Skip to main content Accessibility help
×
Hostname: page-component-68945f75b7-55759 Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-09-03T09:20:34.081Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

References

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  04 August 2017

Francesco Parisi
Affiliation:
University of Minnesota
Get access

Summary

Image of the first page of this content. For PDF version, please use the ‘Save PDF’ preceeding this image.'
Type
Chapter
Information
The Language of Law and Economics
A Dictionary
, pp. 326 - 346
Publisher: Cambridge University Press
Print publication year: 2013

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

References

Ahlborn, Christian, David, S. Evans, and Padilla, A. Jorge. 2004. “The antitrust economics of tying: a farewell to per se illegality,” 49 Antitrust Bulletin 287–341.Google Scholar
Ainslie, George W. 1992. Picoeconomics: The Strategic Interaction of Successive Motivational States within the Person. Cambridge University Press.
Akerlof, George A. 1970. “The market for ‘lemons’: quality uncertainty and the market mechanism,” 84 Quarterly Journal of Economics 488–500.Google Scholar
Akerlof, George A., and Romer, Paul M.. 1993. “Looting: the economic underworld of bankruptcy for profit,” 1993 Brookings Papers on Economic Activity 1–73.Google Scholar
Akerlof, George A., and Yellen, Janet L.. 1986. Efficiency Wage Models of the Labor Market. Cambridge University Press.
Albert, Max, and Heiner, Ronald A.. 2003. “An indirect-evolution approach to Newcomb’s problem,” 20 Homo Oeconomicus 161–94.Google Scholar
Alchian, Armen A., and Demsetz, Harold. 1972. “Production, information costs, and economic organization,” 62 American Economic Review 777–95.Google Scholar
Alesina, Alberto. 1987. “Macroeconomic policy in a two-party system as a repeated game,” 102 Quarterly Journal of Economics 651–78.Google Scholar
Alesina, Alberto, Ignazio, Angeloni, and Schuknecht, Ludger. 2005. “What does the European Union do?,” 123 Public Choice 275–319.Google Scholar
Arlen, Jennifer, and Talley, Eric (eds.). 2008. Experimental Law and Economics. Cheltenham: Edward Elgar.
Arnold, Craig Anthony. 2002. “The reconstitution of property: property as a web of interests,” 26 Harvard Environmental Law Review 281–364.Google Scholar
Arrow, Kenneth J. 1951. Social Choice and Individual Values. New York: John Wiley.
Arrow, Kenneth J. 1971. “A utilitarian approach to the concept of equality in public expenditure,” 85 Quarterly Journal of Economics 409–15.Google Scholar
Arrow, Kenneth J. 1973. “The theory of discrimination,” in Orley Ashenfelter and Albert Rees (eds.), Discrimination in Labor Markets, 3–33. Princeton University Press.
Arrow, Kenneth J., and Fisher, Anthony C.. 1974. “Environmental preservation, uncertainty, and irreversibility,” 88 Quarterly Journal of Economics 312–19.Google Scholar
Arrow, Kenneth J., and Hurwicz, Leonid (eds.). 1977. Studies in Resource Allocation Processes. Cambridge University Press.
Axelrod, Robert M. 1984. The Evolution of Cooperation. New York: Basic Books.
Axelrod, Robert M., and Hamilton, William D.. 1981. “The evolution of cooperation,” 211 Science 1390–6.Google Scholar
Ayres, Ian. 2005. Optional Law: The Structure of Legal Entitlements. University of Chicago Press.
Ayres, Ian. 2012. “Regulating opt-out: an economic theory of altering rules,” 121 Yale Law Journal 2032–117.Google Scholar
Ayres, Ian, and H. Gertner, Robert. 1989. “Filling gaps in incomplete contracts: an economic theory of default rules,” 99 Yale Law Journal 87–130.Google Scholar
Ayres, Ian and H. Gertner, Robert. 1999. “Majoritarian vs. minoritarian defaults,” 51 Stanford Law Review 1591–613.Google Scholar
Ayres, Ian, and Goldbart, Paul. 2001. “Optimal delegation and decoupling in the design of liability rules,” 100 Michigan Law Review 1–79.Google Scholar
Ayres, Ian and Goldbart, Paul. 2003. “Correlated values in the theory of property and liability rules,” 32 Journal of Legal Studies 121–51.Google Scholar
Ayres, Ian, and Talley, Eric. 1995. “Solomonic bargaining: dividing a legal entitlement to facilitate Coasean trade,” 104 Yale Law Journal 1027–117.Google Scholar
Babcock, Linda, Loewenstein, George and Issacharoff, Samuel. 1997. “Creating convergence: debiasing biased litigants,” 22 Law and Social Inquiry 401–13.Google Scholar
Babcock, Linda, Loewenstein, George, Issacharoff, Samuel, and Camerer, Colin. 1995. “Biased judgments of fairness in bargaining,” 85 American Economic Review 1337–43.Google Scholar
Baird, Douglas G., Gertner, Robert H., and Picker, Randal C.. 1994. Game Theory and the Law. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.
Banerjee, Abhijit V. 1992. “A simple model of herd behavior,” 107 Quarterly Journal of Economics 797–817.Google Scholar
Baron, Jonathan, Rajeev, Gowda, and Howard, Kunreuther. 1993. “Attitudes toward managing hazardous waste: what should be cleaned up and who should pay for it,” 13 Risk Analysis 183–92.Google Scholar
Barton, John H. 1972. “The economic basis of damages for breach of contract,” 1 Journal of Legal Studies 277–304.Google Scholar
Bastiat, Frédéric. 1850. Ce qu’on voit et ce qu’on ne voit pas, ou l’économie politique en une leçon [That Which Is Seen and That Which Is Unseen, or Political Economy in One Lesson]. Paris: Guillaumin.
Baumol, William J. 1882. “Contestable markets: an uprising in the theory of industry structure,” 72 American Economic Review 1–15.Google Scholar
Baumol, William J. 1986. “Williamson’s The Economic Institutions of Capitalism,” 17 Rand Journal of Economics 279–92.Google Scholar
Baumol, William J., and Blinder, Alan S.. 2011. Economics: Principles and Policy, 12th edn. Cincinnati: South-Western College Publishing.
Baumol, William J., Panzar, John C., and Willig, Robert D.. 1983. “Contestable markets: an uprising in the theory of industry structure: reply,” 73 American Economic Review 491–6.Google Scholar
Bebchuk, Lucian A. 1996. “A new theory concerning the credibility and success of threats to sue,” 25 Journal of Legal Studies 1–25.Google Scholar
Bebchuk, Lucian A., and Klement, Alon. 2012. “Negative-expected-value suits,” in Chris W. Sanchirico (ed.), Procedural Law and Economics, 2nd edn., 341–9. Cheltenham: Edward Elgar.Google Scholar
Beccaria, Cesare. 1764. Dei delitti e delle pene [On Crimes and Punishments]. Livorno: Coltellini.
Becker, Gary S. 1968. “Crime and punishment: an economic approach,” 78 Journal of Political Economy 169–217.Google Scholar
Becker, Gary S. 1971. The Economics of Discrimination. University of Chicago Press.
Becker, Gary S. 1974. “A theory of social interactions,” 82 Journal of Political Economy 1063–93.Google Scholar
Becker, Gary S. 1983. “A theory of competition among pressure groups for political influence,” 98 Quarterly Journal of Economics 371–400.Google Scholar
Bell, Abraham, and Gideon, Parchomovsky. 2002. “Pliability rules,” 101 Michigan Law Review 1–79.Google Scholar
Bell, Abraham and Parchomovsky, Gideon. 2003. “Of property and anti-property,” 102 Michigan Law Review 1–70.Google Scholar
Bell, Tom W. 2010. “Graduated consent in contract and tort law: toward a theory of justification,” 61 Case Western Law Review 1–68.Google Scholar
Bender, Keith A., and Sloane, Peter J.. 1998. “Job satisfaction, trade unions and exit-voice revisited,” 51 Industrial and Labor Relations Review 222–40.Google Scholar
Bennett, Christopher. 2011. “Expressive punishment and political authority,” 8 Ohio State Journal of Criminal Law 285–301.Google Scholar
Ben-Shahar, Omri. 2004. “Contracts without consent: exploring a new basis for contractual liability,” 152 University of Pennsylvania Law Review 1829–72.Google Scholar
Bentham, Jeremy. 1789. An Introduction to the Principles of Morals and Legislation. London: T. Payne.
Bentham, Jeremy. 1823. Leading Principles of a Constitutional Code for Any State. London: A. Valpy.
Bentham, Jeremy. 1830. Official Aptitude Maximized, Expense Minimized. London: R. Heward.
Bergstrom, Ted. 1989. “A fresh look at the rotten kid theorem,” 97 Journal of Political Economy 1138–59.Google Scholar
Berla, Edward P., Brookshire, Michael L., and Smith, Stan V.. 1990. “Hedonic damages and personal injury: a conceptual approach,” 3 Journal of Forensic Economics 1–8.Google Scholar
Bernholz, Peter. 1982. “Externalities as a necessary condition for cyclical social preferences,” 47 Quarterly Journal of Economics 699–705.Google Scholar
Bernoulli, Daniel. 1954 [1738]. “Exposition of a new theory on the measurement of risk [trans. Lousie Sommer],” 22 Econometrica 22–36.Google Scholar
Bertrand, Joseph. 1883. “Theorie mathematique de la richesse sociale,” 67 Journal des Savants 499–508.Google Scholar
Bhagwati, Jagdish N. 1982. “Directly unproductive, profit-seeking (DUP) activities,” 90 Journal of Political Economy 988–1002.Google Scholar
Bikhchandani, Sushil, Hirshleifer, David, and Welch, Ivo. 1992. “A Theory of fads, fashion, custom, and cultural change as informational cascades,” 100 Journal of Political Economy 992–1026.Google Scholar
Black, Duncan. 1948. “On the rationale of group decision-making,” 56 Journal of Political Economy 23–34.Google Scholar
Black, Duncan. 1958. The Theory of Committees and Elections. Cambridge University Press.
Blackstone, William. 1766. Commentaries on the Laws of England. Oxford: Clarendon Press.
Blair, Roger D., Kaserman, David L., and Romano, Richard E.. 1989. “A pedagogical treatment of bilateral monopoly,” 55 Southern Economic Journal 831–41.Google Scholar
Bork, Robert H. 1978. The Antitrust Paradox: A Policy at War with Itself. New York: Basic Books.
Brampton, C. Kenneth. 1964. “Nominalism and the law of parsimony,” 41 The Modern Schoolman 273–81.Google Scholar
Brennan, Geoffrey, and Buchanan, James M.. 1980. The Power to Tax: Analytical Foundations of a Fiscal Constitution. Cambridge University Press.
