Skip to main content Accessibility help
×
Hostname: page-component-7479d7b7d-t6hkb Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-07-15T22:31:25.902Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

b - The Psychological Crisis of the Corporation: Employee-Owned Alternatives and Futures

from 10 - Alternatives to the Corporation

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  31 March 2017

William Davies
Affiliation:
University of London
Grietje Baars
Affiliation:
City University London
Andre Spicer
Affiliation:
City University London
Get access

Summary

It has long been understood that corporations generate negative ‘externalities’, otherwise known as ‘social costs’. These are costs that are clearly identifiable and often calculable, resulting from the activities of corporations, but which they do not account or pay for themselves. The classic examples of such externalities tend to involve environmental degradation, for instance, oil spills. Where these costs are sufficiently severe and the culprit sufficiently obvious, campaigns and regulatory agencies are mobilized to ensure that the corporation concerned re-admits these costs, through compensation, fines or some type of market-based incentive. It is worth noting, however, that all economic activity generates some externalities, be they positive or negative. The question is whether or not the unpriced cost or benefit is sufficiently great, quantifiable or problematic to require some accounting or regulatory innovation, to formally recognize and respond to it in some way.

In this chapter, I want to look at a particular type of externality, which receives less attention in critical analysis of corporations: psychological externalities. When the notion of ‘externality’ is invoked, it typically refers to something ‘social’, in the sense of non-market spaces, goods, values and relations. The notion of a ‘psychological externality’ is introduced here, to refer to the ways in which economic activity generates unhappiness of a kind that is both quantifiable and yet not adequately calculated by the price system. Just as corporations may externalize costs onto the environment, which eventually rebound onto all actors in a market (including themselves), so they can externalize costs onto the minds of employees, citizens and consumers, which eventually result in tangible economic costs for all. Various mental health afflictions, such as anxiety, depression and stress, are associated with corporate practices, which corporations do not themselves account for fully, which is why they are designated as ‘externalities’. While corporations may engage in various types of ‘wellness’ plans, to alleviate the impact of stress on their more valued employees (Cederstrom and Spicer, 2015), the broader psychological costs of work, advertising and corporate culture are typically externalized across the public.

Type
Chapter
Information
The Corporation
A Critical, Multi-Disciplinary Handbook
, pp. 527 - 537
Publisher: Cambridge University Press
Print publication year: 2017

