Skip to main content Accessibility help
×
Hostname: page-component-78c5997874-m6dg7 Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-11-05T14:23:24.910Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

References

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  05 August 2015

Megumi Naoi
Affiliation:
University of California, San Diego
Get access

Summary

Image of the first page of this content. For PDF version, please use the ‘Save PDF’ preceeding this image.'
Type
Chapter
Information
Building Legislative Coalitions for Free Trade in Asia
Globalization as Legislation
, pp. 191 - 206
Publisher: Cambridge University Press
Print publication year: 2015

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

References

Acemoglu, Daron, and Robinson, James. 2001. “Inefficient Redistribution.” American Political Science Review. 95(3): 649–661.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Akaneya, Tatsuo. 1992. Nihon no gatto kanyu mondai – rejium riron no bunseki shikaku ni yoru jirei kenyu [Japan’s Accession to GATT: Case Study from a Regime Theory Perspective]. Tokyo: University of Tokyo Press.Google Scholar
Albritton, Robert B., and Bureekul, Thawilwadee. 2008. “Developing Democracy under a New Constitution in Thailand.” In How East Asians View Democracy, ed. Zhu, Yuhan, 114138. New York: Columbia University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Amiti, Mary. 1998. “New Trade Theories and Industrial Location in the EU: A Survey of Evidence.” Oxford Review of Economic Policy 14(2): 4553.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Anantarangsi, S., and Walsh, J. 2012. “Income Distribution and Mobility in Thailand: The Perceptions of Migrant Workers in Bangkok and Vicinity.” NIDA Development Journal 49(2): 5178.Google Scholar
Anderson, Kym and Valenzuela, Ernesto. 2011. Estimates of Global Distortions to Agricultural Incentives, 1955 to 2011. Washington, DC: World Bank. June 2013.Google Scholar
Angrist, Joshua D., and Pischke, Jörn-Steffen. 2008. Mostly Harmless Econometrics: An Empiricist’s Companion. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Aramaki, Kenji. 2004. “Shihon torihiki jiyuuka heno siikuensingu: nihon no keiken to chugoku heno shisa.” Kaihatsu Kinnyu Kenkyu-sho hou 21: 4977. Japan Bank for International Cooperation.Google Scholar
Arghiros, Daniel. 1992. “Local-level Electoral Politics and Rural Change in Thailand.” Paper presented at the Annual Conference of the Association of South-East Asian Studies, April 8–10, 1992, at the School of Oriental and African Studies (SOAS), London.Google Scholar
Arghiros, Daniel. 2001. Democracy, Development and Decentralization in Provincial Thailand. Democracy in Asia No. 8. New York: Psychology Press.Google Scholar
Ariga, Kenichi, and Shinya, Ejima. 2000. “Tai oukoku ‘Toubu rinkai kaihatsu keikaku sougou innpakuto hyouka’ (En-shakkan jigyo jigo hyouka)”, Kaihatsu Kinnyu Kenkyu-sho hou 2: 81115. Japan Bank for International Cooperation.Google Scholar
Bailey, Michael A., Goldstein, Judith, and Weingast, Barry R.. 1997. “The Institutional Roots of American Trade Policy: Politics, Coalitions, and International Trade.” World Politics 49(3): 309338.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bailey, Michael, and Brady, David W.. 1998. “Heterogeneity and Representation: The Senate and Free Trade.” American Journal of Political Science 42 (2):524544.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Baldwin, Richard E., and Robert-Nicoud, Frédéric. 2007. “Entry and Asymmetric Lobbying: Why Governments Pick Losers.” Journal of the European Economic Association 5(5): 10641093.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Baldwin, Richard E., and Okubo, T. 2006. “Heterogeneous Firms, Agglomeration and Economic Geography: Spatial Selection and Sorting.” Journal of Economic Geography 6(3): 323346.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Baldwin, Richard E. 2010. Unilateral Tariff Liberalisation. Working Paper w16600. Cambridge, MA: National Bureau of Economic Research.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Baldwin, Robert E. 1985. The Political Economy of U.S. Import Policy. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.Google Scholar
Baldwin, Robert E. 1989. “The Political Economy of Trade Policy: Integrating the Perspectives of Economists and Political Scientists.” Journal of Economic Perspectives 3 (4):119135.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Baldwin, Robert E., and Magee, Christopher S.. 2000. Congressional Trade Votes. Washington, DC: Institute for International Economics.Google Scholar
Bates, Robert H 1981. Markets and States in Tropical Africa. Berkeley: University of California Press.Google Scholar
Bawn, Kathleen, and Rosenbluth, Frances. 2006. “Short versus Long Coalitions: Electoral Accountability and the Size of the Public Sector.” American Journal of Political Science 50(2): 251265.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bawn, Kathleen, and Thies, Michael F.. 2003. “A Comparative Theory of Electoral Incentives Representing the Unorganized under PR, Plurality and Mixed-Member Electoral Systems.” Journal of Theoretical Politics 15(1): 532.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Beck, Nathaniel, and Katz, Jonathan N.. 1995. “What To Do (and Not To Do) with Time-Series–Cross-Section Data in Comparative Politics.” American Political Science Review 89:634647.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bhagwati, Jagdish, and Ramaswami, Vangal K.. 1963. “Domestic Distortions, Tariffs and the Theory of Optimum Subsidy.” The Journal of Political Economy 71(1):4450.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bowie, Alasdair, Unger, Danny, and Unger, Daniel. 1997. The Politics of Open Economies: Indonesia, Malaysia, the Philippines, and Thailand. Vol. 4. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Broz, Lawrence J. 2005. ‘‘Congressional Politics of International Financial Rescues.’’ American Journal of Political Science 49(3): 479496.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Busch, Marc L., and Erik R., Reinhardt 2000. “Geography, International Trade, and Political Mobilization in US Industries.” American Journal of Political Science 44(4): 703719.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Calder, Kent E. 1988. Crisis and Compensation: Public Policy and Political Stability in Japan, 1949–1986. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Calder, Kent E. 1989. International Pressure and Domestic Policy Response: Japanese Informatics Policy in the 1980s. Princeton, NJ: Center for International Studies Woodrow Wilson School of Public and International Affairs, Princeton University.Google Scholar
Callahan, William A. 2005. “The Discourse of Vote Buying and Political Reform in Thailand.” Pacific Affairs 78(1): 95113.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Calvo, Ernesto, and Gibson, Edward. 2000. “Federalism and Low-Maintenance Constituencies: Territorial Dimensions of Economic Reform in Argentina.” Studies in Comparative International Development 35(3): 32–55.Google Scholar
Cameron, David R. 1978. “The Expansion of the Public Economy: A Comparative Analysis.” The American Political Science Review 72(4):12431261.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Campbell, John Creighton. 1977. Contemporary Japanese Budget Politics. Berkeley: University of California Press.Google Scholar
Campbell, John Creighton. 1980. Contemporary Japanese Budget Politics. Vol. 25. Berkeley: University of California Press.Google Scholar
Chambers, Paul. 2008. “Factions, Parties and the Durability of Parliaments, Coalitions and Cabinets the Case of Thailand (1979–2001).” Party Politics 14(3): 299323.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Christensen, Scott R. 1992. “The Public Policy Process and Political Change in Thailand: A Summary of Observations.” TDRI Quarterly Review 7(1): 2126.Google Scholar
Chusho Kigyo Sougou Jigyo Dan. 2001. Sanchi Kasseika Chosa Kenkyu Bunseki Houkokusho: Koraboreeishon no jittai to kanousei ni tsuite [Report on Investigation and Research on the Revitalization of Industrial Regions]. Available at: http://www.smrj.go.jp/keiei/dbps_data/_material_/common/chushou/b_keiei/keieiseni/pdf/sanchi01.pdf (Accessed January 7, 2015).Google Scholar
