Skip to main content Accessibility help
×
Hostname: page-component-7479d7b7d-c9gpj Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-07-15T17:48:31.620Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

4 - The Political Economy of Autocratic Constitutions

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  05 June 2014

Michael Albertus
Affiliation:
University of Chicago
Victor Menaldo
Affiliation:
University of Washington
Tom Ginsburg
Affiliation:
University of Chicago
Alberto Simpser
Affiliation:
University of Chicago
Get access

Summary

Austria adopted a new constitution in 1934, as did Portugal in 1933, Poland in 1935, Turkey in 1924, and Brazil in 1937 and again in 1967. Besides the fact that these are constitutions adopted in countries characterized by colorful political histories marked by periods of both drastic change and hard-fought stability, what do their constitutions share in common? They were adopted under dictatorship. Although all of these countries eventually transitioned to democracy, these constitutions were not designed to bring about democracy – although some of them served, decades after being adopted, as vehicles for introducing elections and checks on executive authority.

Why do autocrats adopt constitutions? This chapter argues that the fundamental reason is that constitutions can help dictators consolidate power, increase investment, and boost economic development – all while generating a steady flow of rents for themselves and their cronies without empowering challengers that might undermine their authority. This claim may come as a surprise to most readers. It certainly challenges the status-quo, minimalist view that an autocratic constitution is merely window dressing that provides lip service to the rule of law and rights without the sincere intention to enforce them (see Posner and Young 2007, and Chapter 1 of this volume). It also challenges the view that in a dictatorship, a constitution is a formality and afterthought that merely announces that the dictator's authority is supreme and formally and publicly announces his political agenda (Brown 2002).

Type
Chapter
Information
Publisher: Cambridge University Press
Print publication year: 2013

