Skip to main content Accessibility help
×
Hostname: page-component-7479d7b7d-rvbq7 Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-07-11T06:49:57.501Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

THREE - Political Economy of Agricultural Distortions

The Literature to Date

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  05 July 2011

Johan F. M. Swinnen
Affiliation:
Katholieke Universiteit Leuven in Belgium
Kym Anderson
Affiliation:
University of Adelaide
Get access

Summary

The 1980s and the first half of the 1990s were a very active period in the field of political economy of agricultural protection and distortions. The research was triggered by a combination of factors. First and foremost, there was the puzzling question: Why was agriculture supported in rich countries and taxed in poor countries? Second, emerging general theories of “new political economy” were coming out from the University of Chicago with the important contributions of Stigler (1971), Peltzman (1976) and Becker (1983), from the public choice school by Buchanan and Tullock (1962), and from the influential work by Downs (1957) and Olson (1965). A third factor was the arrival of new data, in particular the developing country dataset assembled as part of the World Bank study organized by Krueger, Schiff and Valdés (1988, 1991) and the high-income dataset compiled by Anderson, Hayami and Others (1986). The combination of an intriguing question, a rich set of new general theories to apply, and fascinating data induced a rich and vast literature on the political economy of agricultural distortions in the 1980s and the first part of the 1990s, with important contributions by, among others, Kym Anderson, Robert Bates, Harry de Gorter, Bruce Gardner, Yujiro Hayami, and Gordon Rausser. In our chapter for the Handbook of Agricultural Economics, Harry de Gorter and I reviewed most of this empirical and theoretical literature on the political economy of agricultural economics (de Gorter and Swinnen 2002).

Type
Chapter
Information
Publisher: Cambridge University Press
Print publication year: 2010

