Skip to main content Accessibility help
×
Hostname: page-component-77c89778f8-7drxs Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-07-18T17:26:10.736Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

2 - The Consensus about a Greater Incumbency Effect

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  06 July 2010

Jeffrey M. Stonecash
Affiliation:
Syracuse University, New York
Get access

Summary

In 1974 David Mayhew (1974a) called attention to a significant change in House election results. He classified districts as safe if the incumbent won with 60 percent or more of the vote and marginal if the incumbent received less than that. He then compared the frequency of safe and marginal districts for the years 1946–1972. It was clear that the percentage of marginal districts decreased in 1966. Figure 2.1 shows the percentage of House elections involving incumbents who had marginal outcomes from 1956 to 1972. Something happened in 1966 and in subsequent elections involving incumbents. For 1956–1964 an average of 40.4 percent of House incumbent outcomes were marginal. For 1966–1972 the average was 29.7. Subsequent studies confirmed the existence of this trend (Cover and Mayhew, 1977: 63; Krehbiel and Wright, 1983: 143).

Mayhew's speculative, but very plausible, explanation of this change was that members were allocating themselves more of the resources that could be used to increase their visibility, popularity, and vote percentages. Members were sending out more government-funded mail to constituents, allowing them to boost their visibility. They were performing more constituency services, helping constituents with problems. The number of grant-in-aid programs was increasing, allowing members to claim more credit for bringing benefits to the district. They were doing more for their constituents and had more resources to advertise these efforts (Mayhew, 1974a: 310–11, 1974b: 53–60, 84–85).

Type
Chapter
Information
Publisher: Cambridge University Press
Print publication year: 2008

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

Save book to Kindle

To save this book to your Kindle, first ensure coreplatform@cambridge.org is added to your Approved Personal Document E-mail List under your Personal Document Settings on the Manage Your Content and Devices page of your Amazon account. Then enter the ‘name’ part of your Kindle email address below. Find out more about saving to your Kindle.

Note you can select to save to either the @free.kindle.com or @kindle.com variations. ‘@free.kindle.com’ emails are free but can only be saved to your device when it is connected to wi-fi. ‘@kindle.com’ emails can be delivered even when you are not connected to wi-fi, but note that service fees apply.

Find out more about the Kindle Personal Document Service.

Available formats
×

Save book to Dropbox

To save content items to your account, please confirm that you agree to abide by our usage policies. If this is the first time you use this feature, you will be asked to authorise Cambridge Core to connect with your account. Find out more about saving content to Dropbox.

Available formats
×

Save book to Google Drive

To save content items to your account, please confirm that you agree to abide by our usage policies. If this is the first time you use this feature, you will be asked to authorise Cambridge Core to connect with your account. Find out more about saving content to Google Drive.

Available formats
×