Brennan, Geoffrey, and Buchanan, James M.. 1985. The Reason of Rules: Constitutional Political Economy. Cambridge University Press.
Brennan, Geoffrey, Kliemt, Hartmut, and Tollison, Robert D. (eds.). 2002. Method and Morals in Constitutional Economics: Essays in Honor of James M. Buchanan. Berlin: Springer.
Brennan, Geoffrey, and Lomasky, Loren. 1993. Democracy and Decision: The Pure Theory of Electoral Preference. Cambridge University Press.
Broder, David. 1997. “Age of catatonic politics,” Washington Post, A19.Google Scholar
Buchanan, James M. 1954. “Individual choice in voting and the market,” 62 Journal of Political Economy 334–43.Google Scholar
Buchanan, James M. 1974. “Good economics – bad law,” 60 Virginia Law Review 483–92.Google Scholar
Buchanan, James M. 1988. “Politics and meddlesome preferences,” in Robert D. Tollison (ed.), Clearing the Air: Perspectives on Environmental Tobacco Smoke, 107–15. Lanham, MD: Lexington Books.
Buchanan, James M., and Tullock, Gordon. 1962. The Calculus of Consent: Logical Foundations of Constitutional Democracy. Ann Arbor: University of Michigan Press.
Buchanan, James M., and Tullock, Gordon. 1990. “The domain of constitutional economics,” 1 Constitutional Political Economy 1–18.Google Scholar
Buchanan, James M., and Yoon, Yong J.. 2000. “Symmetric tragedies; commons and anticommons,” 43 Journal of Law and Economics 1–14.Google Scholar
Bulow, Jeremy, Geanakoplos, John, and Klemperer, Paul. 1985. “Multimarket oligopoly: strategic substitutes and strategic complements,” 93 Journal of Political Economy 488–511.Google Scholar
Calabresi, Guido. 1961. “Some thoughts on risk distributions and the law of torts,” 70 Yale Law Journal 499–553.Google Scholar
Calabresi, Guido. 1968. “Transaction costs, resource allocation and liability rules: a comment,” 11 Journal of Law and Economics 67–73.Google Scholar
Calabresi, Guido. 1970. The Costs of Accidents: A Legal and Economic Analysis. New Haven, CT: Yale University Press.
Calabresi, Guido. 1980. “An exchange about law and economics: a letter to Ronald Dworkin,” 8 Hofstra Law Review 553–62.Google Scholar
Calabresi, Guido. 1991. “The pointlessness of Pareto: carrying Coase further,” 100 Yale Law Journal 1211–37.Google Scholar
Calabresi, Guido. 1996. “Address,” 6th annual meeting of the American Law and Economics Association, Chicago, May 10.
Calabresi, Guido, and Cooper, Jeffrey. 1996. “New directions in tort law,” 30 Valparaiso University Law Review 859–84.Google Scholar
Calabresi, Guido, and Melamed, Douglas A.. 1972. “Property rules, liability rules, and inalienability: one view of the cathedral,” 85 Harvard Law Review 1089–128.Google Scholar
Carbonara, Emanuela, Luppi, Barbara, and Parisi, Francesco. 2009. “Self-defeating subsidiarity,” 5 Review of Law and Economics 741–83.Google Scholar
Carlton, Dennis W., and Waldman, Michael. 2002. “The strategic use of tying to preserve and create market power in evolving industries,” 33 Rand Journal of Economics 194–220.Google Scholar
Castro, Carl A., and Larsen, Thomas. 1992. “Primacy and recency effects in nonhuman primates,” 18 Journal of Experimental Psychology: Animal Behavior Processes 335–40.Google Scholar
Chamberlin, Edward H. 1933. The Theory of Monopolistic Competition: A Reorientation of the Theory of Value. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.
Chung, Shin-Ho, and Richard, J. Herrnstein. 1961. “Relative and absolute strengths of response as a function of frequency of reinforcement,” 4 Journal of the Experimental Analysis of Animal Behavior 267–72.Google Scholar
Coase, Ronald H. 1937. “The nature of the firm,” 4 Economica 386–405.Google Scholar
Coase, Ronald H. 1959. “The Federal Communications Commission,” 2 Journal of Law and Economics 1–40.Google Scholar
Coase, Ronald H. 1960. “The problem of social cost,” 3 Journal of Law and Economics 1–44.Google Scholar
Coase, Ronald H. 1988. The Firm, the Market, and the Law. University of Chicago Press.
Cohen, Wesley M., and Levinthal, Daniel A.. 1990. “Absorptive capacity: a new perspective on learning and innovation,” 35 Administrative Science Quarterly 128–52.Google Scholar
Coleman, Jules L. 1982. “The economic analysis of law,” in Pennock, J. Roland and John, W. Chapman (eds.), Nomos XXIV: Ethics, Economics and the Law of Property, 83–103. New York University Press. Google Scholar
Cooter, Robert D. 1982. “The cost of Coase,” 11 Journal of Legal Studies 1–33.Google Scholar
Coleman, Jules L. 1994. “Structural adjudication and the new law merchant: a model of decentralized law,” 14 International Review of Law and Economics 215–31.Google Scholar
Coleman, Jules L. 1997. “Punitive damages, social norms, and economic analysis,” 60 Law and Contemporary Problems 73–91.Google Scholar
Coleman, Jules L. 1998. “Expressive law and economics,” 27 Journal of Legal Studies 585–608.Google Scholar
Coleman, Jules L. 2000a. The Strategic Constitution. Princeton University Press.
Cooter, Robert D. 2000b. “Do good laws make good citizens? An economic analysis of internalized norms,” 86 Virginia Law Review 1577–601.Google Scholar
Cooter, Robert D., and Eisenberg, Melvin. 2000. “Fairness, character, and efficiency in firms,” 149 University of Pennsylvania Law Review 1717–33.Google Scholar
Cooter, Robert D., Feldman, Michal, and Feldman, Yural. 2006. “The misperception of norms: the psychology of bias and the economics of equilibrium,” unpublished manuscript; available at .
Cooter, Robert D., Marks, Stephen, and Mnookin, Robert H.. 1982. “Bargaining in the shadow of the law: a testable model of strategic behavior,” 11 Economic Analysis 225–51.Google Scholar
Cooter, Robert D., and Porat, Ariel. 2000. “Does harm to self increase the care owed to others? Law and economics in conflict,” 29 Journal of Legal Studies 19–34.Google Scholar
Cooter, Robert D., and Porat, Ariel. 2002. “Anti-insurance,” 31 Journal of Legal Studies 203–32.Google Scholar
Cooter, Robert D. and Schäfer, Hans-Bend. 2011. Solomon’s Knot: How Law Can End the Poverty of Nations. Princeton University Press.
Cooter, Robert D., and Ulen, Thomas. 1997. Law and Economics. 2nd edn. Boston: Addison-Wesley.
Cooter, Robert D., and Ulen, Thomas. 2008. Law and Economics, 5th edn. Boston: Addison-Wesley.
Cornes, Richard, and Sandler, Todd. 1996. The Theory of Externalities, Public Goods, and Club Goods, 2nd edn. Cambridge University Press.
Cosmides, Leda, and Tooby, John. 2003. “Evolutionary psychology: theoretical foundations,” in Lynn Nadel (ed.), Encyclopedia of Cognitive Science vol. I, 54–64. London: Macmillan.
Cournot, Antoine-Augustin. 1838. Recherches sur les principes mathématiques de la théorie des richesses [Researches on the Mathematical Principles of the Theory of Wealth] Paris: Hachette.
Coursey, Don L., and Linda, R. Stanley. 1988. “Pretrial bargaining behavior within the shadow of the law: theory and experimental evidence,” 8 International Review of Law and Economics 161–79.Google Scholar
Dan-Cohen, Meir. 1984. “Decision rules and conduct rules: on acoustic separation in criminal law,” 97 Harvard Law Review 625–77.Google Scholar
Dari-Mattiacci, Giuseppe. 2005. “On the optimal Scope of negligence,” 1 Review of Law and Economics 331–64.Google Scholar
Dari-Mattiacci, Giuseppe. 2009. “Negative liability,” 38 Journal of Legal Studies 21–60.Google Scholar
Dari-Mattiacci, Giuseppe, and Parisi, Francesco. 2005a. “Rents, dissipation, and lost treasures: rethinking Tullock’s paradox,” 124 Public Choice 411–22.Google Scholar
Dari-Mattiacci, Giuseppe, and Parisi, Francesco. 2005b. “The economics of tort law: a precis,” in Jürgen Backhaus (ed.), The Elgar Companion to Law and Economics, 2nd edn., 87–102. Cheltenham: Edward Elgar.
Dari-Mattiacci, Giuseppe, and De Geest, Gerrit. 2005. “The filtering effect of sharing rules,” 34 Journal of Legal Studies 207–37.Google Scholar
Dari-Mattiacci, Giuseppe and De Geest, Gerrit. 2010. “Carrots, sticks, and the multiplication effect,” 26 Journal of Law, Economics, and Organization 365–84.Google Scholar
Dari-Mattiacci, Giuseppe, Onderstal, Sander, and Parisi, Francesco. 2011. “Inverse adverse selection: the market for gems,” Legal Studies Research Paper no. 10–47, Law School, University of Minnesota. Google Scholar
Davis, Michael. 1991. “Criminal desert, harm, and fairness,” 25 Israel Law Review 524–48.Google Scholar
De Caritat, Marie-Jean-Antoine-Nicolas. 1785. Essai sur l’application de l’analyse à la probabilité des décisions rendues à la pluralité des voix [Essay on the Application of Analysis to the Probability of Majority Decisions] Paris: Imprimerie Royale.
Dekay, Michael L. 1996. “The difference between Blackstone-like error ratios and probabilistic standards of proof,” 21 Law and Social Inquiry 95–132.Google Scholar
Demsetz, Harold M. 1967. “Toward a theory of property rights,” 57 American Economic Review 347–59.Google Scholar
Demsetz, Harold. 1968. “Why regulate utilities?,” 11 Journal of Law and Economics 55–65.Google Scholar
Dekay, Michael L. 1972. “When does the rule of liability matter?” 1 Journal of Legal Studies 13–28.Google Scholar
Demsetz, Harold. 1976. “Economics as a guide to antitrust legislation,” 19 Journal of Law and Economics 371–84.Google Scholar
Depoorter, Ben. 2010. “Law in the shadow of bargaining: the feedback effect of civil settlements,” 95 Cornell Law Review 957–87.Google Scholar
Depoorter, Ben, Francesco, Parisi, and Sven, Vanneste. 2005. “Problems with the enforcement of copyright law: is there a social norm backlash?” 12 International Journal of the Economics of Business 361–9.Google Scholar
Depoorter, Ben, Van Hiel, Alain, and Vanneste, Sven. 2011. “Copyright backlash,” 84 Southern California Law Review 1051–292.Google Scholar
Dixit, Avinash, and Olson, Mancur. 2000. “Does voluntary participation undermine the Coase theorem?,” 76 Journal of Public Economics 309–55.Google Scholar