Connors, Michael Kelly 1999. Political Reform and the State in Thailand. Journal of Contemporary Asia 29(2): 202226.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Cox, Gary W. 1987. The Efficient Secret: The Cabinet and the Development of Political Parties in Victorian England. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Cox, Gary W. 1990. “Centripetal and Centrifugal Incentives in Electoral Systems.” American Journal of Political Science 34(4): 903935.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Cox, Gary W. 1996. “Is the Single Nontransferable Vote Superproportional? Evidence from Japan and Taiwan.” American Journal of Political Science 40(3): 740755.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Cox, Gary W. 2009.“13 Swing Voters, Core Voters, and Distributive Politics.” In Political Representation, ed. Shapiro, Ian, Stokes, Susan, Wood, Elisabeth, and Kirshner, Alexander S.. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Cox, Gary W., and McCubbins, Mathew D.. 1986. “Electoral Politics as a Redistributive Game.” The Journal of Politics 48(2): 370389.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Cox, Gary W., and Niou, Emerson. 1994. “Seat Bonuses under the Single Nontransferable Vote System: Evidence from Japan and Taiwan.” Comparative Politics 26(2): 221236.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Cox, Gary W., and Rosenbluth, Frances. 1993. “The Electoral Fortunes of Legislative Factions in Japan.” American Political Science Review 87 (3): 577589.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Cox, Gary W., Rosenbluth, Frances M., and Thies, Michael F.. 2000. “Electoral Rules, Career Ambitions, and Party Structure: Comparing Factions in Japan’s Upper and Lower Houses.” American Journal of Political Science 44(1): 115122.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Cox, Gary W., and Thies, Michael F.. 2000. “How Much Does Money Matter? “Buying” Votes in Japan, 1967–1990.” Comparative Political Studies 33(1): 3757.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Curtis, Gerald L. 1971. Election Campaigning Japanese Style. New York: Columbia University Press.Google Scholar
Curtis, Gerald. 1988. The Japanese Way of Politics. New York: Columbia University Press.Google Scholar
Curtis, Gerald. 1999. Logic of Japanese Politics. New York: Columbia University Press.Google Scholar
Curtis, Gerald L., and Masumi, Ishiwaka. 1983. Doken Kokka Nippon: Sekai no yutosei no tsuyomi to yowami [Construction State, Japan: Strengths and Weaknesses of the World’s “Honor student”]. Tokyo: Kobunsha.Google Scholar
Davis, Christina L. 2003. Food Fights over Free Trade: How International Institutions Promote Agricultural Trade Liberalization. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Destler, Irving M., Fukui, Haruhiko, and Sato, Hideo. 1979. The Textile Wrangle: Conflict in Japanese-American Relations, 1969–1971. Ithaca, NY: Cornell University Press.Google Scholar
Devarajan, Shantayanan and Sussangkarn, Chalongphob. 1992. “Effective Rates of Protection when Domestic and Foreign Goods are Imperfect Substitutes: The Case of Thailand.” The Review of Economics and Statistics 74 (4): 701711CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Diermeier, Daniel, and Feddersen, Timothy J.. 1998. “Cohesion in Legislatures and the Vote of Confidence Procedure.” American Political Science Review 92(3): 611621.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Doi, Takero. 2000. Chihou zaisei no seijikeizaigaku. Tokyo: Touyou Keizai Shinposha.Google Scholar
Doi, Takero, and Masahiro, Ashiya. 1997. “Kokko shishitsukin bunpai to seiken yotou no kankei.” Nihon Keizai Kenkyu 34: 180195.Google Scholar
Doner, Richard F., and Laothamatas, Anek. 1994. “Thailand: Economic and Political Gradualism.” Voting for Reform: Democracy, Political Liberalization, and Economic Adjustment 411452.Google Scholar
Doner, Richard F., and Ramsay, A. 2000. “Rent-Seeking and Economic Development in Thailand.” In Rents, Rent-Seeking and Economic Development: Theory and Evidence in Asia, ed. Khan, Mushtaq H. and Sundaram, Jomo Kwame, 145181. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Duch, Raymond M., and Stevenson, Randolph T.. 2008. “The Economic Vote: How Political and Economic Institutions Condition Election Results, Political Economy of Institutions and Decisions. New York: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ebrill, Liam P., Stotsky, Janet Gale, and Gropp, Reint. 1999. Revenue Implications of Trade Liberalization. Occasional Paper 180. Washington, DC: International Monetary Fund.Google Scholar
Eda, Satsuki. 1991. Kokkai giin: Wakaru seiji he no hasshin. Tokyo: Koudansha.Google Scholar
Epstein, David, Brady, David, Kawato, Sadafumi, and O’Halloran, Sharyn. 1997. “A Comparative Approach to Legislative Organization: Careerism and Seniority in the United States and Japan.” American Journal of Political Science 41(3): 965998.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Esping-Andersen, Gosta. 1990. The Three Worlds of Welfare Capitalism. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Estevez-Abe, Margarita. 2008. Welfare and Capitalism in Postwar Japan: Party, Bureaucracy, and Business. New York: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Evans, Diana. 1994. “Policy and Pork: The Use of Pork Barrel Projects to Build Policy Coalitions in the House of Representatives.” American Journal of Political Science 38(4): 894917.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Evans, Diana. 2004. Greasing the Wheels: Using Pork Barrel Projects to Build Majority Coalitions in Congress. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Frieden, Jeffry A. 1991. “Invested Interests: The Politics of National Economic Policies in a World of Global Finance.” International Organization 45(4): 425454.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Friman, H. Richard. 1993. “Side-Payments versus Security Cards: Domestic Bargaining Tactics in International Economic Negotiations.” International Organization 47(3): 387410.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Fujii, Nobuyuki. 2004. Chiiki kaihatsu no raireki: Taiheiyo beruto chitai kousou no seiritsu [History of Regional Development: Establishment of Asian-Pacific Belt Plan]. Tokyo: Nihon Keizai Hyoronsha.Google Scholar
Fujita, Masahisa 1988. “A Monopolistic Competition Model of Spatial Agglomeration: Differentiated Product Approach.” Regional Science and Urban Economics 18: 87124.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Fukao, Kyoji, and Ximin, Yue. 2000. Sengo nihon kokunai ni okeru keizai syusoku to seisan yoso tounyu –soroo seicho moderu ha tekiyou dekiruka. Keizai Kenkyu 51(2): 136151.Google Scholar
Fukumoto, Kentaro. 2000. Nihon no kokkai seiji: zen-seifu rippou-hou no bunseki [Parliamentary Politics Japan: Analysis of All Legislations]. Tokyo: Tokyo University Press.Google Scholar
Gandhi, Jennifer, and Przeworski, Adam. 2007. “Authoritarian Institutions and the Survival of Autocrats.” Comparative Political Studies 40(11): 12791301.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Garrett, Geoffrey. 1998. Partisan Politics in Global Economy. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Gibson, Edward L., and Calvo, Ernesto. 2000. “Federalism and Low-Maintenance Constituencies: Territorial Dimensions of Economic Reform in Argentina.” Studies in Comparative International Development 35(3): 3255.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Gilligan, Michael, Alt, James, and Rogowski, Ron. 1994. “The Political Economy of Trading States: Factor Specificity, Collective Action Problems and Domestic Political Institutions.” Journal of Political Philosophy 2(2): 165192.Google Scholar