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

References

Acemoglu, D., Johnson, S. and Robinson, J.A. (2001), “The Colonial Origins of Comparative Development: An Empirical Investigation,”American Economic Review 91(5): 1369–1401.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Acemoglu, D. and Robinson, J.A. (2000), “Why Did the West Extend the Franchise? Growth, Inequality and Democracy in Historical Perspective,”Quarterly Journal of Economics 65: 1167–99.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Acemoglu, D. and Robinson, J.A. (2001), “A Theory of Political Transitions,”American Economic Review 91: 938–63.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Acemoglu, D. and Robinson, J.A. (2006), Economic Origins of Dictatorship and Democracy, Cambridge and New York: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Aghion, P., Alesina, A. and Trebbi, F. (2004), “Endogenous Political Institutions,”Quarterly Journal of Economics 119(2): 565–612.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Anania, G., Bohman, M.E., Carter, C.A. and McCalla, A.F. (eds.) (2004), Agricultural Policy Reform and the WTO: Where Are We Heading?London: Edward Elgar.
Anderson, K. (1995), “Lobbying Incentives and the Pattern of Protection in Rich and Poor Countries,”Economic Development and Cultural Change 43(2): 401–23.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Anderson, K. (ed.), (2009), Distortions to Agricultural Incentives: A Global Perspective, 1955–2007, London: Palgrave Macmillan and Washington DC: World Bank.CrossRef
Anderson, K., Hayami, Y. and Others (1986), The Political Economy of Agricultural Protection: East Asia in International Perspective, London and Boston: Allen and Unwin.Google Scholar
Anderson, K., Lloyd, P.J. and MacLaren, D. (2007),”Distortions to Agricultural Incentives in Australia Since World War II,”The Economic Record 83(263): 461–82.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Anderson, K., and Martin, W. (eds.) (2009), Distortions to Agricultural Incentives in Asia, Washington, DC: World Bank.CrossRef
Anderson, K., and Masters, W. (eds.) (2009), Distortions to Agricultural Incentives in Africa, Washington, DC: World Bank.CrossRef
Anderson, K., and Swinnen, J.F.M. (eds.) (2008), Distortions to Agricultural Incentives in Europe's Transition Economies, Washington, DC: World Bank.CrossRef
Anderson, K., and Valdés, A. (eds.) (2008), Distortions to Agricultural Incentives in Latin America, Washington, DC: World Bank.CrossRef
Anderson, K. and Valenzuela, E. (2008), Global Estimates of Distortions to Agricultural Incentives, 1955 to 2007, database available at http://www.worldbank.org/agdistortionsGoogle Scholar
Bagwell, K. and Staiger, R.W. (2002), The Economics of the World Trading System, Cambridge MA: MIT Press.Google Scholar
Baldwin, R. and Robert-Nicoud, F. (2007), “Entry and Asymmetric Lobbying: Why Governments Picks Losers,”Journal of the European Economic Association 5(5): 1064–93.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Baron, D.P. and Ferejohn, J.A. (1989), “Bargaining in Legislatures,”American Political Science Review 83 (4): 1181–1206.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bates, R.H. (1983), “Patterns of Market Intervention in Agrarian Africa,”Food Policy 8(4): 297–304.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bates, R.H. (1989), Beyond the Miracle of the Market: The Political Economy of Agrarian Development in Rural Kenya, Cambridge and New York: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Bates, R.H. and Rogerson, W.P. (1980), “Agriculture in Development: A Coalition Analysis,”Public Choice 35: 513–27.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Beck, T., Clarke, G., Groff, A., Keefer, P. and Walsh, P. (2001), “New Tools in Comparative Political Economy: The Database of Political Institutions,”World Bank Economic Review 15(1): 165–76.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Becker, G. (1983), “A Theory of Competition Among Pressure Groups for Political Influence,”Quarterly Journal of Economics 98: 371–400, August.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Beghin, J.C. and Kherallah, M. (1994), “Political Institutions and International Patterns of Agricultural Protection,”Review of Economics and Statistics 76(3): 482–9.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Belloc, M. and Guerrieri, P. (2008), “Special Interest Groups and Trade Policy in the EU,”Open Economies Review 19(4): 457–78.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bombardini, M. (2005), “Firm Heterogeneity and Lobby Participation,” mimeo, University of British Columbia, Vancouver.
Buchanan, J.M. and Tullock, G. (1962), The Calculus of Consent, Ann Arbor: University of Michigan Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Cadot, O., Melo, J. and Olarreaga, M. (2004), “Lobbying, Counter-lobbying, and the Structure of Tariff Protection in Poor and Rich Countries,”World Bank Economic Review 18(3): 345–66.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Corden, W.M. (1974), Trade Policy and Economic Welfare, Oxford: Clarendon Press.Google Scholar
