and war, regulation, foreign sovereign debt and currency crisis, entitlement programs, and trade policy.

10 Through using a principal component analysis, the common uncertainty factor only explains approximately 65% of the variation. The importance of the idiosyncratic uncertainty components is illustrated in Section 4.2 of the paper.

11 The results are robust to when we use GDP weights, equal weights, or distance weights. See Section 9 of the Appendix for further details.

12 Appendix 1 provides a description of the data sources.

13 As a robustness check, a test for the joint significance of inflation and the effective cash rate for the USA in the GVAR shows that there is strong evidence that these additional variables provide no additional information content above and beyond the existing GVAR in unemployment and uncertainty. Furthermore, we check whether additional control variables can help purge all endogenous variations from the uncertainty variables by regressing a constant, inflation, and interest rate (and its lags) on the GVAR residuals. We have found that the additional control variables do not provide any additional explanatory power. It is likely then that the addition of these variables will not change the quantitative findings presented in the paper.

14 It is computationally challenging to include more lags in the GVAR and our choice of lag followed the pioneering study of Dees et al. (Reference Dees, Mauro, Pesaran and Smith2007). In testing for the null of no residual serial correlation, we find that in 90% of the individual equations, there is no evidence of residual serial correlation at the 5% level of significance using a Lagrange multiplier test. This finding of statistical insignificance at the 5% level is supported for the system as a whole using a likelihood ratio test for the joint significance of lagged residuals.

15 The t-statistic threshold follows Clements and Hendry (Reference Clements and Hendry2005) who find that the inclusion of variables below the threshold damages the predictive ability of the AR model. The specification search with the threshold also ensures stability for dynamic analysis when working with a large system of variables.

16 For each bivariate system for each state, this involves for: (i) $\tau =1,$ the significance starred uncertainty on uncertainty; (i) $\tau =2,$ the significance of starred unemployment on uncertainty; (iii) for $\tau =3,$ the significance of starred uncertainty on unemployment; and (iv) $\tau =4,$ the significance of starred unemployment on unemployment.

17 For each bivariate system for each state, $\nu$ = 1 refers to the variables relating to state-level uncertainty in the uncertainty equation, while $\nu$ = 2 refers to the variables relating to state-level uncertainty in the unemployment equation.

18 The lag length of the aggregate model is chosen to match that of the disaggregate model. The result remains robust when the lag length for the aggregate model is selected using the AIC.

19 In this case, it would not be strictly valid to reject the disaggregate model simply because $D_{ad}\lt 0$ .

20 Caggiano et al. (Reference Caggiano, Castelnuovo and Groshenny2014) find that unemployment goes up at peak by 0.4% points (in bad times) or by 0.2% points (in normal times) after a one-standard-deviation uncertainty shock for the period 1962Q3 to 2012Q3. On the other hand, Leduc and Liu (Reference Leduc and Liu2016) find that the peak effect of a one-standard-deviation increase in uncertainty on the unemployment rate is equal to 0.15% points for the period 1978M01 to 2013M10. Similarly, Mumtaz (Reference Mumtaz2018) finds that the unemployment rate rises by 0.25% points after a 20% increase in uncertainty with the sample from 1976Q1 to 2015Q3.

21 Smalls banks are banks whose assets are less than the 90% of the national average.

22 Details of the regressions underlying this benchmark result are reported in Section 12 of the Appendix.

23 The increase in the goodness-of-fit of the model is also another reason for keeping state-level debt and removing the Home Vacancy variable. We can see that the adjusted $R^{2}$ measure increases when we replace Home Vacancy by state-level debt in Table 6 Column 3 and Column 8.