Gilligan, Michael J. 1997. Empowering Exporters: Reciprocity, Delegation, and Collective Action in American Trade Policy. Ann Arbor: Michigan University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Goldstein, Judith. 1986. “The Political Economy of Trade: Institutions of Protection.” The American Political Science Review 80(1): 161184.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Goldstein, Judith. 1988. “Ideas, Institutions, and American Trade Policy.” International Organization 42 (1, The State and American Foreign Economic Policy): 179217.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Goldstein, Judith. 1996. “International Law and Domestic Institutions: Reconciling North American “Unfair” Trade Laws.” International Organization 50(4): 541564.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Goldstein, Judith, and Martin, Lisa L.. 2000. “Legalization, Trade Liberalization, and Domestic Politics: A Cautionary Note.” International Organization 54(3): 603632.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Goldstein, Judith L., Rivers, Douglas, and Tomz, Michael. 2007. “Institutions in International Relations: Understanding the Effects of the GATT and the WTO on World Trade.” International Organization 61(1): 3767.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Gourevitch, Peter Alexis. 1977. “International Trade, Domestic Coalitions, and Liberty: Comparative Responses to the Crisis of 1873–1896.” Journal of Interdisciplinary History 8(2): 281313.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Gourevitch, Peter Alexis. 1986. Politics in Hard Times: Comparative Responses to International Economic Crises. Ithaca, NY: Cornell University Press.Google Scholar
Grossman, Gene M., and Helpman, Elhanan. 1994. “Protection for Sale.” The American Economic Review 84(4): 833850.Google Scholar
Guisinger, Alexandra. 2009. “Determining Trade Policy: Do Voters Hold Politicians Accountable?International Organization 63(3): 533557.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Haggard, Stephan. 2000. The Political Economy of the Asian Financial Crisis. Washington, DC: Peterson Institute.Google Scholar
Haggard, Stephan, and Kaufman, Robert R.. 1992. The Politics of Economic Adjustment. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Haggard, Stephan, and Kaufman, Robert R.. 1995. The Political Economy of Democratic Transitions. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Haggard, Stephan, and Kaufman, Robert R.. 2008. Development, Democracy, and Welfare States: Latin America, East Asia, and Eastern Europe. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Haggard, Stephan, and Moon, Chung-in. 1995. “The South Korean State in the International Economy: Liberal, Dependent, or Mercantile?” In The Antinomies of Interdependence: National Welfare and the International Division of Labor, ed. Ruggie, J. G., 131189. New York: Columbia University Press.Google Scholar
Haggard, Stephan, and Webb, Michael. 1994. Voting for Reforms. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Hallerberg, Mark, and Marier, Patrik. 2004. “Executive Authority, the Personal Vote, and Budget Discipline in Latin American and Caribbean Countries.” American Journal of Political Science 48(3): 571587.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Head, Keith, and Mayer, Thierry. 2004. “The Empirics of Agglomeration and Trade.” Handbook of Regional and Urban Economics 4: 26092669.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hewison, Kevin, and Thongyou, Maniemai. 2000. “Developing Provincial Capitalism: A Profile of the Economic and Political Roles of a New Generation in Kohn Kaen, Thailand.” In Money and Power in Provincial Thailand, ed. McVey, Ruth T., 195–220. Copenhagen: NIAS Press.Google Scholar
Hicken, Allen D. 2002. “From Phitsanulok to Parliament: Multiple Parties in Pre-1997 Thailand.” In Thailand’s New Politics: KPI Yearbook 2001. Nonthaburi and Bangkok: King Prajadhipok’s Institute and White Lotus PressGoogle Scholar
Hicken, Allen D. 2004. “The Politics of Economic Reform in Thailand: Crisis and Compromise (January 2004).” William Davidson Institute Working Paper No. 638.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hicken, Allen D. 2008. “How Do Rules and Institutions Encourage Vote Buying?” In Elections for Sale: The Causes and Consequences of Vote Buying, ed. Scaffer, Charles Frederic, 47–60. Manila: Ateneo de Manila University Press.Google Scholar
Hicken, Allen D. 2006. “Party Fabrication: Constitutional Reform and the Rise of Thai Rak Thai.” Journal of East Asian Studies 6(3): 381407.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hicken, A. 2009. Building Party Systems in Developing Democracies. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hillman, Arye L. 1982. “Declining Industries and Political-Support Protectionist Motives.” The American Economic Review 72(5): 11801187.Google Scholar
Hirano, Shigeo. 2006. “Electoral Institutions, Hometowns, and Favored Minorities: Evidence from Japanese Electoral Reforms.” World Politics 59(1): 5182.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hirschman, Albert O. 1970. Exit, Voice, and Loyalty; Responses to Decline in Firms, Organizations, and States. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.Google Scholar
Hiscox, Michael J. 1999. “The Magic Bullet? The RTAA, Institutional Reform, and Trade Liberalization.” International Organization 53(4): 669698.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hiscox, Michael J. 2001. “Class versus Industry Cleavages: Inter-Industry Factor Mobility and the Politics of Trade.” International Organization 55(1): 146.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hiscox, Michael J. 2002. International Trade and Political Conflict. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Horiuchi, Yusaku, and Saito, Jun. 2003. “Reapportionment and Redistribution: Consequences of Electoral Reform in Japan.” American Journal of Political Science 47(4): 669682.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Huber, John D. 1996. “The Vote of Confidence in Parliamentary Democracies.” American Political Science Review 90(2): 269282.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ihori, Toshihiro, and Doi, Takero. 2000. Zaisei Dokuhon [Readers on Finance]. Tokyo: Toyo Keizai Shinpo.Google Scholar
Imaizumi, Shinya. 2012. “Rippou no seido to doutai.” In Tai no rippou katei: kokumin no seiji sanka he no mosaku [Law-Making Process in Thailand]. Kenkyu Sousho. No. 61.Google Scholar
Inoguchi, Takashi, and Iwai, Tomoaki. 1987. “Zokugiin” no kenkyū: Jimintō seiken o gyūjiru shuyaku-tachi. [Study on ‘Policy Tribe Politicians’: The Leaders Who Control the LDP]. Tokyo: Nihon Keizai Shinbunsha.Google Scholar
Institute for Democracy and Electoral Assistance. 2014. “Voter Turnout Data for Thailand.” Available at: http://www.idea.int/vt/countryview.cfm?CountryCode=TH (Accessed June 17, 2014).Google Scholar
Irwin, Douglas A., and Randall S., Kroszner. 1999. “Interests, Institutions, and Ideology in Securing Policy Change: The Republican Conversion to Trade Liberalization after Smoot-Hawley.” The Journal of Law and Economics 42(2): 643674.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Isaacs, Bronwyn Alison. 2009. “Imagining Thailand in European Hypermarkets: New Class-Based Consumption in Chiang Mai’s ‘Cruise Ships’.” The Asia Pacific Journal of Anthropology 10(4): 348363.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ishikawa, Masumi, and Hirose, Michisada. 1989. Jiminto: Choki shihai no kozo [The LDP: The Structure of Long-term Dominance]. Tokyo: Iwanami Shoten.Google Scholar
Iversen, Torben, Cusack, Tom, and Soskice, David. 2007. “Economic Interests and the Origins of Electoral Systems.” American Political Science Review 101(August): 373391.Google Scholar
Iwai, Tomoaki. 1990. Seiji shikin no kenkyu: Rieki yuudou no seiji fuudo. Tokyo: Nihon Keizai Shimbunsha.Google Scholar
Johnson, Chalmers. 1982. MITI and the Japanese Miracle: The Growth of Industrial Policy: 1925–1975. Stanford: Stanford University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Johnson, Harry G. 1965. “An Economic Theory of Protectionism, Tariff Bargaining, and the Formation of Customs Unions.” The Journal of Political Economy 73(3): 256283.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Jongwanich, Juthahip, and Kohpaiboon, Archanun. 2007. “Determinants of Protection in Thai Manufacturing.” Economic Papers 26(3): 276294.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Jun, Saito. 2009. “Infrastructure as the Magnet of Power: Explaining Why Japanese Legislators Left and Returned to the LDP.” Journal of East Asian Studies 9(3): 467493.Google Scholar
Kabashima, Ikuo. 2000. “Chihou no oukoku to toshi no hanran [Kingdom of the rural, rebellion of the city].” Chuo Kouron (September): 130143.Google Scholar