Dixit, Avinash, and Pindyck, Robert S.. 1994. Investment under Uncertainty. Princeton University Press.
Dnes, Antony W. 1995. “Franchising and privatization,” Note no. 40, World Bank, Public Policy for the Private Sector, Washington, DC.Google Scholar
Dodgson, Charles L. 1876. A Method for Taking Votes on More than Two Issues. Oxford: Clarendon Press.
Douglas, Paul H., and Aaron, Director. 1931a. Unemployment. London: Macmillan.
Douglas, Paul H., and Aaron, Director. 1931b. The Problem of Unemployment. London: Macmillan.
Downs, Anthony. 1957. An Economic Theory of Democracy. Cambridge University Press.
Duff, R. Anthony, and Green, Stuart P.. 2011. “Introduction: searching for foundations,” in R. Anthony Duff and Stuart P. Green (eds.) Philosophical Foundations of Criminal Law, 1–19. Oxford University Press.
Dworkin, Ronald. 1977. Taking Rights Seriously. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.
Easterbrook, Frank H., and Fischel, Daniel R.. 1985. “Limited liability and the corporation,” 52 University of Chicago Law Review 89–117.Google Scholar
Edgeworth, Francis Y. 1881. Mathematical Physics: An Essay on the Application of Mathematics to the Moral Sciences. London: Kegan.
Edlin, Aaron S. 2007. “A Christmas warning,” 4 Economists’ Voice, .Google Scholar
Ehrlich, Isaac, and Posner, Richard A. 1974. “An economic analysis of legal rulemaking,” 3 Journal of Legal Studies 257–86.Google Scholar
Ellickson, Robert C. 1991. Order without Law: How Neighbors Settle Disputes. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.
Ellickson, Robert C. 2001. “The market for social norms,” 3 American Law and Economic Review 1–49.Google Scholar
Elster, Jon. 1983. “The crisis in economic theory,” 5 London Review of Books 5–7.Google Scholar
Elster, Jon. 1986. Rational Choice. Oxford: Basil Blackwell.
Emons, Winand, and Garoupa, Nuno. 2004. “The economics of US-style contingent fees and UK-style conditional fees,” Discussion Paper no. 0407, Department of Political Economy, University of Bern.
Epstein, Richard A. 1985. Takings: Private Property and the Power of Eminent Domain. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.
Epstein, Richard A. 1993. “Holdouts, externalities, and the single owner: one more salute to Ronald Coase,” 36 Journal of Law and Economics 553–86.Google Scholar
Epstein, Richard A. 1995a. Simple Rules for a Complex World. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.
Epstein, Richard A. 1995b. “The harm principle – and how it grew,” 45 University of Toronto Law Journal 369–417.Google Scholar
Etner, Johanna, Jeleva, Meglena, and Tallon, Jean-Marc. 2009. “Decision theory under uncertainty,” Working Paper no. 09064, Centre d’Economie, Université Panthéon-Sorbonne, Paris.
Fama, Eugene F. 1965. “The behavior of stock-market prices,” 38 Journal of Business 34–105.Google Scholar
Faure, Michael (ed.). 2009. Tort Law and Economics. Cheltenham: Edward Elgar.
Feeley, Andrew, and Schap, David. 2006. “(Much) more on the collateral source rule,” paper presented at the Eastern Economic Association meeting, Philadelphia, February 25.
Fehr, Ernst, Hart, Oliver, and Zehnder, Christian. 2011. “Contracts as reference points: experimental evidence,” 101 American Economic Review 493–525.Google Scholar
Fehr, Ernst, and Schmidt, Klaus M.. 1999. “A theory of fairness, competition, and cooperation,” 114 Quarterly Journal of Economics 817–68.Google Scholar
Fisher, Ronald A. 1949. The Design of Experiments, 5th edn. London: Oliver & Boyd.
Fon, Vincy, and Parisi, Francesco. 2003. “Reciprocity-induced cooperation,” 159 Journal of Institutional and Theoretical Economics 76–92.Google Scholar
Fon, Vincy, and Parisi, Francesco. 2005. ‘The behavioral foundations of retaliatory justice,” 7 Journal of Bioeconomics 45–72.Google Scholar
Fon, Vincy, Parisi, Francesco, and Ben, Depoorter. 2005. “Litigation, judicial path dependence, and legal change,” 20 European Journal of Law and Economics 43–56.Google Scholar
Forsythe, Robert, Horowitz, Joel L., Savin, N. E., and Sefton, Martin. 1994. “Fairness in simple bargaining experiments,” 6 Games and Economic Behavior 347–69.Google Scholar
Frederick, Shane, Loewenstein, George and O’Donoghue, Ted. 2002. “Time discounting and time preference: a critical review,” 40 Journal of Economic Literature 351–401.Google Scholar
Frey, Bruno S., and Stutzer, Alois, 2008. “The thirst for happiness,” 1 Journal of International Business Ethics 7–17.Google Scholar
Fried, Charles. 1981. Contract as Promise: A Theory of Contractual Obligation. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.
Friedman, David D. 2000. Law’s Order: What Economics Has to Do with Law and Why It Matters. Princeton University Press.
Friedman, Milton. 1953. Essays in Positive Economics. University of Chicago Press.
Friedman, Milton. 1957. A Theory of the Consumption Function. Princeton University Press.
Friedman, Milton. 1958. “The permanent income hypothesis: comment,” 48 American Economic Review 990–1.Google Scholar
Friedman, Milton. 1962. Capitalism and Freedom. University of Chicago Press.
Friedman, Milton. 1976. Price Theory. Piscataway, NJ: Transaction.
Friedman, Milton, and Anna, Jacobson Schwartz. 1963. A Monetary History of the United States, 1867–1960. Princeton University Press.
Friedman, Milton, and Anna, Jacobson Schwartz. 1981. Monetary Trends in the United States and the United Kingdom: Their Relation to Income, Prices, and Interest Rates, 1867–1975. University of Chicago Press.
Fuller, Lon, and Perdue, William R.. 1936. “The reliance interest in contract damages,” 46 Yale Law Journal 52–96.Google Scholar
Furnham, Adrian. 1986. “The robustness of the recency effect: studies using legal evidence,” 133 Journal of General Psychology 351–7.Google Scholar
Garoupa, Nuno, and Rizzolli, Matteo. 2008. “Why pro-defendant criminal procedure might hurt the innocent,” Working Paper no. 137, Department of Economics, University of Milano – Bicocca.
Geanakoplos, John, Pearce, David W., and Stacchetti, Ennio. 1989. “Psychological games and sequential rationality,” 1 Games and Economic Behavior 60–80.Google Scholar
Gibbard, Allan. 1973. “Manipulation of voting schemes: a general result,” 41 Econometrica 665–81.Google Scholar
Gintis, Herbert. 2000. “Strong reciprocity and human sociality,” 206 Journal of Theoretical Biology 169–79.Google Scholar
Glaeser, Edward, and Shleifer, Andrei. 2002. “Legal origins,” 117 Quarterly Journal of Economics 1193–229.Google Scholar
Gneezy, Uri, and Rustichini, Aldo. 2000. “A fine is a price,” 29 Journal of Legal Studies 1–17.Google Scholar
Goetz, Charles J., and Scott, Robert E.. 1977. “Liquidated damages, penalties and the just compensation principle: some notes of an enforcement model and a theory of efficient breach,” 77 Columbia Law Review 554–94.Google Scholar
Goetz, Charles J. and Scott, Robert E.. 1980. “Enforcing promises: an examination of the basis of contract,” 89 Yale Law Journal 1261–300.Google Scholar
Gordon, H. Scott. 1954. “The economic theory of common-property resource: the fishery,” 62 Journal of Political Economy 124–42.Google Scholar
Grady, Mark F. 1983. “A new positive theory of negligence,” 92 Yale Law Journal 799–829.Google Scholar
Grady, Mark F. 1988. “Why are people negligent? Technology, nondurable precautions, and the medical malpractice explosion,” 82 Northwestern University Law Review 293–334.Google Scholar
Granger, Clive W. J. 1969. “Investigating causal relations by econometric models and cross-spectral methods,” 37 Econometrica 424–38.Google Scholar
Granovetter, Mark. 1985. “Economic action and social structure: the problem of embeddedness,” 91 American Journal of Sociology 481–510.Google Scholar
Grey, Thomas C. 1980. “The disintegration of property,” in Roland Pennock and John W. Chapman (eds.) Property, 69–85. New York University Press.
Grossman, Sanford J., and Stiglitz, Joseph. 1976. “Information and competitive price systems,” 66 American Economic Review 246–53.Google Scholar
Grotius, Hugo. 1625. De Jure Belli ac Pacis [Law of War and Peace], Paris: Buon.
Grundmann, Stefan, Kerber, Wolfgang, and Weatherill, Stephen. 2001. Party Autonomy and the Role of Information in the Internal Market. Berlin: Walter de Gruyter.
Guttel, Ehud. 2004. “Overcorrection,” 93 Georgetown Law Journal 241–83.Google Scholar
Hansmann, Henry, and Kraakman, Reiner. 1991. “Toward unlimited shareholder liability for corporate torts,” 100 Yale Law Journal 1879–934.Google Scholar
Hardin, Garrett. 1968. “The tragedy of the commons,” 162 Science 1243–8.Google Scholar
Harris, Milton, and Raviv, Artur. 1981. “Allocation mechanisms and the design of auctions,” 49 Econometrica 1477–500.Google Scholar
Harsanyi, John C. 1953. “Cardinal utility in welfare economics and in the theory of risk-taking,” 61 Journal of Political Economy 434–5.Google Scholar
Harsanyi, John C. 1955. “Cardinal welfare, individualistic ethics, and interpersonal comparisons of utility,” 63 Journal of Political Economy 309–21.Google Scholar
Harsanyi, John C. 1975. “Can the maximin principle serve as a basis for morality? A critique of John Rawls’s theory,” 69 American Political Science Review 594–606.Google Scholar
Hart, Oliver. 2009. “Hold-up, asset ownership, and reference points,” 124 Quarterly Journal of Economics 267–300.Google Scholar
Hart, Oliver. 2011. “Noncontractible investments and reference points,” Working Paper no. 16929, National Bureau of Economic Research, Cambridge, MA.
Hart, Oliver, and John, Moore. 1988a. “Incomplete contracts and renegotiation,” 56 Econometrica 755–85.Google Scholar
Hart, Oliver, and John, Moore. 1988b. “Incomplete contracts and the theory of the firm,” 4 Journal of Law, Economics, and Organization 119–39.Google Scholar