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

References

Acemoglu, Daron, Robinson, James, and Verdier, Thierry. 2004. “Kleptocracy and Divide-and-Rule.” Journal of the European Economic Association Papers and Proceedings 2: 162–92.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Albertus, Michael and Menaldo, Victor. 2012a. “If You're With Them You're Against Us: The Effect of Expropriation on Autocratic Survival.” Comparative Political Studies 45(8): 973–1003.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Albertus, Michael and Menaldo, Victor. 2012b. “Dictators as Founding Fathers? The Role of Constitutions Under Autocracy.” Economics & Politics 24(3): 279–306.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Albertus, Michael and Menaldo, Victor. Forthcoming. “Gaming Democracy: Elite Dominance During Transition and the Prospects for Redistribution.” British Journal of Political Science.
Ahlquist, John and Prakash, Aseem. 2008. “The Influence of Foreign Direct Investment on Contracting Confidence in Developing Countries.” Regulation & Governance 2: 316–39.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Barro, Robert. 1998. Determinants of Economic Growth. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.Google Scholar
Barros, Robert. 2002. Constitutionalism and Dictatorship. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Besley, Timothy and Kudamatsu, Masayuki. 2007. “Making Autocracy Work.” Unpublished manuscript.
Boix, Carles and Svolik, Milan. 2008. “The Foundations of Limited Authoritarian Government: Institutions and Power-Sharing in Dictatorships.” Unpublished manuscript.
Box-Steffensmeier, Janet and Jones, Bradford. 1997. “Time Is of the Essence: Event History Models in Political Science.” American Journal of Political Science 41(4): 1414–61.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Brown, Nathan. 2002. Constitutions in a Nonconstitutional World: Arab Basic Laws and the Prospects for Accountable Government. Albany, NY: SUNY Press.Google Scholar
Brunnschweiler, Christa. 2008. “Cursing the Blessings? Natural Resource Abundance, Institutions, and Economic Growth.” World Development 36(3): 399–419.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bueno de Mesquita, Bruce, Smith, Alastair, Siverson, Randolph, and Morrow, James. 2003. The Logic of Political Survival. Boston: MIT Press.Google Scholar
Carey, John. 2000. “Parchment, Equilibria, and Institutions.” Comparative Political Studies 33(6): 735–61.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Carter, David and Signorino, Curtis. 2010. “Back to the Future: Modeling Time Dependence in Binary Data.” Political Analysis 18: 271–92.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Cheibub, Jose-Antonio and Gandhi, Jennifer. 2004. “Classifying Political Regimes: A Six-Fold Classification of Democracies and Dictatorships.” Unpublished manuscript.
Clague, Christopher, Keefer, Philip, Knack, Stephen, and Olson, Mancur. 1996. “Property and Contract Rights in Autocracies and Democracies.” Journal of Economic Growth 1: 243–76.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Clague, Christopher, Keefer, Philip, Knack, Stephen, and Olson, Mancur. 1999. “Contract-Intensive Money.” Journal of Economic Growth 4: 185–211.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Elkins, Zachary. 2010. “Diffusion and the Constitutionalization of Europe.” Comparative Political Studies 43: 969–99.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Elkins, Zachary, Ginsburg, Tom, and Melton, James. 2009. The Endurance of National Constitutions. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Elkins, Zachary, Ginsburg, Tom, and Melton, James. 2010. The Comparative Constitutions Project. Available at .
de Figueiredo, Rui and Weingast, Barry. 1997. “Rationality of Fear: Political Opportunism and Ethnic Conflict,” in Snyder, Jack and Walter, Barbara, eds., Military Intervention in Civil Wars. New York: Columbia University Press, pp. 262–3.Google Scholar
Gandhi, Jennifer. 2008. Political Institutions under Dictatorship. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Gandhi, Jennifer and Przeworski, Adam. 2006. “Cooperation, Cooptation and Rebellion Under Dictatorship.” Economics and Politics 18(1): 1–26.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Geddes, Barbara. 2003. Paradigms and Sand Castles. Ann Arbor: University of Michigan Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Gehlbach, Scott and Keefer, Philip. 2011. “Investment without Democracy: Ruling-Party Institutionalization and Credible Commitment in Autocracies.” Journal of Comparative Economics 39(2): 123–39.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Glaeser, Edward L., La Porta, Rafael, Lopez-de-Silanes, Florencio, and Shleifer, Andrei. 2004. “Do Institutions Cause Growth?Journal of Economic Growth 9(3): 271–303.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Goemens, Henk, Gleditsch, Kristian Skrede, and Chiozza, Giacomo. 2009. “Introducing Archigos: A Dataset of Political Leaders.” Journal of Peace Research 46: 269–83.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Haber, Stephen. 2006. “Authoritarian Government,” in Weingast, Barry and Wittman, Donald, eds., The Oxford Handbook of Political Economy. New York: Oxford University Press, pp. 693–707.Google Scholar
Haber, Stephen, Razo, Armando, and Mauerer, Noel. 2003. The Politics of Property Rights. New York: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hardin, Russell. 1989. “Why a Constitution,” in Grofman, Bernard and Wittman, Donald, eds., The Federalist Papers and the New Institutionalism. New York: Agathon, pp.100–20.Google Scholar
Hyde, Susan, and Marinov, Nikolay. 2012. “Which Elections Can Be Lost?Political Analysis 20(2): 191–210.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Londregan, John, and Poole, Keith. 1990. “Poverty, the Coup Trap, and the Seizure of Executive Power.” World Politics 42: 151–83.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lust-Okar, Ellen. 2006. “Elections under Authoritarianism: Preliminary Lessons from Jordan.” Democratization 13: 456–71.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Magaloni, Beatriz. 2008. “Credible Power-Sharing and the Longevity of Authoritarian Rule.” Comparative Political Studies 41(4/5): 715–41.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Menaldo, Victor. 2012. “The Middle East and North Africa's Resilient Monarchs.” Journal of Politics 74(3): 707–22.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Myerson, Roger. 2008. “The Autocrat's Credibility Problem and Foundations of the Constitutional State.” American Political Science Review 102: 125–39.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Negretto, Gabriel. 2013. Making Constitutions: Presidents, Parties, and Institutional Choice in Latin America. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
North, Douglass and Weingast, Barry. 1989. “Constitutions and Commitment.” Journal of Economic History 49: 803–32.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ordeshook, Peter. 1992. “Constitutional Stability.” Constitutional Political Economy 3: 137–75.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Posner, Daniel and Young, Daniel. 2007. “The Institutionalization of Political Power in Africa.” Journal of Democracy 18: 126–40.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Sachs, Jeffrey and Warner, Andrew. 1995. Natural Resource Abundance and Economic Growth. NBER Working Paper No. 5398.
Schedler, Andreas. 2002. “Elections Without Democracy: The Menu of Manipulation.” Journal of Democracy 13: 36–50.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Shepsle, Kenneth and Weingast, Barry. 1981. “Structure-Induced Equilibrium and Legislative Choice.” Public Choice 37: 503–19.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Smith, Benjamin. 2004. “Oil Wealth and Regime Survival in the Developing World, 1960–1999.” American Journal of Political Science 48: 232–46.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Summerhill, William. 2007. “Sovereign Credibility with Financial Underdevelopment: The Case of Nineteenth-Century Brazil.” Unpublished manuscript.
Svolik, Milan. 2012. The Politics of Authoritarian Rule. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Weingast, Barry. 1997. “The Political Foundations of Democracy and the Rule of Law.” American Political Science Review 91(2): 245–63.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Wright, Joseph. 2008. “Do Authoritarian Institutions Constrain? How Legislatures Affect Economic Growth and Investment.” American Journal of Political Science 52(2): 322–43.CrossRefGoogle Scholar

Save book to Kindle

To save this book to your Kindle, first ensure coreplatform@cambridge.org is added to your Approved Personal Document E-mail List under your Personal Document Settings on the Manage Your Content and Devices page of your Amazon account. Then enter the ‘name’ part of your Kindle email address below. Find out more about saving to your Kindle.

Note you can select to save to either the @free.kindle.com or @kindle.com variations. ‘@free.kindle.com’ emails are free but can only be saved to your device when it is connected to wi-fi. ‘@kindle.com’ emails can be delivered even when you are not connected to wi-fi, but note that service fees apply.

Find out more about the Kindle Personal Document Service.

Available formats
×

Save book to Dropbox

To save content items to your account, please confirm that you agree to abide by our usage policies. If this is the first time you use this feature, you will be asked to authorise Cambridge Core to connect with your account. Find out more about saving content to Dropbox.

Available formats
×

Save book to Google Drive

To save content items to your account, please confirm that you agree to abide by our usage policies. If this is the first time you use this feature, you will be asked to authorise Cambridge Core to connect with your account. Find out more about saving content to Google Drive.

Available formats
×