Skip to main content Accessibility help
×
Hostname: page-component-848d4c4894-xfwgj Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-06-30T09:30:56.299Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

References

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  16 February 2023

Adam Oliver
Affiliation:
London School of Economics and Political Science
Get access

Summary

Image of the first page of this content. For PDF version, please use the ‘Save PDF’ preceeding this image.'
Type
Chapter
Information
Publisher: Cambridge University Press
Print publication year: 2023

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

References

Akerlof, G. 1982. Labor Contracts as Partial Gift Exchange. Quarterly Journal of Economics 97: 543569.Google Scholar
Akerlof, G. A., and Shiller, R. J. 2015. Phishing for Phools: The Economics of Manipulation and Deception. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Allais, M. 1953. Le comportement de l’homme rationnel devant le risque: critique des postulats et axiomes de l’ecole américaine. Econometrica 21: 503546.Google Scholar
Anderson, E. 1993. Value in Ethics and Economics. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.Google Scholar
Anderson, E. 2017. Private Government: How Employers Rule Our Lives (and Why We Don’t Talk about It). Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Aristotle, . 1980. The Nicomachean Ethics. Translated by David Ross (Oxford World’s Classics). Oxford: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Arrow, K. 1972. Gifts and Exchanges. Philosophy and Public Affairs 1: 343362.Google Scholar
Attenborough, D. 1979/2019. Life on Earth. London: William Collins.Google Scholar
Banfield, E. C. 1958. The Moral Basis of a Backward Society. New York, NY: The Free Press.Google Scholar
Behavioural Insights Team. 2013. Applying Behavioural Insights to Organ Donation: Preliminary Results from a Randomised Controlled Trial. London: Behavioural Insights Team.Google Scholar
Bellamy, E. 1888/1996. Looking Backward. New York, NY: Dover Publications Inc.Google Scholar
Benjamin, D., Cooper, K., Heffetz, O. and Kimball, M. 2020. Self-Reported Wellbeing Indicators Are a Valuable Complement to Traditional Economic Indicators but Are Not yet Ready to Compete with Them. Behavioural Public Policy 4: 198209.Google Scholar
Bentham, J. 1781/1988. The Principles of Morals and Legislation. New York, NY: Prometheus Books.Google Scholar
Berlin, I. 1969. Introduction. In Mill, J. S. [1863/1969], On Liberty and Utilitarianism. Oxford: Oxford University Press, pp. viixxxix.Google Scholar
Bernheim, D. 2010. Behavioral Welfare Economics. Panoeconomicus 57: 123151.Google Scholar
Bernheim, D. 2016. The Good, the Bad, and the Ugly: A Unified Approach to Behavioural Welfare Economics. Journal of Benefit-Cost Analysis 7: 157.Google Scholar
Binmore, K. 2005. Economic Man – Or Straw Man? Behavioral and Brain Sciences 28: 817818.Google Scholar
Blau, P. M. 1964. Exchange and Power in Social Life. New York, NY: Wiley.Google Scholar
Boehm, C. 2012. Moral Origins: The Evolution of Virtue, Altruism and Shame. New York, NY: Basic Books.Google Scholar
Buchanan, J. M. 1979. What Should Economists Do? Indianapolis, IN: Liberty Press.Google Scholar
Caldwell, B. 2005. Hayek’s Challenge: An Intellectual Biography of F. A. Hayek. Chicago, IL: The University of Chicago Press.Google Scholar
Camerer, C. F. 2003. Behavioral Game Theory: Experiments in Strategic Interaction. New York, NY: Russell Sage Foundation.Google Scholar
Camerer, C. F., and Loewenstein, G. 2003. Behavioral Economics: Past, Present, Future. In Camerer, C. F., Loewenstein, G. and Rabin, M. (eds.), Advances in Behavioral Economics. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press, pp. 351.Google Scholar
Camerer, C., and Thaler, R. 1995. Ultimatums, Dictators, and Manners. Journal of Economic Perspectives 9: 209219.Google Scholar
Camerer, C., Issacharoff, S., Loewenstein, G., O’Donoghue, T. and Rabin, M. 2003. Regulation for Conservatives: Behavioral Economics and the Case for ‘Asymmetric Paternalism’. University of Pennsylvania Law Review 1151: 12111254.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Carlsson, F., He, H. and Martinsson, P. 2013. Easy Come, Easy Go: The Role of Windfall Money in Lab and Field Experiments. Experimental Economics 16: 190207.Google Scholar
Carter, G. G., and Wilkinson, G. S. 2013. Food Sharing in Vampire Bats: Reciprocal Help Predicts Donations More Than Relatedness or Harassment. Proceedings of the Royal Society B 280: 20122573.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Chater, N. 2022. What Is the Point of Behavioural Public Policy? A Contractarian Approach. Behavioural Public Policy, forthcoming.Google Scholar