Hart, Oliver. 1990. “Property rights and the nature of the firm,” 98 Journal of Political Economy 1119–58.Google Scholar
Hart, Oliver and Moore, John. 2008. “Contracts as reference points,” 123 The Quarterly Journal of Economics 1–48.Google Scholar
Hayek, Friedrich. 1944. The Road to Serfdom. University of Chicago Press.
Heller, Michael A. 1998. “The tragedy of the anticommons: property in the transition from Marx to markets,” 111 Harvard Law Review 621–88.Google Scholar
Heller, Michael A. 1999. “The boundaries of private property,” 108 Yale Law Journal 1163–223.Google Scholar
Henry, Claude. 1974. “Investment decisions under uncertainty: the irreversibility effect,” 64 American Economic Review 1006–12.Google Scholar
Hicks, John R. 1932. The Theory of Wages. London: Macmillan.
Hicks, John. 1939. “The foundations of welfare economics,” 49 Economic Journal 696–712.Google Scholar
Hillman, Arye L., and Samet, Dov. 1987. “Dissipation of contestable rents by small numbers of contenders,” 54 Public Choice 63–82.Google Scholar
Hirshleifer, Jack. 1983. “From weakest-link to best-shot: the voluntary provision of public goods,” 41 Public Choice 371–86.Google Scholar
Hirshleifer, J. 1985. “From Weakest-Link to Best-Shot: Correction,” 46 Public Choice 221–23.Google Scholar
Hirschman, Albert O. 1970. Exit, Voice, and Loyalty: Responses to Decline in Firms, Organizations, and States. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.
Hobbes, Thomas. 1651. Leviathan, or The Matter, Forme and Power of a Common Wealth Ecclesiasticall and Civil. London: Andrew Cooke.
Hodgson, David H. 1967. Consequences of Utilitarianism. Oxford University Press.
Hotelling, Harold. 1929. “Stability in competition,” 39 Economic Journal 41–57.Google Scholar
Hotelling, Harold. 1931. “The generalization of student’s ratio,” 2 Annals of Mathematical Statistics 360–78.Google Scholar
Hurwicz, Leonid. 1972. “On informationally decentralized systems,” in C. B. McGuire and Roy Radner, eds. Decision and Organization: A Volume in Honor of Jacob Marschak, 2nd edn., 297–336. Minneapolis: University of Minnesota Press.
Inman, Robert P., and Rubinfeld, Daniel L.. 1997. “Rethinking federalism,” 11 Journal of Economic Perspectives 43–64.Google Scholar
Inman, Robert P., and Rubinfeld, Daniel L.. 1998. “Subsidiarity and the European Union,” Working Paper no. 6556, National Bureau of Economic Research, Cambridge, MA.
Jolls, Christine, and Sunstein, Cass R.. 2006a. “Debiasing through law,” 35 Journal of Legal Studies 199–241.Google Scholar
Jolls, Christine and Sunstein, Cass R.. 2006b. “The law of implicit bias,” 94 California Law Review 969–96.Google Scholar
Jolls, Christine, Sunstein, Cass R., and Richard, Thaler. 1998. “A behavioral approach to law and economics,” 50 Stanford Law Review 1471–550.Google Scholar
Kahan, Dan M. 1998. “Social meaning and the economic analysis of crime,” 27 Journal of Legal Studies 609–22.Google Scholar
Kahan, Dan M. 2000. “Gentle nudges vs. hard shoves: solving the sticky norms problem,” 67 University of Chicago Law Review 607–45.Google Scholar
Kahan, Dan M., and Posner, Eric A.. 1999. “Slamming white-collar criminals: a proposal for reform of the federal sentencing guidelines,” 42 Journal of Law and Economics 365–92.Google Scholar
Kahan, Marcel. 1989. “Causation and incentives to take care under the negligence rule,” 18 Journal of Legal Studies 427–47.Google Scholar
Kahneman, Daniel. 2002. “Maps of bounded rationality: a perspective on intuitive judgment and choice,” Nobel lecture, December 8, Stockholm.
Kahneman, Daniel, and Tversky, Amos. 1973. “On the psychology of prediction,” 80 Psychological Review 237–51.Google Scholar
Kahneman, Daniel, and Tversky, Amos. 1979. “Prospect theory: an analysis of decision under risk,” 47 Econometrica 313–27.Google Scholar
Kalai, Ehud. 1977. “Proportional solutions to bargaining situations: interpersonal utility comparisons,” 45 Econometrica 1623–30.Google Scholar
Kaldor, Nicholas. 1939. “Welfare propositions in economics and interpersonal comparisons of utility,” 49 Economic Journal 549–52.Google Scholar
Kaneko, Mamoru, and Nakamura, Kenjiro. 1979. “The Nash social welfare function,” 47 Econometrica 423–35.Google Scholar
Kant, Immanuel. 1781. Critik der reinen Vernunft [The Critique of Pure Reason] Riga: Hartknoch.
Kaplow, Louis. 1992. “The optimal probability and magnitude of fines for acts that definitely are undesirable,” 12 International Review of Law and Economics 3–11.Google Scholar
Kaplow, Louis, and Shavell, Steven M.. 1994. “Why the legal system is less efficient than the income tax in redistributing income,” 23 Journal of Legal Studies 667–81.Google Scholar
Kaplow, Louis and Shavell, Steven. 1996. “Property rules versus liability rules: an economic analysis,” 109 Harvard Law Review 713–90.Google Scholar
Kaplow, Louis and Shavell, Steven. 2001. “Fairness versus welfare,” 114 Harvard Law Review 961–1388.Google Scholar
Kaplow, Louis and Shavell, Steven. 2002. Fairness versus Welfare. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.
Kassin, Saul M., and Lawrence, S. Wrightsman, . 1979. “On the requirements of proof: the timing of judicial instruction and mock juror verdicts,” 37 Journal of Personality and Social Psychology, 1877–87.Google Scholar
Katz, Avery W., and Sanchirico, Chris William. 2010. “Fee shifting in litigation: survey and assessment”, Research Paper no. 10–30, Institute for Law and Economics, University of Pennsylvania.
Kaye, David H., Freedman, David A, David, L. Faigman, Michael J. Saks, Joseph Sanders, and Edward, K. Cheng. 2010. Modern Scientific Evidence: The Law and Science of Expert Testimony. St. Paul, MN: West Publishing.
Kerin, Roger A., Varadarajan, R. Rajan, and Peterson, Robert A.. 1992. “First-mover advantage: a synthesis, conceptual framework, and research propositions,” 56 Journal of Marketing 33–52.Google Scholar
Kessler, Friedrich. 1943. “Contracts of adhesion: some thoughts about freedom of contracts,” 43 Columbia Law Review 629–42.Google Scholar
Kim, Pauline. 1999. “Norms, learning, and law: exploring the influences on workers’ legal knowledge,” 1999 University of Illinois Law Review 447–515.Google Scholar
Kingdon, John W. 1995. Agendas, Alternatives, and Public Policy, 2nd edn. New York: HarperCollins College Publishers.
Llick, Jonathan, and Francesco, Parisi. 2005. “Wealth, utility and the human dimension,” 1 New York University Journal of Law and Liberty 590–608.Google Scholar
Kronman, Anthony T. 1985. “Contract law and the state of nature,” 1 Journal of Law, Economics, and Organization 5–32.Google Scholar
Kuhn, Thomas. 1962. The Structure of Scientific Revolutions. University of Chicago Press.
Laffer, Arthur. 2004. “The Laffer curve: past, present, and future,” Heritage Foundation; available at .
Laibson, David. 1997. “Golden eggs and hyperbolic discounting,” 112 Quarterly Journal of Economics 443–77.Google Scholar
Landes, William, H. and Richard, A. Posner 1987. The Economic Structure of Tort Law. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.
Laycock, Douglas. 2009. “Voting with your feet is no substitute for constitutional rights,” 32 Harvard Journal of Law and Public Policy 29–44.Google Scholar
Leibenstein, Harvey. 1978. General X-Efficiency Theory and Economic Development. New York: Oxford University Press.
Lindbeck, Assar, and Jörgen, W. Weibull, . 1988. “Altruism and efficiency: the economics of fait accompli,” 96 Journal of Political Economy, 1165–82.Google Scholar
Lloyd, William Forster. 1833. Two Lectures on the Checks to Population. Oxford University Press.
Loewenstein, George, and Drazen, Prelec. 1992. Choices over Time. New York: Russell Sage Foundation.
Lundberg, Shelly, and Robert, A. Pollak, 2003. “Efficiency in marriage,” 1 Review of the Economics of the Household 153–67.Google Scholar
Luce, R. Duncan, and Raiffa, Howard. 1957. Games and Decisions: Introduction and Critical Survey. New York: John Wiley.
Luppi, Barbara, and Parisi, Francesco. 2011. “Toward an asymmetric Coase theorem,” 31 European Journal of Law and Economics 111–22.Google Scholar
Luppi, Barbara, and Parisi, Francesco. 2012a. “Politics with(out) Coase,” 59 International Review of Economics 175–87.Google Scholar
Luppi, Barbara and Parisi, Francesco. 2012b. “Jury size and the hung-jury paradox,” Legal Studies Research Paper no. 12–01, Law School, University of Minnesota.Google Scholar
Luppi, Barbara, Parisi, Francesco, and Daniel, Pi. 2012. “Double-edged torts,” Legal Studies Research Paper no. 12–57, Law School, University of Minnesota.
Malloy, Robin Paul. 1988. “Invisible hand or sleight of hand? Adam Smith, Richard Posner and the philosophy of law and economics,” 36 University of Kansas Law Review 209–59.Google Scholar
Mandeville, Bernard. 1714. The Fable of the Bees: or, Private Vices, Publick Benefits. London: Edmund Parker.
Manne, Henry G. 1965. “Mergers and the market for corporate control,” 73 Journal of Political Economy 110–20.Google Scholar
Manne, Henry G. 1966. Insider Trading and the Stock Market. New York: Free Press.
Markovits, Daniel. 2004. “The no-retraction principle and the morality of negotiations,” 152 University of Pennsylvania Law Review 1903–21.Google Scholar
Markovits, Richard S. 2008. Truth or Economics: On the Definition, Prediction, and Relevance of Economic Efficiency. New Haven, CT: Yale University Press.
Markowitz, Harry M. 1952. “Portfolio selection,” 7 Journal of Finance 77–91.Google Scholar
Marongiu, Pietro, and Newman, Graeme. 1987. Vengeance: The Fight Against Injustice. Totowa, NJ: Rowman & Littlefield.
Marshall, Alfred. 1890. Principles of Economics. London: Macmillan.
Marshall, Kevin, and Fitzgerald, Patrick. 2005. “The collateral source rule and its abolition: an economic perspective,” 15 Kansas Journal of Law and Public Policy 56–84.Google Scholar
Marx, Karl. 1993 [1857]. Grundrisse (trans. Martin Nicolaus). London: Penguin Books.