Gorter, H. (2008), “Agricultural Instrument Choice”, Agricultural Distortions Working Paper 75, World Bank, Washington DC, available at http://www.worldbank.org/agdistortions
Gorter, H., Nielson, D.J. and Rausser, G.C. (1992), “Productive and Predatory Public Policies: Research Expenditures and Producer Subsidies in Agriculture,”American Journal of Agricultural Economics 74(1): 27–37.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Gorter, H. and Swinnen, J.F.M. (2002), “Political Economy of Agricultural Policies,” pp. 2073–123 in Gardner, B. and Rausser, G. (eds.), Handbook of Agricultural Economics, Volume 2, Amsterdam: Elsevier Science.Google Scholar
Gorter, H. and Tsur, Y. (1991), “Explaining Price Policy Bias in Agriculture: The Calculus of Support-Maximizing Politicians”, American Journal of Agricultural Economics 73(4): 1244–54.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Dewan, T. and Shepsle, K. (2008a), “Recent Economic Perspectives on Political Economy: Part I,”British Journal of Political Science 38(2): 363–82.Google Scholar
Dewan, T. and Shepsle, K. (2008b), “Recent Economic Perspectives on Political Economy: Part II,”British Journal of Political Science 38(3): 543–64.Google Scholar
Downs, A. (1957), An Economic Theory of Democracy, New York: Harper and Row.Google Scholar
Dutt, P. and Mitra, D. (2002), “Endogenous Trade Policy Through Majority Voting: An Empirical Investigation,”Journal of International Economics 58(1): 107–33.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Dutt, P. and Mitra, D. (2005), “Political Ideology and Endogenous Trade Policy: An Empirical Investigation,”Review of Economics and Statistics 87(1): 59–72.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Dutt, P. and Mitra, D. (2007), “Political Economy of Agricultural Protection: A Framework,” Paper presented at the World Bank workshop on the political economy of agricultural distortions, Portland, OR.
Dutt, P. and Mitra, D. (2009), “Impacts of Ideology, Inequality, Lobbying, and Public Finance,” Ch. 11 in this volume.
Facchini, G., Biesebrouck, J. and Willmann, G. (2006), “Protection for Sale with Imperfect Rent Capturing,”Canadian Journal of Economics 39: 845–73.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Francois, J.F., Nelson, D. and Pelkmans-Balaoing, A. (2008), “Endogenous Protection in General Equilibrium: Estimating Political Weights in the EU,” CEPR Discussion Paper 6979, London, October.
Gardner, B.L. (1987), “Causes of U.S. Farm Commodity Programs,”Journal of Political Economy 95(2): 290–310.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Gawande, K. and Bandyopadhyay, U. (2000), “Is Protection for Sale? Evidence on the Grossman-Helpman Theory of Endogenous Protection,”Review of Economics and Statistics 82(1): 139–52.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Gawande, K. and Hoekman, B. (2006), “Lobbying and Agricultural Trade Policy in the United States,”International Organization 60: 527–61.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Gawande, K. and Krishna, P. (2003), “The Political Economy of Trade Policy: Empirical Approaches,” pp. 213–50 in Choi, E.K. and Harrigan, J. (eds.), Handbook of International Trade, Oxford: Blackwell Publishing.Google Scholar
Gawande, K. and Li, H. (2004), “The Case of the Missing Contributions,” Working Paper, Texas A&M University, College Station TX.
Gawande, K., Sanguinetti, P. and Bohara, A.K. (2005), “Exclusions for Sale: Evidence on the Grossman-Helpman Model of Free Trade Agreements,” NAFTA-MERCOSUR Working Paper No. 4, University of New Mexico.
Goldberg, P. and Maggi, G. (1999), “Protection for Sale: An Empirical Investigation,”American Economic Review 89(5): 1135–55.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Grossman, G.M. and Helpman, E. (1994), “Protection for Sale,”American Economic Review 84(4): 833–50.Google Scholar
Grossman, G.M. and Helpman, E. (1995), “Trade Wars and Trade Talks,”Journal of Political Economy 103(4): 675–708.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Grossman, G.M. and Helpman, E. (2001), Special Interest Politics, Cambridge MA: MIT Press.Google Scholar
Grossman, G.M. and Helpman, E. (2002), Interest Groups and Trade Policy, Princeton NJ: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Hillman, A.L. (1982), “Declining Industries and Political-Support Protectionist Motives,”American Economic Review 72(5): 1180–7.Google Scholar
Hillman, A.L. (1989), The Political Economy of Protection, London: Taylor and Francis.Google Scholar
Honma, M. and Hayami, Y. (1986), “The Determinants of Agricultural Protection Levels: An Econometric Analysis,” Ch. 4 in Anderson, K., Hayami, Y. and Others, The Political Economy of Agricultural Protection: East Asia in International Perspective, London: Allen and Unwin.Google Scholar