Chater, N., and Loewenstein, G. F. 2022. The I-Frame and the S-Frame: How Focusing on the Individual-Level Solutions Has Led Behavioural Public Policy Astray. Available at SSRN: https://papers.ssrn.com/sol3/papers.cfm?abstract_id=4046264Google Scholar
Cherry, T. L., Frykblom, P. and Shogren, J. F. 2002. Hardnose the Dictator. American Economic Review 92: 12181221.Google Scholar
Conly, S. 2013. Against Autonomy: Justifying Coercive Paternalism. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Daniels, N. 1985. Just Health Care. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Darwin, C. 1879/2004. The Descent of Man. London: Penguin Classics.Google Scholar
de Tocqueville, A. 1835/1998. Democracy in America. Hertfordshire: Wordsworth Editions Limited.Google Scholar
de Waal, F. 2010. The Age of Empathy: Nature’s Lessons for a Kinder Society. London: Souvenir Press.Google Scholar
Dworkin, G. 1972. Paternalism. Monist 56: 6484.Google Scholar
Easterlin, R. A. 1974. Does Economic Growth Improve the Human Lot? Some Empirical Evidence. In David, P. A. and Reder, M. W. (eds.), Nations and Households in Economic Growth. New York, NY and London: Academic Press, pp. 89125.Google Scholar
Egan, P. 1830/2006. Boxiana. Boston, MA: Elibron Classics.Google Scholar
Engel, C. 2011. Dictator Games: A Meta Study. Experimental Economics 14: 583610.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Enthoven, A. C. 1985. Reflections on the Management of the National Health Service. London: Nuffield Provincial Hospitals Trust.Google Scholar
Falk, A., and Fischbacher, U. 2006. A Theory of Reciprocity. Games and Economic Behavior 54: 293315.Google Scholar
Feinberg, J. 1970. Doing & Deserving: Essays in the Theory of Responsibility. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Feinberg, J. 1986. Harm to Self. Volume 3 of the Moral Limits to the Criminal Law. Oxford: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Friedman, M., and Friedman, R. 1980/1990. Free to Choose: A Personal Statement. Orlando, FL: Harvest.Google Scholar
Frijters, P., Clark, A. E., Krekel, C. and Layard, R. 2020. A Happy Choice: Wellbeing as the Goal of Government. Behavioural Public Policy 4: 126165.Google Scholar
Hamann, K., Bender, J. and Tomasello, M. 2013. Meritocratic Sharing Is Based on Collaboration in 3-Year-Olds. Developmental Psychology 50: 121128.Google Scholar
Hausman, D. M. 2015. Valuing Health: Well-Being, Freedom and Suffering. Oxford: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Hayek, F. A. 1944/2001. The Road to Serfdom. Abingdon: Routledge Classics.Google Scholar
Heath, A. 1976. Rational Choice and Exchange: A Critique of Exchange Theory. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Heinrich, J. 2021. The Weirdest People in the World: How the West Became Psychologically Peculiar and Particularly Prosperous. London: Penguin Books.Google Scholar
Helliwell, J. F. 2020. Three Questions about Happiness. Behavioural Public Policy 4: 177187.Google Scholar
Henrich, J. 2016. The Secret of Our Success: How Culture Is Driving Human Evolution, Domesticating Our Species and Making Us Smarter. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Henrich, J., Boyd, R., Bowles, S., et al. 2005. “Economic Man” in Cross-Cultural Perspective: Behavioral Experiments in 15 Small-Scale Societies. Behavioral and Brain Sciences 28: 795855.Google Scholar
Hertwig, R. 2017. When to Consider Boosting: Some Rules for Policy-Makers. Behavioural Public Policy 1: 143161.Google Scholar
Huber, J., Payne, J. W. and Puto, C. 1982. Adding Asymmetrically Dominated Alternatives: Violations of Regularity and the Similarity Hypothesis. Journal of Consumer Research 9: 9098.Google Scholar
Hume, D. 1751/2018. An Enquiry Concerning the Principles of Morals. In Coventry, A., and Valls, A. (eds.), David Hume on Morals, Politics, and Society. New Haven, CT: Yale University Press, pp. 3131.Google Scholar
Hume, D. 1777/2018. Essays and Treatises on Several Subjects. Printed as Essays, Moral, Political and Literary. In Coventry, A., and Valls, A. (eds.), David Hume on Morals, Politics, and Society. New Haven, CT: Yale University Press, pp. 132238.Google Scholar
John, P. 2018. How Far to Nudge? Assessing Behavioural Public Policy. Cheltenham: Edward Elgar Publishing.Google Scholar
John, P., Cotterill, S., Moseley, A., Richardson, L., Smith, G., Stoker, G. and Wales, C. 2011. Nudge, Nudge, Think, Think: Experimenting with Ways to Change Civic Behaviour. London: Bloomsbury Academic.Google Scholar
Kahneman, D. 2011. Thinking, Fast and Slow. London: Allen Lane.Google Scholar
Kahneman, D., and Tversky, A. 1979. Prospect Theory: An Analysis of Decision under Risk. Econometrica 47: 263292.Google Scholar
Kahneman, D., Wakker, P. P. and Sarin, R. 1997. Back to Bentham? Explorations of Expected Utility. The Quarterly Journal of Economics 112: 375405.Google Scholar