Maynard Smith, John, and Price, George. 1973. “The logic of animal conflict,” 245 Nature 15–18.Google Scholar
McAdams, Richard H. 1992. “Relative preferences,” 102 Yale Law Journal 1–104.Google Scholar
McAdams, Richard H. 2000. “A focal point theory of expressive law,” 86 Virginia Law Review 1649–729.Google Scholar
McDonald, Robert and Siegel, Daniel R.. 1986. “The value of waiting to invest,” 101 Quarterly Journal of Economics 707–27.Google Scholar
McDonnell, Brett. 2007. “Sticky defaults and altering rules in corporate law,” 60 Southern Methodist University Law Review 383–440.Google Scholar
Merges, Robert P. 2005. “A transactional view of property rights,” 20 Berkeley Technology Law Journal 1477–520.Google Scholar
Michelman, Frank I. 1982. Ethics, Economics, and the Law of Property. New York University Press.
Mises, Ludwig von. 1966. Human Action: A Treatise on Economics, 3rd edn. Chicago: Henry Regnery.
Mnookin, Robert H., and Lewis, Kornhauses. 1979. “Bargaining in the shadow of the law: the case of divorce,” 88 Yale Law Journal 950–97.Google Scholar
Mueller, Dennis C. 2003. Public Choice III. Cambridge University Press.
Mukhopadhaya, Kaushik. 2003. “Jury size and the free rider problem,” 19 Journal of Law, Economics, and Organization 24–44.Google Scholar
Murdock, Jr., Bennet, B. 1962. “The serial position effect of free recall,” 64 Journal of Experimental Psychology 482–8.Google Scholar
Muris, Timothy J. 1983. “Cost of completion or diminution in market value: the relevance of subjective value,” 12 Journal of Legal Studies 379–400.Google Scholar
Muth, John F. 1960. “Optimal properties of exponentially weighted forecasts,” 55 Journal of the American Statistical Association 299–306.Google Scholar
Muth, John F. 1961. “Rational expectations and the theory of price movements,” 29 Econometrica 315–35.Google Scholar
Myerson, Roger B. 1978. “Refinements of the Nash equilibrium concept,” 7 International Journal of Game Theory 73–80.Google Scholar
Nash, John F. 1950a. “Equilibrium points in n-person games,” 36 Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences 48–9.Google Scholar
Nash, John F. 1950b. “The bargaining problem,” 18 Econometrica 155–62.Google Scholar
Nash, John F. 1951. “Non-cooperative games,” 54 Annals of Mathematics 286–95.Google Scholar
Nash, John F. 1953. “Two-person cooperative games,” 21 Econometrica 128–40.Google Scholar
Nelson, Phillip. 1970. “Information and consumer behavior,” 78 Journal of Political Economy 311–29.Google Scholar
Neyman, Jerzy, and Pearson, Egon S.. 1928. “On the use and interpretation of certain test criteria for purposes of statistical inference,” 20 Biometrika 175–240.Google Scholar
North, Douglass C. 1990. “Institutions, Institutional Change and Economic Performance. Cambridge University Press.
Nozick, Robert. 1969. “Newcomb’s problem and two principles of choice,” in Nicholas Rescher (ed.), Essays in Honour of Carl G. Hempel, 107–33. Dordrecht: Reidel.
Nozick, Robert. 1974. Anarchy, State, and Utopia. New York: Basic Books.
Nussbaum, Martha C. 2000. Women and Human Development: The Capabilities Approach. Cambridge University Press.
Nussbaum, Martha C., and Amartya, Sen (eds.). 1993. The Quality of Life. Oxford University Press.
Oates, Wallace E. 1972. Fiscal Federalism. New York: Harcourt Brace Jovanovich.
Oates, Wallace E. 1985. “Searching for Leviathan: an empirical study,” 75 American Economic Review 748–57.Google Scholar
Oi, Walter Y. 1971. “A Disneyland dilemma: two-part tariffs for a Mickey Mouse monopoly,” 85 Quarterly Journal of Economics 77–96.Google Scholar
Olson, Mancur. 1965. The Logic of Collective Action: Public Goods and the Theory of Groups. Boston: Harvard University Press.
Olson, Mancur. 1982. The Rise and Decline of Nations: Economic Growth, Stagflation, and Social Rigidities. New Haven, CT: Yale University Press.
Ostrom, Elinor. 1990. Governing the Commons: The Evolution of Institutions for Collective Action. New York: Cambridge University Press.
Ostrom, Elinor, Gardner, Roy, and Walker, James. 1994. Rules, Games and Common-Pool Resources. Ann Arbor: University of Michigan Press.
Panzar, John C., and Willig, Robert D.. 1977. “Economies of scale in multi-output production,” 91 Quarterly Journal of Economics 481–93.Google Scholar
Parchomovsky, Gideon, and Stein, Alex. 2010. “The distortionary effect of evidence on primary behavior,” 124 Harvard Law Review 518–48.Google Scholar
Pareto, Vilfredo. 1897. “The new theories of economics,” 5 Journal of Political Economy 488–502.Google Scholar
Parisi, Francesco. 2000. “Spontaneous emergence of law: customary law,” in Boudewijn Bouckaert and Gerrit De Geest (eds.). Encyclopedia of Law and Economics, vol. V, The Economics of Crime and Litigation, 603–30. Cheltenham: Edward Elgar.Google Scholar
Parisi, Francesco. 2001. “The genesis of liability in ancient law,” 3 American Law and Economics Review 82–124.Google Scholar
Parisi, Francesco. 2002. “Entropy in property,” 50 American Journal of Comparative Law 595–622.Google Scholar
Parisi, Francesco. 2003. “Political Coase theorem,” 115 Public Choice 1–36.Google Scholar
Parisi, Francesco. 2004. “The harmonization of legal warranties in European sales law: an economic analysis,” 52 American Journal of Comparative Law 403–31.Google Scholar
Parisi, Francesco. 2007. “The fall and rise of functional property,” in Donatella Porrini and Giovanni Ramello (eds.), Property Rights Dynamics: A Law and Economics Perspective, 19–39. Abingdon: Routledge.
Parisi, Francesco, and Fon, Vincy. 2004. “Comparative causation,” 6 American Law and Economics Review, 345–68.Google Scholar
Parisi, Francesco and Fon, Vincy. 2009. The Economics of Lawmaking. Oxford University Press.
Parisi, Francesco, Fon, Vincy, and Ghei, Nita. 2004. “The value of waiting in lawmaking,” 18 European Journal of Law and Economics 131–48.Google Scholar
Parisi, Francesco, Luppi, Barbara, and Fon, Vincy. 2011. “Optimal remedies for bilateral contracts,” 40 Journal of Legal Studies 245–71.Google Scholar
Parisi, Francesco, Schulz, Norbert, and Depoorter, Ben. 2005. “Duality in property: commons and anticommons,” 25 International Review of Law and Economics 578–91.Google Scholar
Parisi, Francesco, Schulz, Norbert, and Klick, Jonathan. 2006. “Two dimensions of regulatory competition,” 26 International Review of Law and Economics 56–66.Google Scholar
Parisi, Francesco, and Singh, Ram. 2010. “The efficiency of comparative causation,” 6 Review of Law and Economics; available at ideas.repec.org/a/bpj/rlecon/v6y2010i2n5.html.Google Scholar
Parisi, Francesco, and von Wangenheim, Georg. 2006. “Legislation and countervailing effects from social norms,” in Christian Schubert and Georg von Wangenheim (eds.), Evolution and Design of Institutions, 25–55. Abingdon: Routledge.
Pearson, Karl. 1905. On the General Theory of Skew Correlation and Non-Linear Regression. London: Dulau.
Peltzman, Sam. 1990. “How efficient is the voting market?,” 33 Journal of Law and Economics 27–63.Google Scholar
Pigou, Arthur C. 1920. The Economics of Welfare. London: Macmillan.
Pindyck, Robert S. 1991. “Irreversibility, uncertainty and investment,” 29 Journal of Economic Literature 1110–48.Google Scholar
Plato, . 1953 [355BC]. The Dialogues of Plato, vol. IV, The Laws (trans. Benjamin Jowett), 4th edn. Oxford: Clarendon Press.
Plott, Charles R., and Zeiler, Kathryn. 2007. “Exchange asymmetries incorrectly interpreted as evidence of endowment effect theory and prospect theory?,” 97 American Economic Review 1449–66.Google Scholar
Polinsky, A. Mitchell. 1980. “Strict liability vs. negligence in a market setting,” 70 American Economic Review 363–70.Google Scholar
Polinsky, A. Mitchell. 1989. An Introduction to Law and Economics, 2nd edn. Boston: Little, Brown.
Polinsky, A. Mitchell and Che, Yeon-Koo. 1991. “Decoupling liability: optimal incentives for care and litigation,” 22 RAND Journal of Economics 562–70.Google Scholar
Polinsky, A. Mitchell, and Shavell, Steven. 2007. “The theory of public enforcement of law,” in A. Mitchell Polinsky and Steven Shavell (eds.), Handbook of Law and Economics, vol. I, 403–54. Amsterdam: North-Holland.
Pollak, Robert A. 1976. “Interdependent preferences,” 66 American Economic Review 309–20.Google Scholar
Popitz, Johannes. 1927. “Der Finanzausgleich,” in Handbuch der Finanzwissenschaft, vol. II, 338–75. Tübingen: T. C. B. Mohr.
Popper, Karl. 1959. The Logic of Scientific Discovery. London: Hutchinson.
Porat, Ariel, and Tabbach, Avraham. 2011. “Willingness to pay, death, wealth, and damages,” 13 American Law and Economics Review 45–102.Google Scholar
Posner, Eric A. 2003. “Probability errors: some positive and normative implications for tort and contract law,” 11 Supreme Court Economic Review 125–41.Google Scholar
Posner, Eric A. 2006. “There are no penalty default rules in contract law,” 33 Florida State University Law Review 563–87.Google Scholar
Posner, Eric A., and Sunstein, Cass R.. 2010. Law and Happiness. University of Chicago Press.
Posner, Richard A. 1975. “The social costs of monopoly and regulation,” 83 Journal of Political Economy 807–27.Google Scholar
Posner, Richard. 1976. Antitrust Law: An Economic Perspective. University of Chicago Press.
Posner, Richard. 1979. “Utilitarianism, economics, and legal theory,” 8 Journal of Legal Studies 103–40.Google Scholar
Posner, Richard. 1981. The Economics of Justice. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.
Posner, Richard A. 1981. “The positive economic theory of tort law,” 15 Georgia Law Review 851–924.Google Scholar
Posner, Richard. 1985. “Wealth maximization revisited,” 2 Notre Dame Journal of Law, Ethics and Public Policy 85–105.Google Scholar
Posner, Richard. 1988. “The ethics of wealth maximization: reply to Malloy,” 36 University of Kansas Law Review 261–5.Google Scholar