References

Angelini, G., Bacchiocchi, E., Caggiano, G. and Fanelli, L. (2018) Uncertainty across volatility regimes. Journal of Applied Econometrics 34(3), 437455.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bachmann, R., Elstner, S. and Sims, E. R. (2013) Uncertainty and economic activity: Evidence from business survey data. American Economic Journal: Macroeconomics 5(2), 217249.Google Scholar
Baker, S., Bloom, N. and Davis, S. J. (2016) Measuring economic policy uncertainty. Quarterly Journal of Economics 131(4), 15391636.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bar-Ilan, A. and Strange, W. C. (1996) Investment lags. The American Economic Review 86(3), 610622.Google Scholar
Bloom, N. (2009) The impact of uncertainty shocks. Econometrica 77(3), 623685.Google Scholar
Bloom, N. (2014) Fluctuations in uncertainty. Journal of Economic Perspectives 28(2), 153176.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bontempi, M. E., Golinelli, R. and Squadrani, M. (2019) Uncertainty, perception and the internet. Quaderni-Working Paper DSE.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Caggiano, G., Castelnuovo, E. and Groshenny, N. (2014) Uncertainty shocks and unemployment dynamics in US recessions. Journal of Monetary Economics 67(2), 7892.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Caporin, M., Gupta, R. and Ravazzolo, F. (2021) Contagion between real estate and financial markets: A bayesian quantile-on-quantile approach. The North American Journal of Economics and Finance 55(6), 101347.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Carlino, G. and DeFina, R. (1998) The differential regional effects of monetary policy. Review of Economics and Statistics 80(4), 572587.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Carriero, A., Clark, T. E. and Marcellino, M. (2018a) Endogenous uncertainty. Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland Working Paper No. 18-05.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Carriero, A., Clark, T. E. and Marcellino, M. (2018b) Measuring uncertainty and its impact on the economy. The Review of Economics and Statistics 100(5), 799815.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Castelnuovo, E. (2019). Domestic and Global Uncertainty: A Survey and Some New Results. Technical report.Google Scholar
Castelnuovo, E. and Tran, T. D. (2017) Google it up! a Google Trends-based uncertainty index for the United States and Australia. Economics Letters 161, 149153.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Choi, H. and Varian, H. (2009) Predicting Initial Claims for Unemployment Benefits. Google Inc, pp. 15.Google Scholar
Chudik, A. and Pesaran, M. H. (2016) Theory and practice of GVAR modelling. Journal of Economic Surveys 30(1), 165197.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Clements, M. P. and Hendry, D. F. (2005) Guest editors’ introduction: Information in economic forecasting. Oxford Bulletin of Economics and Statistics 67(s1), 713753.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Comscore (2016) Comscore Releases February 2016 U.S. Desktop Search Engine Rankings. Reston, VA: Comscore.Google Scholar
Dees, S., Mauro, F.d, Pesaran, M. H. and Smith, L. V. (2007) Exploring the international linkages of the euro area: A global VAR analysis. Journal of Applied Econometrics 22(1), 138.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Fernández-Villaverde, J., Guerrón-Quintana, P., Kuester, K. and Rubio-Ramírez, J. (2015) Fiscal volatility shocks and economic activity. American Economic Review 105(11), 33523384.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Garín, J., Lester, R. and Sims, E. (2019) Are supply shocks contractionary at the ZLB? Evidence from utilization-adjusted tfp data. Review of Economics and Statistics 101(1), 160175.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Garratt, A., Lee, K. and Shields, K. (2018) The role of uncertainty, sentiment and cross-country interactions in G7 output dynamics. Canadian Journal of Economics 51(2), 391418.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Garratt, A., Robertson, D. and Wright, S. (2006) Permanent vs transitory components and economic fundamentals. Journal of Applied Econometrics 21(4), 521542.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Giacomini, R. and White, H. (2006) Tests of conditional predictive ability. Econometrica 74(6), 15451578.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Istrefi, K. and Mouabbi, S. (2017) Subjective interest rate uncertainty and the macroeconomy: A cross-country analysis. Journal of International Money and Finance 88, 296313.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Jo, S. (2014) The effects of oil price uncertainty on global real economic activity. Journal of Money, Credit and Banking 46(6), 11131135.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Jurado, K., Ludvigson, S. C. and Ng, S. (2015a) Measuring uncertainty. American Economic Review 105(3), 11771216.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Jurado, K., Ludvigson, S. C. and Ng, S. (2015b) Measuring uncertainty. The American Economic Review 105(3), 11771216.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Leduc, S. and Liu, Z. (2016) Uncertainty shocks are aggregate demand shocks. Journal of Monetary Economics 82(Supplement C), 2035.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lee, K. and Shields, K. (1998) Modelling sectoral output growth in the EU economies. Report for the European Commission.Google Scholar
Lee, K. C. and Pesaran, M. H. (1993) Persistence profiles and business cycle fluctuations in a disaggregated model of uk output growth. Ricerche Economiche 47(3), 293322.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lewis, J. B. and Linzer, D. A. (2005) Estimating regression models in which the dependent variable is based on estimates. Political Analysis 13(4), 345364.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ludvigson, S. C., Ma, S. and Ng, S. (2020) Uncertainty and business cycles: Exogenous impulse or endogenous response? American Economic Journal: Macroeconomics 13, 369410Google Scholar
Mumtaz, H. (2018) Does uncertainty affect real activity? Evidence from state-level data. Economics Letters 167(3), 127130.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Mumtaz, H., Sunder-Plassmann, L. and Theophilopoulou, A. (2018) The state-level impact of uncertainty shocks. Journal of Money, Credit and Banking 50(8), 18791899.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Mumtaz, H. and Surico, P. (2018) Policy uncertainty and aggregate fluctuations. Journal of Applied Econometrics 33(3), 319331.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Pesaran, M. H., Pierse, R. G., Kumar, M. S. and et al. (1989) Econometric analysis of aggregation in the context of linear prediction models. Econometrica 57(4), 861888.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Pesaran, M. H., Pierse, R. G. and Lee, K. C. (1994) Choice between disaggregate and aggregate specifications estimated by instrumental variables methods. Journal of Business & Economic Statistics 12(1), 1121.Google Scholar
Rossi, B. and Sekhposyan, T. (2015) Macroeconomic uncertainty indices based on nowcast and forecast error distributions. The American Economic Review 105(5), 650655.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Scotti, C. (2016) Surprise and uncertainty indexes: Real-time aggregation of real-activity macro-surprises. Journal of Monetary Economics 82(2), 119.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Shoag, D. and Veuger, S. (2016) Uncertainty and the geography of the Great Recession. Journal of Monetary Economics 84(2), 8493.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Tran, T. D. (2021). The macroeconomic effects of commodity price uncertainty. Centre for Applied Macroeconomics Analysis Working Paper. https://www.anu.edu.au/ CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Van Garderen, K. J., Lee, K. and Pesaran, M. H. (2000) Cross-sectional aggregation of non-linear models. Journal of Econometrics 95(2), 285331.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Figure 0