Kanngiesser, P., and Warneken, F. 2012. Young Children Consider Merit When Sharing Resources with Others. PLoS ONE 7: e443979.Google Scholar
Kant, I. 1785/1981. Grounding for the Metaphysics of Morals. Translated by Ellington, James. Indianapolis, IN: Hackett.Google Scholar
Kropotkin, P. 1902/2014. Mutual Aid: A Factor in Evolution. Seattle, WA: Createspace Independent Publishing Platform.Google Scholar
Layard, R. 2005. Happiness: Lessons from a New Science. London: Allen Lane.Google Scholar
Le Grand, J. 1991. Equity and Choice: An Essay in Economics and Applied Philosophy. New York, NY: Harper Collins Academic.Google Scholar
Le Grand, J. 1997. Knights, Knaves or Pawns? Human Behaviour and Social Policy. Journal of Social Policy 26: 149169.Google Scholar
Le Grand, J., and New, B. 2015. Government Paternalism: Nanny State or Helpful Friend. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
March, J. G. 1974. The Technology of Foolishness. In Leavitt, H., Pinfield, L. and Webb, E. (eds.), Organizations of the Future: Interaction with the External Environment. New York, NY: Praeger, pp. 131142.Google Scholar
Markowitz, H. 1952. The Utility of Wealth. Journal of Political Economy 60: 151158.Google Scholar
Mauss, M. 1954. The Gift: Forms and Functions of Exchange in Archaic Societies. Glencoe, IL: The Free Press.Google Scholar
Meyer, R., and Kunreuther, H. 2017. The Ostrich Paradox: Why We Underprepare for Disasters. Philadelphia, PA: Wharton Digital Press.Google Scholar
Mill, J. S. 1848/1970. Principles of Political Economy. Middlesex: Pelican Classics.Google Scholar
Mill, J. S. 1859/1969. On Liberty. In On Liberty and Utilitarianism. Oxford: Oxford University Press, pp. 1110.Google Scholar
Mill, J. S. 1863/1969. Utilitarianism. In On Liberty and Utilitarianism. Oxford: Oxford University Press, pp. 111172.Google Scholar
Mishel, L., and Sabadish, N. 2013. CEO Pay in 2012 Was Extraordinarily High Relative to Typical Workers and Other High Earners. Washington, DC: Economic Policy Institute.Google Scholar
Moore, J., and Desmond, A. 2004. In Darwin, C. [1879/2004], The Descent of Man. London: Penguin Classics.Google Scholar
Musgrave, R. A. 1957. A Multiple Theory of Budget Determination. Finanzarchiv 17: 333343.Google Scholar
Musgrave, R. A. 1959. The Theory of Public Finance: A Study in Public Economy. New York, NY: McGraw Hill.Google Scholar
Nagel, T. 1986. The View from Nowhere. Oxford: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Nakamura, R., Pechey, R., Suhrcke, M., Jebb, S. A. and Marteau, T. M. 2014. Sales Impact of Displaying Alcoholic and Non-alcoholic Beverages in End-of-Aisle Locations: An Observational Study. Social Science & Medicine 108: 6873.Google Scholar
Nussbaum, M. C. 2013. Creating Capabilities: The Human Development Approach. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.Google Scholar
Oliver, A. 2013. From Nudging to Budging: Using Behavioural Economics to Inform Public Sector Policy. Journal of Social Policy 42: 685700.Google Scholar
Oliver, A. 2015. Nudging, Shoving and Budging: Behavioural Economic-Informed Policy. Public Administration 93: 700714.Google Scholar
Oliver, A. 2017. The Origins of Behavioural Public Policy. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Oliver, A. 2018. Your Money and Your Life: Risk Attitudes over Gains and Losses. Journal of Risk and Uncertainty 57: 2950.Google Scholar
Oliver, A. 2019. Reciprocity and the Art of Behavioural Public Policy. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Oliver, A. 2020. Reviving and Revising Economic Liberalism: An Examination in Relation to Private Decisions and Public Policy. Journal of European Public Policy 12: 17631780.Google Scholar
Oliver, A. 2022. If You’ve Earned It, You Deserve It: Ultimatums, with Lego. Behavioural Public Policy, forthcoming.Google Scholar
Ostrom, E. 1990. Governing the Commons: The Evolution of Institutions for Collective Action. New York, NY: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Ostrom, E. 2000. Collective Action and the Evolution of Social Norms. Journal of Economic Perspectives 14: 137158.Google Scholar
Oxfam, 2017. An Economy for the 99%. Oxford: Oxfam.Google Scholar
Oxoby, R. J., and Spraggon, J. 2008. Mine and Yours: Property Rights in Dictator Games. Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization 65: 703713.Google Scholar
Pinker, S. 2018. Enlightenment Now: The Case for Reason, Science, Humanism and Progress. London: Allen Lane.Google Scholar
Prelec, D. 2013. Decision Analysis from a Neo-Calvinist Point of View. In Oliver, A. (ed.), Behavioural Public Policy. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, pp. 216227.Google Scholar
Rawls, J. 1999. A Theory of Justice. 2nd Revised Edition. Oxford: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Raz, J. 1986. The Morality of Freedom. Oxford: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Rebonato, R. 2012. Taking Liberties: A Critical Examination of Libertarian Paternalism. Basingstoke: Palgrave Macmillan.Google Scholar