Posner, Richard. 1990a. Cardozo: A Study in Reputation. University of Chicago Press.
Posner, Richard. 1990b. The Problems of Jurisprudence. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.
Posner, Richard. 1992a. Sex and Reason. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.
Posner, Richard. 1992b. The Essential Holmes: Selections from the Letters, Speeches, Judicial Opinions, and Other Writings of Oliver Wendell Holmes, Jr. University of Chicago Press.
Posner, Richard. 1994. “What do judges and justices maximize? (The same thing everybody else does),” 3 Supreme Court Economic Review 1–41.Google Scholar
Posner, Richard. 1995. Overcoming Law. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.
Posner, Richard. 1996a. Law and Legal Theory in England and America. Oxford University Press.
Posner, Richard. 1996b. The Federal Courts: Challenge and Reform, rev. edn. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.
Posner, Richard. 1998. Law and Literature, 2nd edn. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.
Posner, Richard. 1999. The Problematics of Moral and Legal Theory. Cambridge, MA: Belknap Press.
Posner, Richard. 2001. Antitrust Law, 2nd edn. University of Chicago Press.
Posner, Richard. 2003. “Law, Pragmatism, and Democracy. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.
Posner, Richard. 2004. Catastrophe: Risk and Response. New York: Oxford University Press.
Posner, Richard. 2005. Preventing Surprise Attacks: Intelligence Reform in the Wake of 9/11. Lanham, MD: Rowman & Littlefield.
Posner, Richard. 2010. Economic Analysis of Law, 8th edn. New York: Aspen Law & Business.
Postema, Gerald J. 1986. Bentham and the Common Law Tradition. New York: Clarendon Press.
Priest, George L. 1977. “The common law process and the selection of efficient rules,” 6 Journal of Legal Studies 65–82.Google Scholar
Priest, George L. 1981. “A theory of the consumer product warranty,” 90 Yale Law Journal 1297–352.Google Scholar
Priest, George L. 1985. “Reexamining the selection hypothesis: learning from Wittman’s mistakes,” 14 Journal of Legal Studies 215–43.Google Scholar
Priest, George L. 2010. “Market share liability in personal injury and public nuisance litigation: an economic analysis,” 18 Supreme Court Economic Review 109–33.Google Scholar
Priest, George L., and Benjamin, Klein. 1984. “The selection of disputes for litigation,” 13 Journal of Legal Studies 1–55.Google Scholar
Pronin, Emily, and Matthew, B. Kugler, . 2007. “Valuing thoughts, ignoring behavior: the introspection illusion as a source of the bias blind spot,” 43 Journal of Experimental Social Psychology 565–78.Google Scholar
Pronin, Emily, Daniel, Y. Lin, , and Lee, Ross. 2002. “The bias blind spot: perceptions of bias in self versus others,” 28 Personality and Social Psychology Bulletin 369–81.Google Scholar
Rabin, Matthew. 1993. “Incorporating fairness into game theory and economics,” 83 American Economic Review 1281–302.Google Scholar
Rabin, Matthew. 2002. “Inference by believers in the law of small numbers,” 117 Quarterly Journal of Economics 775–816.Google Scholar
Rae, John. 1834. Statements of Some New Principles on the Subject of Political Economy. Boston: Hillard, Gray.
Ramsey, Frank P. 1927. “A contribution to the theory of taxation,” 37 Economic Journal 543–59.Google Scholar
Rasmusen, Eric B. 1996. “Stigma and self-fulfilling expectations of criminality,” 39 Journal of Law and Economics 519–44.Google Scholar
Rawls, John B. 1971. A Theory of Justice. Cambridge, MA: Belknap Press.
Rawls, John B. 1993. Political Liberalism. New York: Columbia University Press.
Rawls, John B. 1999. The Law of Peoples. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.
Rawls, John B. 2001. Justice as Fairness: A Restatement. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.
Redelmeier, Donald A., and Daniel, Kahneman. 1996. “Patients’ memories of painful medical treatments: real-time and retrospective evaluations of two minimally invasive procedures,” 66 Pain 3–8.Google Scholar
Regan, Donald H. 1980. Utilitarianism and Co-operation. Oxford: Clarendon Press.
Ricardo, David. 1817. On the Principles of Political Economy and Taxation. London: John Murray.
Riker, William H. 1986. The Art of Political Manipulation. New Haven, CT: Yale University Press.
Rizzo, Mario J., and Arnold, Frank S.. 1980. “Causal apportionment in the law of torts: an economic theory,” 80 Columbia Law Review 1399–429.Google Scholar
Rizzolli, Matteo, and Saraceno, Margherita. 2009. “Better that X guilty persons escape than that one innocent suffer,” Working Paper no. 168, Department of Economics, University of Milan – Bicocca.
Robbins, Lionel. 1935. An Essay on the Nature and Significance of Economic Science, 2nd edn. London: Macmillan.
Robinson, Joan. 1933. The Economics of Imperfect Competition. London: Macmillan.
Rochet, Jean-Charles, and Tirole, Jean. 2004. “Two-sided markets: An overview,” working paper, Institut d’Economie Industrielle, Toulouse.
Rose, Carol M. 1985. “Possession as the origin of property,” 52 University of Chicago Law Review 73–88.Google Scholar
Rose, Carol. 1994. Property and Persuasion: Essays on the History, Theory, and Rhetoric of Ownership. Boulder, CO: Westview.
Rothschild, Michael, and Stiglitz, Joseph. 1976. “Equilibrium in competitive insurance markets: an essay on the economics of imperfect information,” 90 Quarterly Journal of Economics 629–49.Google Scholar
Rowley, Charles K. 1984. “The relevance of the median voter theorem,” 140 Journal of Institutional and Theoretical Economics 104–26.Google Scholar
Rowley, Charles. 1989. “The common law in public perspective: a theoretical and institutional critique,” 12 Hamline Law Review 355–83.Google Scholar
Rubin, Paul H. 1977. “Why is the common law efficient?,” 6 Journal of Legal Studies 51–63.Google Scholar
Salop, Steven C. 1979. “Monopolistic competition with outside goods,” 10 Bell Journal of Economics 141–56.Google Scholar
Samuelson, Paul A. 1938. “A note on the pure theory of consumer’s behaviour,” 5 Economica 61–71.Google Scholar
Samuelson, Paul A. 1950. “The problem of integrability in utility theory,” 17 Economica 355–85.Google Scholar
Samuelson, Paul A. 1954. “The pure theory of public expenditure,” 36 Review of Economics and Statistics 387–9.Google Scholar
Samuelson, Paul A. 1955. “Diagrammatic exposition of a theory of public expenditure,” 37 Review of Economics and Statistics 350–6.Google Scholar
Sanchirico, Chris W. 2000. “Taxes versus legal rules as instruments for equity: a more equitable view,” 29 Journal of Legal Studies 797–820.Google Scholar
Sandler, Todd. 2001. “On financing global and international public goods,” Policy Research Working Paper no. 2638, World Bank, Washington, DC.
Sandler, Todd. 2006. “Regional public goods and international organizations,” 1 Review of International Organizations 5–25.Google Scholar
Schelling, Thomas C. 1960. The Strategy of Conflict. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.
Schelling, Thomas C. 1966. Arms and Influence. New Haven, CT: Yale University Press.
Schkade, David, Sunstein, Cass R., and Kahneman, Daniel. 2000. “Do people want optimal deterrence?,” 29 Journal of Legal Studies 237–53.Google Scholar
Schulz, Norbert, Parisi, Francesco, and Depoorter, Ben. 2002. “Fragmentation in property: towards a general model,” 158 Journal of Institutional and Theoretical Economics 594–613.Google Scholar
Schumpeter, Joseph A. 1994 [1942]. Capitalism, Socialism and Democracy. London: Routledge.
Schweizer, Urs. 2006. “Cooperative investments induced by contract law,” 37 RAND Journal of Economics 134–45.Google Scholar
Scitovsky, Tibor. 1941. “A note on welfare propositions in economics,” 9 Review of Economic Studies 77–88.Google Scholar
Scott, Robert E., and Kraus, Jody S.. 2007. Contract Law and Theory, 4th edn. Newark, NJ: Matthew Bender.
Scott, Robert Haney. 1972. “Avarice, altruism, and second party preferences,” 86 Quarterly Journal of Economics 1–18.Google Scholar
Seidmann, Daniel. 2005. “The effects of the right to silence,” 72 Review of Economic Studies 593–614.Google Scholar
Seidmann, Daniel, and Stein, Alex. 2000. “The right to silence helps the innocent: a game-theoretic analysis of the Fifth Amendment privilege,” 114 Harvard Law Review 430–510.Google Scholar
Selten, Reinhard. 1975. “Re-examination of the perfectness concept for equilibrium points in extensive games,” 4 International Journal of Game Theory 25–55.Google Scholar
Selten, Reinhard. 1978. “The chain store paradox,” 9 Theory and Decision 127–59.Google Scholar
Sen, Amartya. 1970a. Collective Choice and Social Welfare. San Francisco: Holden-Day.
Sen, Amartya. 1970b. “The impossibility of a Paretian liberal,” 78 Journal of Political Economy 152–7.Google Scholar
Sen, Amartya. 1977. “Rational fools: a critique of the behavioral foundations of economic theory,” 6 Philosophy and Public Affairs 317–44.Google Scholar
Sen, Amartya. 1985. Commodities and Capabilities. Oxford: Elsevier.
Sen, Amartya. 1989. “Development as capability expansion,” 19 Journal of Development Planning 41–58.Google Scholar
Sen, Amartya. 1993. “Capability and well-being,” in Martha Nussbaum and Amartya Sen (eds.), The Quality of Life, 30–53. Oxford University Press.
Shapley, Lloyd S., and Shubik, Martin. 1954. “A method for evaluating the distribution of power in a committee system,” 48 American Political Science Review 787–92.Google Scholar
Shavell, Steven M. 1980a. “Damage measures for breach of contract,” 11 Bell Journal of Economics 466–90.Google Scholar
Shavell, Steven M. 1980b. “Strict liability versus negligence,” 9 Journal of Legal Studies 1–25.Google Scholar
Shavell, Steven M. 1986. “The judgment proof problem,” 6 International Review of Law and Economics 45–58.Google Scholar
Shavell, Steven M. 1987. Economic Analysis of Accident Law. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.