Kahler, Miles, and Lake, David, eds. 2003. Governance in a Global Economy: Political Authority in Transition. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Kajisa, Kei, and Akiyama, Takamasa 2005. “The Evolution of Rice Price Policies over Four Decades: Thailand, Indonesia and the Philippines.” Oxford Development Studies 33(2): 305329.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kanchoochat, Veerayooth. 2008. “Services, Servility and Survival: The Accommodation of Big Retail.” In Thai Capital after the 1997 Crisis, ed. Phongpaichit, Pasuk and Baker, Chris, 85104. Chiangmai: Silkworm Books.Google Scholar
Kato, Junko. 1998. “When the Party Breaks Up: Exit and Voice among Japanese Legislators.” American Political Science Review 92(4): 857870.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Katzenstein, Peter. 1985. Small States in World Economy. Ithaca, NY: Cornell University Press.Google Scholar
Kaufman, Robert, and Segura-Ubiergo, Alex. 2001. “Globalization, Domestic Politics, and Social Spending in Latin America: A Time-Series Cross-Section Analysis, 1973–1997.” World Politics 53(4): 553587.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kawato, Sadafumi. 1996a. Jimintou ni okeru yakushoku jinji no seidoka. Hougaku 59(6): 933957.Google Scholar
Kawato, Sadafumi. 1996b. Shinioriti ruuru to habatsu: Jimintou ni okeru jinji haibun no henka [Seniority Rule and Factions: Changing Personnel Appointment Allocations in the LDP]. Leviathan, Special Winter Issue.Google Scholar
Kawato, Sadafumi. 2004. Senkyo seido to seitou sisutemu [Electoral Institutions and Party Systems]. Tokyo: Bokutakusha.Google Scholar
Kawato, Sadafumi. 2005. Nihon no kokkai seido to seitou seiji. Tokyo: University of Tokyo Press.Google Scholar
Keefer, Philip, and Vlaicu, Razvan. 2008. “Democracy, Credibility, and Clientelism.” Journal of Law, Economics, and Organization 24(2): 371406.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Keele, Luke, and Kelly, Nathan J.. 2006. “Dynamic Models for Dynamic Theories: The Ins and Outs of Lagged Dependent Variables.” Political Analysis 14(2): 186205.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Keen, Michael, and Baunsgaard, Thomas. 2005. Tax Revenue and (or?) Trade Liberalization. Washington, DC: International Monetary FundCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Keohane, Robert O., and Milner, Helen V.. 1996. Internationalization and Domestic Politics. Cambridge and New York: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kim, Sukkoo. 1995. “Expansion of Markets and the Geographic Distribution of Economic Activities: The Trends in US Regional Manufacturing Structure, 1860–1987.” The Quarterly Journal of Economics 110(4): 881908.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kohno, Masaru. 1997. Japan’s Postwar Party Politics, 108–109. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kohno, Masaru, and Nishizawa, Yoshitaka. 1990. “A Study of the Electoral Business Cycle in Japan: Elections and Government Spending on Public Construction.” Comparative Politics 22(2): 151166.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kollman, Ken, Hicken, Allen, Caramani, Daniele, Backer, David, and Lublin, David. 2012. Constituency-Level Elections Archive. Produced and distributed by Ann Arbor: Center for Political Studies, University of Michigan.Google Scholar
Kondo, Makoto. 2010. Sekiyu kiki go no keizai kouzou chosei to guroobarizeishon he no taiou [Adjusting Economic Structure and Responding to Globalization After the Energy Crises]” In Nihon keizai no kiroku – Dainiji sekiyu kiki he no taiou kara baburu houkai made, ed. Masao, Komine. Cabinet Office, Economic and Social Research Institute. Available at: http://www.esri.go.jp/jp/prj/sbubble/history/history_01/history_01.html (Accessed March 4, 2015).Google Scholar
Kovak, Brian K. 2013. “Regional Effects of Trade Reform: What Is the Correct Measure of Liberalization?The American Economic Review 103(5): 19601976.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Krauss, Ellis S., and Pekkanen, Robert. 2004. “Explaining Party Adaptation to Electoral Reform: The Discreet Charm of the LDP?The Journal of Japanese Studies 30(1): 134.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Krauss, Ellis S. 2010. “The Rise and Fall of Japan’s Liberal Democratic Party.” The Journal of Asian Studies 69(1): 515.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Krueger, Anne O. 1974. “The Political Economy of the Rent-Seeking Society.” The American Economic Review 64(3): 291303.Google Scholar
Krugman, Paul. 1991a. “Increasing Returns and Economic Geography.” Journal of Political Economy 99: 483499.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Krugman, Paul. 1991b. Geography and Trade. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.Google Scholar
Krugman, Paul, Obstfeld, Maurice, and Melitz, Marc J.. 2011. International Economics: Theory and Policy, 9th ed. Upper Saddle River, NJ: Prentice Hall.Google Scholar
Kume, Ikuo. 1998. Disparaged Success: Labor Politics in Post-War Japan. Ithaca, NY: Cornell University Press.Google Scholar
Kuno, A. 2006. “An Evaluation of Japan’s First Safeguards Actions.” The World Economy 29(6): 763782.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Laakso, Markku, and Taagepera, Rein. 1979. “Effective Number of Parties: A Measure with Application to West Europe.” Comparative Political Studies 12(1): 327.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Laothamatas, Anek. 1988. “Business and Politics in Thailand: New Patterns of Influence.” Asian Survey 28(4): 451470.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Laothamatas, Anek. 1992. Business Associations and the New Political Economy in Thailand: From Bureaucratic Polity to Liberal Corporatism. Studies of the East Asian Institutes. Boulder, CO: Westview Press.Google Scholar
Laothamatas, Anek. 1996. “A Tale of Two Democracies: Conflicting Perceptions of Elections and Democracy in Thailand.” In Politics of Elections in Southeast Asia, ed. Taylor, R. H., 201–223. Cambridge, New York, and Melbourne: Woodrow Wilson Center Press and Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Lauridsen, Laurids S. 1998. “The Financial Crisis in Thailand: Causes, Conduct and Consequences?World Development 26(8): 15751591.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lawrence, Robert Z., and Weinstein, David E.. 2001. “Trade and Growth: Import-Led or Export-Led? Evidence from Japan and Korea.” In Rethinking the East Asian Miracle, ed., Stiglitz, Joseph E. and Yusuf, Shahid, 379–408. Washington, DC: World Bank Publications.Google Scholar
Lee, Eddy. 1998. The Asian Financial Crisis: The Challenge for Social Policy. Geneva, Switzerland: International Labour Organization.Google Scholar
Liberal Democratic Party. 1987. Jiyuu minshutou tou shi [The History of the Liberal Democratic Party]. Tokyo: Shiryohen.Google Scholar
Limmanee, Anusorn. 1999. Political Business Cycle in Thailand, 1979–1992: General Election and Currency in Circulation. Research Report Submitted to the Institute of Thai Studies. Bangkok: Chulalongkorn University Press.Google Scholar
Magee, Stephen. 1980. “Three Simple Tests of the Stolper-Samuelson theorem.” In Issues in International Economics, ed. Oppenheimer, P., 138153. London: Oriel.Google Scholar
Magee, Stephen, Brock, William, and Young, L. 1989. Black Hole Tariffs and Endogenous Policy Theory. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Mano, Yukichi, and Otsuka, Keijiro. 2000. “Agglomeration Economies and Geographical Concentration of Industries: A Case Study of Manufacturing Sectors in Postwar Japan.” Journal of the Japanese and International Economies 14(3): 189203.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Mansfield, Edward D., and Mutz, Diana C.. 2009. “Support for Free Trade: Self-interest, Sociotropic Politics, and Out-Group Anxiety.” International Organization 63(3): 425457.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Mansfield, Edward D., Milner, Helen V., and Rosendorff, B. Peter. 2000. “Free to Trade: Democracies, Autocracies, and International Trade.” American Political Science Review 94(2): 305321.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Mares, Isabela. 2003. Politics of Social Risk: Business and Welfare State Development. Cambridge and New York: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Martin, Will, and Ng, Francis. 2004. “A Note on Sources of Tariff Reductions in Developing Countries, 1983–2003.” Background paper for Global Economic Prospects 2005 – Trade Regionalism, and Development, Washington, DC: World Bank.Google Scholar