Table 1. List of search terms

Figure 1

Figure 1. GTU index for selected states in the USA. Notes: The index is transformed to have a mean of 100 and standard deviation of 30. The shaded area represents the Great Recession.

Figure 2

Figure 2. Cross-state uncertainty correlation.

Figure 3

Table 2. F-test statistics on the joint significance of national uncertainty ($us^*$) and national unemployment ($ur^*$)

Figure 4

Table 3. F-test statistics on the joint significance of state-specific uncertainty ($us$)

Figure 5

Figure 3. Prediction criteria. Notes: This figure plots the observed $D_{ad}$, which is the difference in the prediction criteria test statistic (red line) and $d^*_{ad}(\alpha )$, which is the left tail of the simulated distribution of the prediction criteria test statistic (dotted blue line) and assesses the ability of the disaggregate model versus the aggregate model in predicting aggregate uncertainty and aggregate unemployment, respectively. The figure also plots the observed $D_{dpard}$, which is the difference in the prediction criteria test statistic (red line) and $d^*_{dpard}(\alpha )$, which is the left tail of the simulated distribution of the prediction criteria test statistic (dotted blue line) and assesses the ability of the disaggregate model versus the partial disaggregate model without state-level uncertainty in predicting unemployment.

Figure 6

Table 4. Evaluation of out-of-sample point and density forecasts

Figure 7

Figure 4. Aggregate uncertainty shocks on aggregate unemployment. Notes: This figure compares the IRFs of a one-standard-deviation aggregate uncertainty shock in the GVAR model to the VAR model. The GVAR IRFs are the weighted response of each state unemployment to an aggregate uncertainty shock in the GVAR model, where the aggregate shock is defined in equation (12) through using population weights. The VAR IRFs are constructed via the Cholesky decomposition where uncertainty is placed first. Unemployment is defined as the quarterly change in unemployment rate. The confidence interval is the bootstrapped IRFs at $\pm 1$ s.d.

Figure 8

Figure 5. US heatmap—peak response of state-level unemployment to an aggregate uncertainty shock. Notes: This figure presents the median estimate of the peak response of state-level unemployment to a one-standard-deviation aggregate uncertainty shock.

Figure 9

Figure 6. US heatmap—relative importance of national uncertainty. Notes: This figure plots $\frac{p^{NU}_{ii}}{p^U_{ii}}$, which measures the relative importance of national influences in propagating uncertainty shocks on state $i$’s unemployment.

Figure 10

Table 5. Heterogeneity analysis on the response of state-level unemployment to an aggregate uncertainty shock

Figure 11

Table 6. Heterogeneity analysis on the importance of national influences in propagating uncertainty shocks