Shavell, Steven M. 2003. “Economic analysis of accident law,” Working Paper no. 9694, National Bureau of Economic Research, Cambridge, MA.
Shavell, Steven M. 2004. Foundations of Economic Analysis of Law. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.
Shepsle, Kenneth A. 1979. “Institutional arrangements and equilibrium in multidimensional voting models,” 23 American Journal of Political Science 23–57.Google Scholar
Siegelman, Peter. 2004. “Adverse selection in insurance markets: an exaggerated threat,” 113 Yale Law Journal 1223–81.Google Scholar
Simon, Herbert A. 1956. “Rational choice and the structure of the environment,” 63 Psychological Review 129–38.Google Scholar
Simons, Kenneth W. 1995. “The puzzling doctrine of contributory negligence,” 16 Cardozo Law Review 1693–748.Google Scholar
Singh, Nirvikar, and Vives, Xavier. 1984. “Price and quantity competition in a differentiated duopoly,” 15 RAND Journal of Economics 546–54.Google Scholar
Smeed, Reuben J. 1949. “Some statistical aspects of road safety research,” 112 Journal of the Royal Statistical Society 1–34.Google Scholar
Smith, Adam. 1759. The Theory of Moral Sentiments. London: A. Millar.
Smith, Adam. 1776. An Inquiry into the Nature and Causes of the Wealth of Nations. London: Strahan & Cadell.
Spence, A. Michael. 1973. “Job market signaling,” 87 Quarterly Journal of Economics 355–74.Google Scholar
Stanley, Linda R., and Don, L. Coursey. 1990. “Empirical evidence on the selection hypothesis and the decision to litigate or settle,” 19 Journal of Legal Studies 145–72.Google Scholar
Stevenson, Betsey, and Justin, Wolfers. 2006. “Bargaining in the shadow of the law: divorce laws and family distress,” 121 Quarterly Journal of Economics 267–88.Google Scholar
Stigler, George J. 1950. Five Lectures on Economic Problems. London: Macmillan.
Stigler, George J. 1965. Essays in the History of Economics. University of Chicago Press.
Stigler, George J. 1966. The Theory of Price, 3rd edn. New York: Macmillan.
Stanley, Linda R., and Don, L. Coursey. 1969. The Organization of Industry. University of Chicago Press.
Stigler, George. 1970. “The optimum enforcement of law,” 78 Journal of Political Economy 526–36.Google Scholar
Stigler, George. 1971. “The theory of economic regulation,” 3 Bell Journal of Economics and Management Science 3–18.Google Scholar
Stigler, George. 1975. The Citizen and the State: Essays on Regulation. University of Chicago Press.
Stigler, George. 1986. The Essence of Stigler (eds. Kurt R. Leube and Thomas G. Hoore). Stanford CA: Hoover Institution Press.
Stigler, George. 1988. Memoirs of an Unregulated Economist. New York: Basic Books.
Stiglitz, Joseph E. 1974. “Alternative theories of wage determination and unemployment in LDCs: the labor turnover model,” 88 Quarterly Journal of Economics 194–227.Google Scholar
Stiglitz, Joseph E. 1976. “The efficiency wage hypothesis, surplus labor and the distribution of income in LDCs,” 28 Oxford Economic Papers 185–207.Google Scholar
Stiglitz, Joseph E. 2002. “Information and the change in the paradigm in economics,” 92 American Economic Review 460–501.Google Scholar
Strazzella, James A. 1997. “The relationship of double jeopardy to prosecution appeals,” 73 Notre Dame Law Review 1–30.Google Scholar
Stremitzer, Alexander, and Tabbach, Avraham. 2009. “Insolvency and biased standards: the case for proportional liability,” Faculty Scholarship. Paper no. 24, Yale Law School, New Haven, CT.Google Scholar
Stuntz, William J. 2000. “Self-defeating crimes,” 86 Virginia Law Review 1871–99.Google Scholar
Sunstein, Cass R. 1996. “Social norms and social roles,” 96 Columbia Law Review 903–68.Google Scholar
Sunstein, Cass R. (ed.). 2000. Behavioral Law and Economics. Cambridge University Press.
Takenaka, Toshiko. 2008. Patent Law and Theory: A Handbook of Contemporary Research. Northampton, MA: Edward Elgar.
Taylor, Shelley E., and Brown, Jonathon D.. 1988. “Illusion and well-being: a social psychological perspective on mental health,” 103 Psychological Bulletin 193–210.Google Scholar
Taylor, Timothy. 2011. Principles of Economics, 2nd edn. Minneapolis: Textbook Media Press.
Thaler, Richard. 1980. “Toward a positive theory of consumer choice,” 1 Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization 39–60.Google Scholar
Tiebout, Charles. 1956. “A pure theory of local expenditures,” 64 Journal of Political Economy 416–24.Google Scholar
Tirole, Jean, and Benabou, Roland. 2006. “Incentives and prosocial behavior,” 96 American Economic Review 1652–78.Google Scholar
Tobin, James. 1974. “Prospects for macro-economic policy,” in The New Economics, One Decade Older, 71–96. Princeton University Press.
Tollison, Robert D. 1982. “Rent seeking: a survey,” 35 Kyklos 575–602.Google Scholar
Trebilcock, Michael J. 1993. The Limits of Freedom of Contract. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.
Trimarchi, Pietro. 2003. “Transfers, uncertainty and the cost of disruption,” 23 International Review of Law and Economics 49–62.Google Scholar
Tucker, Albert W. 1950. “A two-person dilemma,” unpublished notes, Stanford University, CA.
Tullock, Gordon. 1967. “The welfare costs of monopolies, tariffs, and theft,” 5 Western Economic Journal 224–32.Google Scholar
Tullock, Gordon. 1971a. “The charity of the uncharitable,” 9 Western Economic Journal 379–92.Google Scholar
Tullock, Gordon. 1971b. The Logic of the Law. New York: Basic Books.
Tullock, Gordon. 1980. Trials on Trial: The Pure Theory of Legal Procedure. New York: Columbia University Press.
Tullock, Gordon. 1993. Rent Seeking. Brookfield, VT: Edward Elgar.
Tullock, Gordon. 1980. “Efficient rent-seeking,” in Buchanan, James M., Tollison, Robert D., and Tullock, Gordon, Toward a Theory of the Rent-Seeking Society, 97–112. College Station: Texas A&M University Press.
Tversky, Amos, and Kahneman, Daniel. 1974. “Judgment under uncertainty: heuristics and biases,” 185 Science 1124–31.Google Scholar
Tversky, Amos, and Kahneman, Daniel. 1991. “Loss aversion in riskless choice: a reference-dependent model.” 106 Quarterly Journal of Economics 1039–61.Google Scholar
Tyler, Tom R. 1990. Why People Obey the Law. New Haven, CT: Yale University Press.
Van den Hauwe, Ludwig. 2005. “Public choice, constitutional political economy and law and economics,” in Boudemijn Bouckaert and Gerrit De Geest (eds.), Encyclopedia of Law and Economics, vol. I, The History and Methodology of Low and Economics, 603–59. Cheltenham: Edward Elgar.Google Scholar
Vickrey, William. 1945. “Measuring marginal utility by reactions to risk,” 13 Econometrica 319–33.Google Scholar
Vickrey, William. 1961. “Counterspeculation, auctions, and competitive sealed tenders,” 16 Journal of Finance 8–37.Google Scholar
Volokh, Alexander. 1997. “N guilty men,” 146 University of Pennsylvania Law Review 173–216.Google Scholar
Von Neumann, John, and Morgenstern, Oskar. 1944. Theory of Games and Economic Behavior. Princeton University Press.
Von Stackelberg, Heinrich 1934. Marktform und Gleichgewicht [Market Structure and Equilibrium]. Vienna: Julius Springer.
Wagner, Richard E. 2004. “Meddlesome preferences and rent extraction: the tobacco shakedown,” in Rowley, Charles K. and Schneider, Friedrich (eds.), The Encyclopedia of Public Choice, 378–80. Dordrecht: Kluwer Academic.
Wanniski, Jude. 1978. “Taxes, revenues, and the ‘Laffer curve,’” 50 The Public Interest 3–16.Google Scholar
Wayburn, Laurie A., and Chiono, Anton. 2010. “The role of federal policy in establishing ecosystem service markets,” 20 Duke Environmental Law and Policy Forum 385–415.Google Scholar
Weisbach, David A. 2008. “What does happiness research tell us about taxation?,” 37 Journal of Legal Studies 293–324.Google Scholar
Williamson, Oliver E. 1964. The Economics of Discretionary Behavior: Managerial Objectives in a Theory of the Firm. Englewood Cliffs, NJ: Prentice Hall.
Williamson, Oliver E. 1968. “Economies as an antitrust defense: the welfare trade-offs,” 58 American Economic Review 18–36.Google Scholar
Williamson, Oliver E. 1970. Corporate Control and Business Behavior: An Inquiry into the Effects of Organization Form on Enterprise Behavior. Englewood Cliffs, NJ: Prentice Hall.
Williamson, Oliver E. 1975. Markets and Hierarchies: Analysis and Antitrust Implications. New York: Free Press.
Williamson, Oliver E. 1979. “Transaction-cost economics: the governance of contractual relations,” 22 Journal of Law and Economics 233–61.Google Scholar
Williamson, Oliver E. 1983. “Credible commitments: using hostages to support exchange,” 73 American Economics Review 519–40.Google Scholar
Williamson, Oliver E. 1985. The Economic Institutions of Capitalism: Firms, Markets, Relational Contracting. New York: Free Press.
Williamson, Oliver E. 1991. “Comparative economic organization: the analysis of discrete structural alternatives,” 36 Administrative Science Quarterly 269–96.Google Scholar
Williamson, Oliver E. 1996. The Mechanisms of Governance. Oxford University Press.
Williamson, Oliver E. 2002. “The theory of the firm as governance structure: from choice to contract,” 16 Journal of Economic Perspectives 171–95.Google Scholar
Williamson, Oliver E. 2005. “The economics of governance,” 95 American Economic Review 1–18.Google Scholar
Wittman, Donald A. 1984. “Liability for harm or restitution of benefit?13 Journal of Legal Studies 57–80.Google Scholar
Yablon, Charles M. 2007. “The historical race: competition for corporate charters and the rise and decline of New Jersey: 1880–1910,” 32 Journal of Corporation Law 323–80.Google Scholar
Zermelo, Ernst. 1913. “Uber eine Anwendung der Mengenlehre auf die Theorie des Schachspiels,” in E. W. Hobson and A. E. H. Love (eds.), Proceedings of the Fifth International Congress of Mathematicians, vol. II, 501–4. Cambridge University Press.