Masuyama, Mikitaka. 2003. Gikai seido to nihon seiji: Giji unei no keiryo seijigaku. Tokyo: Bokutakusha.Google Scholar
Mayer, Frederick W. 1992. “Managing Domestic Differences in International Negotiations: The Strategic Use of Internal Side-Payments.” International Organization 46(4): 793818.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Mayer, Wolfgang. 1984. “Endogenous Tariff Formation.” The American Economic Review 74(5): 970985.Google Scholar
Mayhew, David R. 1974. Congress: The Electoral Connection. New Haven, CT: Yale University Press.Google Scholar
McCargo, Duncan, and Pathmanand, Ukrist. 2005. The Thaksinization of Thailand (NIAS Studies in Contemporary Asian History, Vol. 4). Copenhagen: NIAS Press.Google Scholar
McCarty, Nolan, and Rothenberg, Lawrence S.. 1996. “Commitment and the Campaign Contribution Contract.” American Journal of Political Science 40(3): 872904.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
McCubbins, Mathew D., and Noble, Gregory. 1995. “The Appearance of Power: Legislators, bureaucrats, and the budget process in the United States and Japan.” In Structure and Policy in Japan and the United States, ed. Cowhey, P. F. and McCubbins, M. D.. Cambridge and New York: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
McCubbins, Mathew D., and Thies, Michael F.. 1997. “As a Matter of Factions: The Budgetary Implications of Shifting Factional Control in Japan’s LDP.” Legislative Studies Quarterly 22(3): 293328.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
McElwain, Kenneth Mori. 2008. “Manipulating Electoral Rules to Manufacture Single-Party Dominance.” American Journal of Political Science 52(1): 3247.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
McGillivray, Fiona. Privileging Industries: The Comparative Politics of Trade and Industrial Policy. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University PressGoogle Scholar
McGillivray, Fiona. 1997. “Party Discipline as a Determinant of the Endogenous Formation of Tariffs.” American Journal of Political Science 41(2): 584607.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
McKean, Margaret, and Scheiner, Ethan. 2000. “Japan’s New Electoral System: la plus ça change…Electoral Studies 19(4): 447477.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
McKinsey Global Institute. 1999. MGI Thailand Report: Retail Trade.Google Scholar
McVey, Ruth, ed. 2000. Money and Power in Provincial Thailand. Singapore: Institute of Southeast Asian Studies.Google Scholar
Melitz, Marc J. 2003. “The Impact of Trade on Intra-industry Reallocations and Aggregate Industry Productivity.” Econometrica 71(6): 16951725.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Michio, Muramatsu. 1988. Chihou Jichi [Local Governance]. Tokyo: Tokyo Daigaku Shuppankai.Google Scholar
Milner, Helen V. 1988. Resisting Protectionism: Global Industries and the Politics of International Trade. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Milner, Helen V. 1999. “The Political Economy of International Trade.” Annual Review of Political Science 2(1): 91114.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Milner, Helen V., and Tingley, Dustin H.. 2011. “Who Supports Global Economic Engagement? The Sources of Preferences in American Foreign Economic Policy.” International Organization 65(1): 3768.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Milner, Helen V., and Keiko, Kubota. 2005. “Why the Move to Free Trade? Democracy and Trade Policy in the Developing Countries.” International Organization 59(01): 107143.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Minesaki, Jun. 2003. “Nihon no doboku wo aruku: Atte atarimae no Tokyo-wan oudan douro.” Kensetu Gyokai. Available at: http://www.nikkenren.com/archives/doboku/ce/kikanshi0303/aruku1.htm (Accessed April 30, 2014).Google Scholar
Ministry of Agriculture, Forestry and Fisheries. 2001a. Yasai shukka toukei [Statistics on Vegetable Shipment]Google Scholar
Ministry of Agriculture, Forestry and Fisheries. 2001b. Yasai tou no seifu gaado wo meguru joukyo. Available at: http://www.maff.go.jp/j/council/seisaku/kikaku/bukai/01/pdf/h131219_01_07_siryo.pdf (Accessed March 4, 2015).Google Scholar
Ministry of Finance, Zaisei Kin-yu Toukei Geppou [Monthly Reports on Fiscal and Finance Statistics], various years.Google Scholar
Ministry of Health, Welfare and Labor. 2011. “Jidai no niizu ni taiou shita shakai hosyo seido no hatten wo furikaeru. [Looking Back on the Development of Social Security System Corresponding to the Social Needs]” Section I of Heisei 23nen do ban Kousei Roudou Hakusho (Heisei 23 Health, Welfare and Labor White Paper).Google Scholar
Ministry of International Trade and Industry. 1968. Senshinkokukan keizai seisaku mondai. In White Paper on Commerce, [Issues Related to Economic Relations among Advanced Industrialized Nations].Google Scholar
Ministry of International Trade and Industry 1991. Tsusho sangyou seisaku shi. Vol. 8: Period of High Economic Growth. Tokyo: MITI Research Committee.Google Scholar
Ministry of International Trade and Industry 1994. “Oiru shokku to shigen enerugii seisaku.” In Tsuusho Sangyo Seisaku shi, Vol. 13, ed. Toshimitsu Imuta.Google Scholar
Miyamoto, Taro. 2008. Fukushi seiji: Nihon no seikatsu hosho to demokurashii [The Politics of Welfare: Social Security and Democracy in Japan]. Tokyo: Yuuhikaku.Google Scholar
Muramatsu, Michio, and Kume, Ikuo. 2006. Nihon Seiji Hendo no 30-nen. [Japanese Politics: Changes in Three Decades]. Tokyo: Toyo Keizai Shinpo Sha.Google Scholar
Myerson, Roger B. 1993. “Incentives to Cultivate Favored Minorities under Alternative Electoral Systems.” American Political Science Review 87(4): 856869.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Naoi, Megumi. 2007. “Decentralization, Industrial Geography and the Politics of Export Regulation: The Case of Sino-Japanese Trade Disputes.” In China’s Foreign Trade Policy, ed. Ka Zeng. London: Routledge, 4058.Google Scholar
Naoi, M. 2009. “Shopping for Protection: The Politics of Choosing Trade Instruments in a Partially Legalized World.” International Studies Quarterly 53(2): 421444.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Naoi, M. 2010. “Whose Side Do Legislators Take? The Politics of Economic Winners and Losers in the Global Economy.” Journal of Law, Politics, and Sociology (Hougaku Kenkyu). March: 502–528.Google Scholar
Naoi, Megumi, and Krauss, Ellis. 2009. “Who Lobbies Whom: Special Interest Politics under Alternative Electoral Systems.” American Journal of Political Science 53(4): 874–892.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Naoi, Megumi, and Kume, Ikuo. 2011. “Explaining Mass Support for Agricultural Protectionism: Evidence from a Survey Experiment during the Global Recession.” International Organization 65(4): 771795.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Naoi, Megumi, and Tetsuji, Okazaki. 2013. “Political Economy of Trade Liberalization: The Case of Postwar Japan.” CIRJE Discussion Papers CIRJE-F-898, Center for International Research on the Japanese Economy (CIRJE), 4.Google Scholar
Naoi, Megumi, and Urata, Shujiro. 2013. “Free Trade Agreements and Domestic Politics: The Case of the Trans-Pacific Partnership Agreement.” Asian Economic Policy Review 8(2): 326349.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Neher, Clark D. 1987. “Thailand in 1986: Prem, Parliament, and Political Pragmatism.” Asian Survey 27(2): 219230.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Nelson, Michael H. 2007. “Institutional Incentives and Informal Local Political Groups (Phuak) in Thailand: Comments on Allen Hicken and Paul Chambers.” Journal of East Asian Studies 7(1): 125147.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Nemoto, Kuniaki, Krauss, Ellis, and Pekkanen, Robert. 2008. “Policy Dissension and Party Discipline: The July 2005 Vote on Postal Privatization in Japan.” British Journal of Political Science 38(3): 499525.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ng, Francis K. T. 2011. “Trends in Average MFN Applied Tariff Rates in Developing and Industrialized Countries, 1981–2010.” Available at World Bank’s Data Bank.Google Scholar