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

References

Baritz, L. (1960) The Servants of Power (Middletown, CT: Wesleyan University Press).
Barley, S., and Kunda, G. (1992) ‘Design and devotion: surges of rational and normative ideologies of control in managerial discourse’, Administrative Science Quarterly 37(3): 363–399.Google Scholar
Beniger, J. R. (1986) The Control Revolution: Technological and Economic Origins of the Information Society (Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press).
Benzer, M. (2011) ‘Quality of life and risk conceptions in UK healthcare regulation: towards a critical analysis’, Discussion Paper 68 (London: Centre for Analysis of Risk and Regulation (CARR), London School of Economics).
Binkley, S. (2014) Happiness as Enterprise: An Essay on Neoliberal Life (New York: SUNY Press).
Blaug, R., Kenyon, A., and Lekhi, R. (2007) Stress at Work (London: Work Foundation).
Boltanski, L., and Chiapello, E. (2007) The New Spirit of Capitalism (London: Verso).
Bryson, A., and Freeman, R. B. (2008) How Does Shared Capitalism Affect Economic Performance in the UK? (Cambridge, MA: National Bureau of Economic Research).
Burgin, A. (2012) The Great Persuasion: Reinventing Free Markets since the Depression (Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press).
Cederstrom, C., and Fleming, P. (2012) Dead Man Working (London: Zero).
Cederstrom, C., and Spicer, A. (2015) The Wellness Syndrome (London: Polity Press).
Coase, R. H. (1960) ‘The problem of social cost’, Journal of Law and Economics 3(1): 1–44.Google Scholar
Crouch, C. (2011) The Strange Non-Death of Neoliberalism (Cambridge: Polity Press).
Davies, W. (2009) Reinventing the Firm (London: Demos).
Davies, W. (2010) ‘Economics and the “nonsense” of law: the case of the Chicago antitrust revolution’, Economy and Society 39(1): 64–83.Google Scholar
Davies, W. (2011a) ‘The political economy of unhappiness’, New Left Review 71 (September/October): 65–80.
Davies, W. (2011b) ‘Economic advice as a vocation: symbioses of scientific and political authority’, British Journal of Sociology 62(2): 304–323.Google Scholar
Davies, W. (2012) All of Our Business: Why Britain Needs Private Sector Employee Ownership (London: Employee Ownership Association).
Davies, W. (2014) The Limits of Neoliberalism: Authority, Sovereignty and the Logic of Competition (London: Sage).
Davies, W. (2015) The Happiness Industry: How Government and Big Business Sold Us Wellbeing (London: Verso).
Davies, W., and Michie, J. (2012) Employee Ownership: Defusing the Business Succession Time-Bomb in Wales (Swansea: Wales Co-operative Centre).
Davies, W., and Yeoman, R. (2013) Becoming a Public Service Mutual (Oxford: Centre for Mutual and Employee-owned Business).
Erdal, D. (2008) Local Heroes: How Loch Fyne Oysters Embraced Employee Ownership and Business Success (London: Viking).
Foucault, M. (2007) Security, Territory, Population: Lectures at the College de France, 1977–78 (Basingstoke: Palgrave Macmillan).
Friedli, L., and Stearn, R. (2015) ‘Positive affect as coercive strategy: conditionality, activation and the role of psychology in UK government workfare programmes’, Medical Humanities 41: 40–47.Google Scholar
Gallup, (2002) ‘The high cost of disengaged employees’, Gallup Business Journal, 15 April, http://businessjournal.gallup.com/content/247/the-high-cost-of-disengaged-employees.aspx.
Gilbert, J. (2014) Common Ground: Democracy and Collectivity in an Age of Individualism (London: Pluto).
Hoopes, J. (2003) False Prophets: The Gurus Who Created Modern Management and Why Their Ideas Are Bad for Business Today (New York: Perseus).
Horwitz, A., and Wakefield, J. (2007) The Loss of Sadness: How Psychiatry Transformed Normal Sorrow into Depressive Disorder (New York: Oxford University Press).
Hsieh, N. (2008) ‘Survey article: justice in production’, Journal of Political Philosophy 16(1): 72–100.Google Scholar
Hutton, W. (1995) The State We're In (London: Jonathan Cape).
Karasek, R., and Theorell, T. (1992) Healthy Work: Stress, Productivity, and the Reconstruction of Working Life (New York: Basic Books).
Kasser, T. (2003) The High Price of Materialism (Cambridge, MA: MIT Press).
Kay, J. A. (2010) Obliquity: Why Our Goals Are Best Achieved Indirectly (London: Profile Books).
Lampel, J. (2010) Model Growth: Do Employee-Owned Businesses Deliver Sustainable Performance (London: Employee Ownership Association).
Layard, R., and Clark, D. (2014) Thrive: The Power of Evidence-Based Psychological Therapies (Harmondsworth: Penguin Books).
Lazonick, W., and O'Sullivan, M. (2000) ‘Maximizing shareholder value: a new ideology for corporate governance’, Economy and Society 29(1): 13–35.Google Scholar
Matrix, (2010) The Employee Ownership Effect: A Review of the Evidence (London: Employee Ownership Association).
McQuaid, R. (2012) Fit for Work? Health and Wellbeing of Employees in Employee Owned Businesses (London: Employee Ownership Association).
Millon, D. (1990) ‘Theories of the corporation’, Duke Law Journal 39(2): 201–262.Google Scholar
Mirowski, P., and Plehwe, D. (2009) The Road from Mont Pèlerin: The Making of the Neoliberal Thought Collective (Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press).
Mizruchi, M. S. (2013) The Fracturing of the American Corporate Elite (Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press).
Moloney, P. (2013) The Therapy Industry: The Irresistible Rise of the Talking Cure, and Why It Doesn't Work (London: Pluto Press).
Oswald, A. J., Proto, E., and Sgroi, D. (2014) ‘Happiness and productivity’, 13 (108) CAGE Online Working Paper Series, University of Warwick.
Pitofsky, R. (2008) How the Chicago School Overshot the Mark: The Effect of Conservative Economic Analysis on US antitrust (Oxford: Oxford University Press).
Posner, R. A. (1976) Antitrust Law: An Economic Perspective (Chicago: University of Chicago Press).
Rapley, M. (2003) Quality of Life Research: A Critical Introduction (London: Sage).
Rapley, M., Moncrieff, J., and Dillon, J. (eds.) (2011) De-Medicalizing Misery: Psychiatry, Psychology and the Human Condition (Basingstoke, UK: Palgrave Macmillan).
Rappaport, A. (1986) Creating Shareholder Value: The New Standard for Business Performance (New York: Free Press).
Rappaport, A. (2005) ‘The economics of short-term performance obsession’, Financial Analysts Journal 61(3): 65–79.Google Scholar
Rose, N. (1996) Inventing Our Selves: Psychology, Power, and Personhood (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press).
Sennett, R. (1998) The Corrosion of Character: The Personal Consequences of Work in the New Capitalism (New York: Norton).
Streeck, W. (1998) ‘Beneficial constraints: on the economic limits of rational voluntarism’, in Hollingsworth, R. and Boyer, R. (eds.) Contemporary Capitalism: The Embeddedness of Institutions (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press), 197–219.
Tatzel, M. (2002) ‘“Money worlds” and well-being: an integration of money dispositions, materialism and price-related behavior’, Journal of Economic Psychology 23(1): 103–126.Google Scholar
Van Horn, R. (2011) ‘Chicago's shifting attitude toward concentrations of business power (1934–1962)’, Seattle University Law Review 34(4): 1527–1544.Google Scholar
White, S. (2009) ‘Revolutionary liberalism’? The philosophy and politics of ownership in the post-war Liberal party’, British Politics 4(2): 164–187, doi:10.1057/bp.2008.35.Google Scholar
Zoller, H. M. (2003) ‘Working out managerialism in workplace health promotion’, Management Communication Quarterly 17(2): 171–205.Google Scholar

Save book to Kindle

To save this book to your Kindle, first ensure coreplatform@cambridge.org is added to your Approved Personal Document E-mail List under your Personal Document Settings on the Manage Your Content and Devices page of your Amazon account. Then enter the ‘name’ part of your Kindle email address below. Find out more about saving to your Kindle.

Note you can select to save to either the @free.kindle.com or @kindle.com variations. ‘@free.kindle.com’ emails are free but can only be saved to your device when it is connected to wi-fi. ‘@kindle.com’ emails can be delivered even when you are not connected to wi-fi, but note that service fees apply.

Find out more about the Kindle Personal Document Service.

Available formats
×

Save book to Dropbox

To save content items to your account, please confirm that you agree to abide by our usage policies. If this is the first time you use this feature, you will be asked to authorise Cambridge Core to connect with your account. Find out more about saving content to Dropbox.

Available formats
×

Save book to Google Drive

To save content items to your account, please confirm that you agree to abide by our usage policies. If this is the first time you use this feature, you will be asked to authorise Cambridge Core to connect with your account. Find out more about saving content to Google Drive.

Available formats
×