Save book to Kindle

To save this book to your Kindle, first ensure coreplatform@cambridge.org is added to your Approved Personal Document E-mail List under your Personal Document Settings on the Manage Your Content and Devices page of your Amazon account. Then enter the ‘name’ part of your Kindle email address below. Find out more about saving to your Kindle.

Note you can select to save to either the @free.kindle.com or @kindle.com variations. ‘@free.kindle.com’ emails are free but can only be saved to your device when it is connected to wi-fi. ‘@kindle.com’ emails can be delivered even when you are not connected to wi-fi, but note that service fees apply.

Find out more about the Kindle Personal Document Service.

  • References
  • Francesco Parisi, University of Minnesota
  • Book: The Language of Law and Economics
  • Online publication: 04 August 2017
  • Chapter DOI: https://doi.org/10.1017/CBO9781139034043.002
Available formats
×

Save book to Dropbox

To save content items to your account, please confirm that you agree to abide by our usage policies. If this is the first time you use this feature, you will be asked to authorise Cambridge Core to connect with your account. Find out more about saving content to Dropbox.

  • References
  • Francesco Parisi, University of Minnesota
  • Book: The Language of Law and Economics
  • Online publication: 04 August 2017
  • Chapter DOI: https://doi.org/10.1017/CBO9781139034043.002
Available formats
×

Save book to Google Drive

To save content items to your account, please confirm that you agree to abide by our usage policies. If this is the first time you use this feature, you will be asked to authorise Cambridge Core to connect with your account. Find out more about saving content to Google Drive.

  • References
  • Francesco Parisi, University of Minnesota
  • Book: The Language of Law and Economics
  • Online publication: 04 August 2017
  • Chapter DOI: https://doi.org/10.1017/CBO9781139034043.002
Available formats
×