Nielson, Daniel L. 2003. “Supplying Trade Reform: Political Institutions and Liberalization in Middle-Income Presidential Democracies.” American Journal of Political Science 47(3): 470491.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Nishio, Masaru. 1977. “Kaso to kamitsu no seiji gyosei” [The Politics and Governance of Depopulation and Over-Population]. Nenpou Seijigaku 28: 193258.Google Scholar
Niskanen, William A. 1975. “Bureaucrats and Politicians.” Journal of Law and Economics 18(3): 617643.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Noguchi, Yukio. 1995. Senkyuhyaku yonjuunen taisei [1940 Regime], Toyokeizai Shimposha. Tokyo.Google Scholar
Ockey, James. 2003. “Change and Continuity in the Thai Political Party System.” Asian Survey, 43(4): 663680.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ockey, James. 2000. “The Rise of Local Power in Thailand: Provincial Crime, Elections and Bureaucracy.” In Money and Power in Provincial Thailand, ed. McVey, Ruth T., 7496. Copenhagen: NIAS Press.Google Scholar
Ockey, James. 2004. Making Democracy: Leadership, Class, Gender, and Political Participation in Thailand. Honolulu: University of Hawaii Press.Google Scholar
Ohara Shakai Mondai Kenkyujo, Nihon Roudou Nenkan [Yearbook of Labor in Japan]. Various Years. Digital Archives available at: http://oohara.mt.tama.hosei.ac.jp/rn/ (Accessed March 4, 2015).Google Scholar
Ohta, Hiroko. 2006. Keizai zaisei shimon kaigi no tatakai [The Battles at the Council of Economic and Fiscal Policy]. Tokyo: Toyokeizai Shimposha.Google Scholar
Okazaki, Tetsuji. 2010. Boueki jiyuuka no seiji keizaigaku: sengo nihon no keisu. [Political Economy of Trade Liberalization: The Case of Post-War Japan] http://hermes-ir.lib.hit-u.ac.jp/rs/bitstream/10086/18976/1/No5-dp_10_05.pdf (Accessed March 4, 2015).Google Scholar
Okazaki, Tetsuji, and Korenaga, Takafumi. 1999. “Foreign Exchange Allocation and Productivity Growth in Post-War Japan: A Case of the Wool Industry.” Japan and the World Economy 11(2): 267285.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Olson, Mancur. 1965. The Logic of Collective Action: Public Goods and the Theory of Groups. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.Google Scholar
O’Rourke, Kevin H., et al. 2001. “The Determinants of Individual Trade Policy Preferences: International Survey Evidence [with comments and discussion].” Brookings Trade Forum. Washington, DC: Brookings Institution Press.Google Scholar
Pandya, Sonal S. 2010. “Labor Markets and the Demand for Foreign Direct Investment.” International Organization 64(3): 389409.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Pasuk, Phongpaichit, and Baker, Chris. 1995. Thailand: Economy and Politics. Kuala Lumpur: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Pekkanen, Robert, Nyblade, Benjamin, and Krauss, Ellis S.. 2006. “Electoral Incentives in Mixed-Member Systems: Party, Posts, and Zombie Politicians in Japan.” American Political Science Review 100(2): 183193.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Pekkanen, Saadia M. 2003. Picking Winners? From Technology Catch-Up to the Space Race in Japan. Stanford: Stanford University Press.Google Scholar
Pempel, T. J. 2010. “Between Pork and Productivity: The Collapse of the Liberal Democratic Party.” The Journal of Japanese Studies 36(2):227254.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Pempel, T. J., and Tsunekawa, Keiichi. 1979. “Corporatism without Labor? The Japanese Anomaly.” In Trends toward Corporatist Intermediation, ed. Schmitter, Philippe C. and Lehmbruch, Gerhard, 231270. Thousand Oaks, CA: SAGE.Google Scholar
Phongpaichit, Pasuk. 1999. Civilising the State: State, Civil Society and Politics in Thailand. Amsterdam: Centre for Asian Studies.Google Scholar
Phongpaichit, Pasuk, and Baker, Chris 2002. The Only Good Populist Is a Rich Populist: Thaksin Shinawatra and Thailand’s Democracy. Southeast Asia Research Centre, City University of Hong Kong.Google Scholar
Prasirtsuk, Kitti. 2007. “From Political Reform and Economic Crisis to Coup d’Etat in Thailand: The Twists and Turns of the Political Economy, 1997–2006.”Asian Survey 47(6): 872–893.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Punyaratabandhu-Bhakdi, Suchitra. 1983. “Thailand in 1982: General Arthit Takes Center Stage.” Asian Survey 23(2): 172177.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ray, Edward John. 1981. “The Determinants of Tariff and Nontariff Trade Restrictions in the United States.” The Journal of Political Economy 89(1): 105121.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ricardo, David, ed. 1951–1973. The Works and Correspondence of David Ricardo, ed. Sraffa, P. with Dobb, M. H.. Cambridge: Cambridge University PressGoogle Scholar
Riker, William H. 1962. The Theory of Political Coalitions. New Haven, CT: Yale University Press.Google Scholar
Robertson, Philip S., Jr. 1996. “The Rise of the Rural Network Politician: Will Thailand’s New Elite Endure?Asian Survey 36(9): 924941.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Rock, Michael T. 1995. “Thai Industrial Policy: How Irrelevant Was It to Export Success?” Journal of International Development 7(5): 745757.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Rodrik, Dani. 1986. “Tariffs, Subsidies, and Welfare with Endogenous Policy.” Journal of International Economics 21(3): 285299.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Rodrik, Dani. 1993. “The Positive Economics of Policy Reform.” The American Economic Review 83 (2, Papers and Proceedings of the Hundred and Fifth Annual Meeting of the American Economic Association): 356361.Google Scholar
Rodrik, Dani. 1994. “The Rush to Free Trade in the Developing World: Why So Late? Why Now? Will It Last?” In Voting for Reform: Democracy, Political Liberalization, and Economic Adjustment, ed. Haggard, S. and Webb, S., 61–87. New York: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Rodrik, Dani. 1996a. International Trade and Big Government. New York: Columbia University School of International and Public Affairs.Google Scholar
Rodrik, Dani. 1996b. “Understanding Economic Policy Reform.” Journal of Economic Literature 34(1): 941.Google Scholar
Rodrik, Dani. 1997. Has Globalization Gone Too Far? Washington, DC: Institute of International Economics.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Rodrik, Dani. 1998. “Why Do More Open Economies Have Bigger Governments?Journal of Political Economy 106(5): 9971032.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Rogowski, Ronald. 1987a. “Political Cleavages and Changing Exposure to Trade.” The American Political Science Review 81(4): 11211137.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Rogowski, Ronald. 1987b. “Trade and the Variety of Democratic Institutions.” International Organization 41(2): 203223.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Rogowski, Ronald. 1989. Commerce and Coalitions. Princeton, NJ: Princeton Univeristy Press.Google Scholar
Rogowski, Ronald, and Kayser, Mark Andreas. 2002. “Majoritarian Electoral Systems and Consumer Power: Price-Level Evidence from the OECD Countries.” American Journal of Political Science 46(3): 526539.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Rose, Andrew K. 2007. “Do We Really Know that the WTO Increases Trade?” Reply. The American Economic Review 97(5): 20192025.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Rosenbluth, Frances McCall, and Ramseyer, J. Mark. 1993. Japan’s Political Marketplace. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press, 152160.Google Scholar
Rudra, Nita. 2002. “Globalization and the Decline of the Welfare State in Less-Developed Countries.” International Organization 56(2): 411445.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Rudra, Nita. 2008. Globalization and the Race to the Bottom in Developing Countries: Who Really Gets Hurt? Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ruggie, John Gerard. 1982. “International Regimes, Transactions, and Change: Embedded Liberalism in Postwar Economic Order.” International Organization 36(2): 379415.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Saito, Jun. 2010. Jiminto choki seiken no seijikeizaigaku – rieki yudo seiji no jiko mujun. [Political Economy of the LDP’s Long-term Rule: Self-contradiction of Pork Barrel Politics]. Tokyo: Keiso-shobou.Google Scholar