Reijula, S., and Hertwig, R. 2022. Self-Nudging and the Citizen Architect. Behavioural Public Policy 6: 119149.Google Scholar
Rizzo, M. J., and Whitman, G. 2020. Escaping Paternalism: Rationality, Behavioural Economics, and Public Policy. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Rizzo, M. J., and Whitman, G. 2022. The Unsolved Hayekian Knowledge Problem in Behavioral Economics. Behavioural Public Policy, forthcoming.Google Scholar
Rosenblatt, H. 2018. The Lost History of Liberalism: From Ancient Rome to the Twenty-First Century. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Roth, A. 1995. Bargaining Experiments. In Kagel, J., and Roth, A. (eds.), Handbook of Experimental Economics. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press, pp. 254348.Google Scholar
Ruffle, B. 1998. More Is Better, But Fair Is Fair: Tipping in Dictator and Ultimatum Games. Games and Economic Behavior 23: 247265.Google Scholar
Russell, B. 1946/1996. History of Western Philosophy. London: George Allen & Unwin Ltd.Google Scholar
Salter, J. 1986. Introduction. In Liebling, A. J. 1962/1986. Between Meals: An Appetite for Paris. New York, NY: North Point Press, pp. ixxix.Google Scholar
Samuelson, P. 1963. A Fallacy of Large Numbers. Scienta 98: 108113.Google Scholar
Sapolsky, R. 2017. Behave: The Biology of Humans at Our Best and Worst. London: Bodley Head.Google Scholar
Sen, A. 1985. Commodities and Capabilities. Amsterdam: North-Holland.Google Scholar
Sen, A. 1999. Development as Freedom. New York, NY: Random House.Google Scholar
Sidgwick, H. 1891. The Elements of Politics. London: Macmillan.Google Scholar
Simon, H. A. 1956. Rational Choice and the Structure of the Environment. Psychological Review 63: 129138.Google Scholar
Smith, A. 1776/1999. The Wealth of Nations. London: Penguin Classics.Google Scholar
Smith, A. 1759/2009. The Theory of Moral Sentiments. London: Penguin Classics.Google Scholar
Starmans, C., Sheskin, M. and Bloom, P. 2017. Why People Prefer Unequal Societies. Nature Human Behaviour 1: 17.Google Scholar
Sugden, R. 2009. On Nudging. A Review of Nudge: Improving Decisions about Health, Wealth and Happiness by Richard H. Thaler and Cass R. Sunstein. International Journal of the Economics of Business 16: 365373.Google Scholar
Sugden, R. 2018. The Community of Advantage: A Behavioural Defence of the Liberal Tradition of Economics. Oxford: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Sugden, R. 2022. How Hayekian Is Sunstein’s Behavioral Economics? Behavioural Public Policy, forthcoming.Google Scholar
Sunstein, C. R. 2013. Simpler. New York: Simon & Schuster.Google Scholar
Sunstein, C. R. 2016. The Ethics of Influence: Government in the Age of Behavioural Science. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Sunstein, C. R. 2019a. On Freedom. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Sunstein, C. R. 2020. Behavioral Welfare Economics. Journal of Benefit-Cost Analysis 11: 196220.Google Scholar
Sunstein, C. R. 2022a. Sludge Audits. Behavioural Public Policy 6: 654673.Google Scholar
Sunstein, C. R. 2022b. Hayekian Behavioral Economics. Behavioural Public Policy, forthcoming.Google Scholar
Thaler, R. H. 2015. Misbehaving: The Making of Behavioural Economics. New York, NY: Penguin Random House.Google Scholar
Thaler, R. H., and Sunstein, C. R. 2003. Libertarian Paternalism. The American Economic Review 93: 175179.Google Scholar
Thaler, R. H., and Sunstein, C. R. 2008. Nudge: Improving Decisions about Health, Wealth and Happiness. New Haven, CT: Yale University Press.Google Scholar
Titmuss, R. M. 1970/1997. The Gift Relationship: From Human Blood to Social Policy. New York, NY: The New Press.Google Scholar
Tversky, A., and Kahneman, D. 1992. Advances in Prospect Theory: Cumulative Representation of Uncertainty. Journal of Risk and Uncertainty 5: 297323.Google Scholar
von Humboldt, W. 1791–1792/1993. The Limits of State Action. Indianapolis, IN: The Liberty Fund.Google Scholar
von Mises, L. 1927/2005. Liberalism. The Classical Tradition. Indianapolis, IN: The Liberty Fund.Google Scholar
von Neumann, J., and Morgenstern, O. 1944. Theory of Games and Economic Behavior. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Weale, A. 1978. Paternalism and Social Policy. Journal of Social Policy 7: 157172.Google Scholar
Wilkinson, G. S. 1984. Reciprocal Food Sharing in the Vampire Bat. Nature 308: 181184.Google Scholar
Winch, D. 1970. Introduction. In Mill, J. S. 1848/1970. Principles of Political Economy. Middlesex: Pelican Classics.Google Scholar
Xiao, E., and Bicchieri, C. 2010. When Equality Trumps Reciprocity. Journal of Economic Psychology 31: 456470.Google Scholar

