Skip to main content Accessibility help
×
Hostname: page-component-77c89778f8-rkxrd Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-07-21T08:21:41.594Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

1 - An introduction to the competitive effects of branding

from PART I - Brands, price theory and business studies' perspectives

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  05 August 2015

Peter Davis
Affiliation:
Faculty of Laws, UCL.
Kirsten Edwards-Warren
Affiliation:
Compass Lexecon.
Deven R. Desai
Affiliation:
Georgia Institute of Technology
Ioannis Lianos
Affiliation:
University College London
Spencer Weber Waller
Affiliation:
Loyola University, Chicago
Get access

Summary

Brands allow businesses to reach consumers directly with messages regarding emotion, identity, and self-worth such that consumers are no longer buying a product but buying a brand.

Introduction

The purpose of this chapter is to provide a brief review of the economics of the competitive effects of branding. Since Marshall (1890, 1919), economists have thought about at least two roles that brands can play, one largely positive the other potentially negative:

  1. 1. Informing and Signalling: Brands may convey information about a product's price or quality to consumers. As such branding may involve choice of names, terms, symbols and designs which signal the quality of the goods of a particular seller and thereby attempt to differentiate them from those of its competitors. Customers may recognize a brand even when they know little about the product.

  2. 2. Persuading: Branding may seek to persuade customers to buy a product that they would not have otherwise purchased; branding may seek to create new demand.

In terms of the first role, consider, for example, an experience good, such as a new shampoo, where the quality of the product can only be observed after purchase. For such products, a brand may indicate to consumers that a new product is of high quality. Another example is provided by the franchising literature, which seeks to understand why, for example, potential entrepreneurs pay to open a Subway or McDonalds store rather than open an independent restaurant. One reason may be that the brand signals that products will satisfy a minimum quality – such minimum quality levels will be enforceable since they will form a part of the contract between franchisee and franchisor. The result is that customers know that products purchased from outlets with which they do not have experience will not be too different from the products sold by those with which they do. The brand signals a minimum quality, in this case across locations.

In terms of the second role, the potential persuasive effect of advertising has long been a source of concern to both policymakers and economists. Economists would typically welcome an outcome where a customer is persuaded of the merits of a good because it fits with her wants.

Type
Chapter
Information
Publisher: Cambridge University Press
Print publication year: 2015

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

References

Ackerberg, Daniel (2001). ‘Empirically Distinguishing Informative and Prestige Effects of Advertising’, RAND Journal of Economics 32 (2): 316–33.Google Scholar
Arrington, R. L. (1982). ‘Advertising and Behavior Control’, Journal of Business Ethics 1: 3–12.Google Scholar
Bagwell, K. (2007). ‘The Economic Analysis of Advertising’, in Schmalenssee, R., Armstrong, M. and Willig, R. D., Handbook of Industrial Organization, Amsterdam: Elsevier, Volume 3, Chapter 28.
Becker, Gary and Kevin, Murphy (1993). ‘A Simple Theory of Advertising as a Good or Bad’, The Quarterly Journal of Economics 108(4): 941–64.Google Scholar
Bronnenberg, B., Dubé, J. P., Gentzkow, M. and Shapiro, J. M. (2014). ‘Do Pharmacists Buy Bayer? Informed Shoppers and the Brand Premium’, mimeo, Chicago and NBER. Available from: http://faculty.chicagobooth.edu/jesse.shapiro/research/generics.pdf (accessed 26 April 2014).
Chamberlain, E. (1933). The Theory of Monopolistic Competition: A Re-orientation of the Theory of Value, Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press, 1965 8th edn.
Crisp, R. (1987) ‘Persuasive Advertising, Autonomy and the Creation of Desire’, Journal of Business Ethics 6(5): 413–18.Google Scholar
Desai, D. and Waller, S. Weber (2014) ‘The Competitive Significance of Brands.’ Antitrust Chronicle, Competition Policy International, July, No. 2. Available from: www.competitionpolicyinternational.com/the-competitive-significance-of-brands/.
Galbraith, J. K. (1958). The Affluent Society, Boston, MA: Houghton Mifflin.
Hotelling, H. (1929). ‘Stability in Competition’, The Economic Journal 29(153): 41–57.Google Scholar
Kaldor, N. V. (1950). ‘The Economic Aspects of Advertising’, Review of Economic Studies 18: 1–27.Google Scholar
Lafontaine, F. (1992) ‘Agency Theory and Franchising: Some Empirical ResultsRAND, 7(1): 263–83.Google Scholar
Lee, Nick, Broderick, Amanda J. and Chamberlain, Laura (2007). ‘What Is “Neuromarketing”? A Discussion and Agenda for Future Research’, International Journal of Psychophysiology 63(2): 199–204.Google Scholar
Marshall, A. (1890). Principles of Economics, London: Macmillan and Co. Ltd, London.
Marshall, A. (1919). Industry and Trade, McMillan and Co. Ltd, London.
Mathewson, G. F. and Winter, R. A. (1985). ‘The Economics of Franchise Contracts’, Journal of Law and Economics 28(3): 503–26.Google Scholar
Milgrom, Paul and Roberts, John (1986). ‘Price and Advertising Signals of Product Quality’, Journal of Political Economy 94(4): 796–821.Google Scholar
Milyo, Jeffrey and Waldfogel, Joel (1999). ‘The Effect of Price Advertising on Prices: Evidence in the Wake of 44 Liquormart’, The American Economic Review 89(5): 1081–96.Google Scholar
Nelson, Phillip (1974). ‘Advertising as Information’, Journal of Political Economy 82(4): 729–54.Google Scholar
Stigler, George (1961). ‘The Economics of Information’, Journal of Political Economy 69(3): 213–25.Google Scholar
Stigler, George and Becker, Gary (1977). ‘De Gustibus Non Est Disputandum’, The American Economic Review 67(2): 76–90.Google Scholar
Telser, L. (1964). ‘Advertising and Competition’, The Journal of Political Economy, 76(6): 537–62.Google Scholar
Veblen, T. B. (1899). The Theory of the Leisure Class. An Economic Study of Institutions, London: Macmillan Publishers.

Save book to Kindle

To save this book to your Kindle, first ensure coreplatform@cambridge.org is added to your Approved Personal Document E-mail List under your Personal Document Settings on the Manage Your Content and Devices page of your Amazon account. Then enter the ‘name’ part of your Kindle email address below. Find out more about saving to your Kindle.

Note you can select to save to either the @free.kindle.com or @kindle.com variations. ‘@free.kindle.com’ emails are free but can only be saved to your device when it is connected to wi-fi. ‘@kindle.com’ emails can be delivered even when you are not connected to wi-fi, but note that service fees apply.

Find out more about the Kindle Personal Document Service.

Available formats
×

Save book to Dropbox

To save content items to your account, please confirm that you agree to abide by our usage policies. If this is the first time you use this feature, you will be asked to authorise Cambridge Core to connect with your account. Find out more about saving content to Dropbox.

Available formats
×

Save book to Google Drive

To save content items to your account, please confirm that you agree to abide by our usage policies. If this is the first time you use this feature, you will be asked to authorise Cambridge Core to connect with your account. Find out more about saving content to Google Drive.

Available formats
×