Sasaki, Takeshi, Shinichi, Yoshida, and Masaki, Taniguchi. 1999. Daigishi to kane: seiji shikin zenkoku chosa houkoku [Representatives and Money: Report on the Nation-wide Research on Political Finance]. Tokyo: Asahi Shimbun Shuppan.Google Scholar
Sato, Seizaburo, and Matsuzaki, Tetsuhisa. 1986. Jiminto Seiken [LDP Regime]. Tokyo: Chuo Koronsha.Google Scholar
Scarrow, Susan E. 2007. “Political Finance in Comparative Perspective.” Annual Review of Political Science 10: 193210.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Schattschneider, Elmer Eric. 1935. Politics, Pressures and the Tariff: A Study of Free Private Enterprise in Pressure Politics, as Shown in the 1929–1930 Revision of the Tariff. Upper Saddle River, NJ: Prentice-Hall.Google Scholar
Scheiner, Ethan. 2006. Democracy Without Competition in Japan: Opposition Failure in a One-Party Dominant State. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Scheve, Kenneth F., and Slaughter, Matthew J. 2001. Globalization and the Perceptions of American Workers. Washington, DC: Institute for International Economics.Google Scholar
Scheve, Kenneth F., and Stasavage, David. 2009. “Institutions, Partisanship and Inequality in the Long Run.” World Politics. 61: 215253.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Schoppa, Leonard J. 1993. “Two-Level Games and Bargaining Outcomes: Why Gaiatsu Succeeds in Japan in Some Cases but not Others.” International Organization 47(3): 353386.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Schoppa, Leonard J. 1997. Bargaining with Japan: What American Pressure Can and Cannot Do. New York: Columbia University Press.Google Scholar
Selway, Joel Sawat. 2011. “Electoral Reform and Public Policy Outcomes in Thailand: The Politics of the 30-baht Health Scheme.” World Politics 63(1): 165202.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Shatkin, Gavin. 2004. “Globalization and Local Leadership: Growth, Power and Politics in Thailand’s Eastern Seaboard.” International Journal of Urban and Regional Research 28(1): 1126.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Shimano, Takao. 1980. Shohin seisan yusyutunyuryo ruinen toukei hyo [Export, Import and Production Statistical Tables for Commercial Product]. Tokyo: Yuukyo Syoin.Google Scholar
Shimomura, Yasutami (Ed.). 2004. Asian Development Experience, Vol. 2: The Role of Governance in Asia. Singapore: Institute of Southeast Asian Studies.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Shimomura, Yasutami. 2003. “In Search of Endogenous Elements of Good Governance: The Case of the Eastern Seaboard Development Plan in Thailand.” The Role of Governance in Asia 2: 166189.Google Scholar
Shinya, Imaizumi. 2012. “Rippou no seido to doutai [Law-making institutions and Changes].” In Tai no rippou katei: kokumin no seiji sanka he no mosaku, ed. Imaizumi, Shinya. IDE-JETRO Publication, No. 601. Tokyo.Google Scholar
Shirk, Susan L. 1993. The Political Logic of Economic Reform in China. Berkeley: University of California Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Simmons, Beth A. 2000. “International Law and State Behavior: Commitment and Compliance in International Monetary Affairs.” American Political Science Review 94(4): 819835.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Sirikrai, Surachai. 1982. “General Prem Survives on a Conservative Line.” Asian Survey 22(11): 10931104.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Soeya, Yoshihide. 1999. Japan’s Economic Diplomacy with China, 1945–1978. New York: Oxford University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Soma, Masao. 1977. Kokusei senkyo to seito seiji –Sougou Bunseki 1945–1976 [National Elections and Party Politics – Comprehensive Analysis from 1945 to 1976]. Tokyo: Seiji Koho Center.Google Scholar
Stiglitz, Joseph E., and Yusuf, Shahid, eds. 2001. Rethinking the East Asian Miracle. Washington, DC: World Bank Publications.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Stokes, Susan C. 2005. “Perverse Accountability: A Formal Model of Machine Politics with Evidence from Argentina.” American Political Science Review 99(3): 315325.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Stolper, Wolfgang F., and Samuelson, Paul A. 1941. “Protection and Real Wages.” Review of Economic Studies November: 58–73.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Sucharithanarugse, Withaya. 1983. Thailand in 1982: The Year of Living in Anxiety. Southeast Asian Affairs 277295.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Suehiro, Akira. 1989. Capital Accumulation in Thailand 1855–1985. Tokyo: The Centre for East Asian Cultural Studies (The Toyo Bunko).Google Scholar
Suehiro, Akira, and Wailerdsak, Natenapha. 2004. “Family Business in Thailand: Its Management, Governance, and Future Challenges.” ASEAN Economic Bulletin 21(1): 8193.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Suwanmala, Charas. 2009. “Fighting Corruption from the Bottom: A Case of Thailand.” Asian Human Rights Commission. Available at: http://www.humanrights.asia/resources/journals-magazines/article2/0901/07fighting-corruption-from-the-bottom-the-case-of-thailand (Accessed March 4, 2015).Google Scholar
Takii, Hiroomi. 2001. “Korekara dousuru seefu-gaado [What to do with safeguard provision].” Ronza 77: 100109.Google Scholar
Tatebayashi, Masahiko. 2004. Giin Kodo no seiji keizaigaku- Jiminto shihai no seido bunseki. Tokyo: Yuhikakusha.Google Scholar
Liberal Democratic Party. 1988. Jiyu minshuto shi [The History of the Liberal Democratic Party]. Tokyo: The Liberal Democratic Party.Google Scholar
Thies, Michael F. 1998. “When Will Pork Leave the Farm? Institutional Bias in Japan and the United States.” Legislative Studies Quarterly 23(4): 467492.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Tomoaki, Iwai. 1990. Seiji shikin no kenkyu: Rieki yuudou no nihon teki seiji fuudo. Tokyo: Nihon keizai shimbun sha.Google Scholar
Tomz, Michael, Goldstein, Judith L., and Rivers, Douglas. 2007. “Do We Really Know that the WTO Increases trade? Comment.” The American Economic Review 97(5): 20052018.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Topalova, Petia. 2007. “Trade Liberalization, Poverty and Inequality: Evidence from Indian Districts.” In Globalization and Poverty, ed. Harrison, Ann, 291336. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
United Nations Center of Transnational Corporations. 1991. World Investment Report: The Triad in Foreign Direct Investment. New York: United Nations.Google Scholar
Urata, Shujiro, and Yokota, Kazuhiko. 1994. “Trade Liberalization and Productivity Growth in Thailand.” The Developing Economies 32(4): 444459.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Uriu, Robert M. 1996. Troubled Industries: Confronting Economic Change in Japan. Ithaca, NY: Cornell University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Wade, Robert. 1990. Governing the Market: Economic Theory and the Role of Government in East Asian Industrialization. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Wallack, Jessica Seddon, et al. 2003. “Particularism around the World.” The World Bank Economic Review 17(1): 133143.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Warr, Peter G. 1996. Thailand’s Macroeconomic Miracle: Stable Adjustment and Sustained Growth. Washington, DC: World Bank Publications.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Warr, Peter G., and Nidhiprabha, Bhanupong.1996. Thailand’s Macroeconomic Miracle: Stable Adjustment and Sustained Growth. Washington, DC and New York: World Bank/Oxford University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Warr, Peter G., and Sarntisart, Isra. 2005. “Poverty Targeting in Thailand.” In Poverty Targeting in Asia, ed. Weiss, John. 186218. Cheltenham: Edward Elgar Publishing.Google Scholar
Weingast, Barry R., and Marshall, W. J. 1988. “The Industrial Organization of Congress; or, Why Legislatures, Like Firms, Are Not Organized as Markets.” The Journal of Political Economy 96(1): 132163.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Wongpreedee, Achakorn. 2007. “Decentralization and Its Effect on Provincial Political Power in Thailand (The front of area studies).” Asian and African Area Studies 6(2): 454470.Google Scholar
World Bank. 1993. East Asian Miracle: Economic Growth and Public Policy. Washington, DC: World Bank Group.Google Scholar