Save book to Kindle

To save this book to your Kindle, first ensure coreplatform@cambridge.org is added to your Approved Personal Document E-mail List under your Personal Document Settings on the Manage Your Content and Devices page of your Amazon account. Then enter the ‘name’ part of your Kindle email address below. Find out more about saving to your Kindle.

Note you can select to save to either the @free.kindle.com or @kindle.com variations. ‘@free.kindle.com’ emails are free but can only be saved to your device when it is connected to wi-fi. ‘@kindle.com’ emails can be delivered even when you are not connected to wi-fi, but note that service fees apply.

Find out more about the Kindle Personal Document Service.

  • References
  • Adam Oliver, London School of Economics and Political Science
  • Book: A Political Economy of Behavioural Public Policy
  • Online publication: 16 February 2023
  • Chapter DOI: https://doi.org/10.1017/9781009282574.014
Available formats
×

Save book to Dropbox

To save content items to your account, please confirm that you agree to abide by our usage policies. If this is the first time you use this feature, you will be asked to authorise Cambridge Core to connect with your account. Find out more about saving content to Dropbox.

  • References
  • Adam Oliver, London School of Economics and Political Science
  • Book: A Political Economy of Behavioural Public Policy
  • Online publication: 16 February 2023
  • Chapter DOI: https://doi.org/10.1017/9781009282574.014
Available formats
×

Save book to Google Drive

To save content items to your account, please confirm that you agree to abide by our usage policies. If this is the first time you use this feature, you will be asked to authorise Cambridge Core to connect with your account. Find out more about saving content to Google Drive.

  • References
  • Adam Oliver, London School of Economics and Political Science
  • Book: A Political Economy of Behavioural Public Policy
  • Online publication: 16 February 2023
  • Chapter DOI: https://doi.org/10.1017/9781009282574.014
Available formats
×