Save book to Kindle

To save this book to your Kindle, first ensure coreplatform@cambridge.org is added to your Approved Personal Document E-mail List under your Personal Document Settings on the Manage Your Content and Devices page of your Amazon account. Then enter the ‘name’ part of your Kindle email address below. Find out more about saving to your Kindle.

Note you can select to save to either the @free.kindle.com or @kindle.com variations. ‘@free.kindle.com’ emails are free but can only be saved to your device when it is connected to wi-fi. ‘@kindle.com’ emails can be delivered even when you are not connected to wi-fi, but note that service fees apply.

Find out more about the Kindle Personal Document Service.

  • References
  • Megumi Naoi, University of California, San Diego
  • Book: Building Legislative Coalitions for Free Trade in Asia
  • Online publication: 05 August 2015
  • Chapter DOI: https://doi.org/10.1017/CBO9781139583435.008
Available formats
×

Save book to Dropbox

To save content items to your account, please confirm that you agree to abide by our usage policies. If this is the first time you use this feature, you will be asked to authorise Cambridge Core to connect with your account. Find out more about saving content to Dropbox.

  • References
  • Megumi Naoi, University of California, San Diego
  • Book: Building Legislative Coalitions for Free Trade in Asia
  • Online publication: 05 August 2015
  • Chapter DOI: https://doi.org/10.1017/CBO9781139583435.008
Available formats
×

Save book to Google Drive

To save content items to your account, please confirm that you agree to abide by our usage policies. If this is the first time you use this feature, you will be asked to authorise Cambridge Core to connect with your account. Find out more about saving content to Google Drive.

  • References
  • Megumi Naoi, University of California, San Diego
  • Book: Building Legislative Coalitions for Free Trade in Asia
  • Online publication: 05 August 2015
  • Chapter DOI: https://doi.org/10.1017/CBO9781139583435.008
Available formats
×