Kaufmann, D., Kraay, A. and Mastruzzi, M. (2003), “Governance Matters III: Governance Indicators for 1996–2002”, Policy Research Working Paper No. 3106, World Bank, Washington DC.
Krueger, A.O. (1974), “The Political Economy of the Rent-seeking Society,”American Economic Review 64(3): 291–303.Google Scholar
Krueger, A.O., Schiff, M., and Valdés, A. (1988), “Agricultural Incentives in Developing Countries: Measuring the Effect of Sectoral and Economywide Policies,”World Bank Economic Review 2(3): 255–72.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Krueger, A.O., Schiff, M. and Valdés, A. (1991), The Political Economy of Agricultural Pricing Policy, London: Johns Hopkins University Press for the World Bank.Google Scholar
Ferrara, E. (2002), “Inequality and Group Participation: Theory and Evidence from Rural Tanzania,”Journal of Public Economics 85(2): 235–73.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lindert, P.H. (1991), “Historical Patterns of Agricultural Policy,” in Timmer, C. (ed.), Agriculture and the State: Growth, Employment, and Poverty, Ithaca NY: Cornell University Press.Google Scholar
Lopez, R.A. (2008), “Does ‘Protection for Sale’ Apply to the US Food Industries?”Journal of Agricultural Economics 9(1): 25–40.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lopez, R.A. and Matschke, X. (2006), “Food Protection for Sale,”Review of International Economics 14(3): 380–91, August.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Mayda, A.M. and Rodrik, D. (2005), “Why Are Some People (And Countries) More Protectionist Than Others?”European Economic Review 49(6): 1393–1430.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Mitra, D. (1999), “Endogenous Lobby Formation and Endogenous Protection: A Long-run Model of Trade Policy Determination”, American Economic Review 89(5): 1116–34.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Mitra, D., Thomakos, D.D. and Ulubasoglu, M. (2006), “Can We Obtain Realistic Parameter Estimates for the ‘Protection for Sale’ Model?”Canadian Journal of Economics 39(1): 187–210.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
North, D.C., Wallis, J.J. and Weingast, B.R. (2009), Violence and Social Orders: A Conceptual Framework for Interpreting Recorded Human History, Cambridge and New York: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Olper, A. (2001), “Determinants of Agricultural Protection: The Role of Democracy and Institutional Setting,”Journal of Agricultural Economics 52(2): 75–92.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Olper, A. (2007), “Land Inequality, Government Ideology and Agricultural Protection,”Food Policy 32(1): 67–83.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Olson, M. (1965), The Logic of Collective Action, New Haven: Yale University Press.Google Scholar
O'Rourke, K. and J. Taylor, (2007), “Democracy and Protection”, in The New Comparative Economic History: Essays in Honor of Jeffrey G. Williamson, edited by Hatton, T., O'Rourke, K.H. and Taylor, A.M., Cambridge MA: MIT Press.Google Scholar
Peltzman, S. (1976), “Towards a More General Theory of Regulation,”Journal of Law and Economics 19: 211–40, August.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Persson, T. and Tabellini, G.E. (2000), Political Economics: Explaining Economic Policy, Cambridge MA: MIT Press.Google Scholar
Persson, T. and Tabellini, G.E. (2003), The Economic Effects of Constitutions: What Do the Data Say? Cambridge MA: MIT Press.Google Scholar
Pokrivcak, J., Crombez, C., and Swinnen, J.F.M. (2006), “The Status Quo Bias and Reform of the Common Agricultural Policy: Impact of Voting Rules, the European Commission, and External Changes,”European Review of Agricultural Economics 33(4): 562–90.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Prendergast, C. (2007), “The Motivation and Bias of Bureaucrats”, American Economic Review 97(1): 180–96.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Rausser, G.C. (1982), “Political Economic Markets: PERTs and PESTs in Food and Agriculture”, American Journal of Agricultural Economics 64(5): 821–33.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Rausser, G.C. and Roland, G. (2010), “Special Interests Versus the Public Interest in Policy Determination”, Ch. 3 in Anderson, K. (ed.), Distortions to Agricultural Incentives: A Global Perspective, 1955–2007, London: Palgrave Macmillan and Washington DC: World Bank.
Rausser, G.C., Swinnen, J.F.M. and Zusman, P. (2010), Political Power and Endogenous Policy Formation, Cambridge and New York: Cambridge University Press (forthcoming).Google Scholar
Rodrik, D. (1995), “Political Economy of Trade Policy,” pp. 1457–94 in Grossman, G.M. and Rogoff, K. (eds.), Handbook of International Economics, Vol, 3, Amsterdam: North-Holland.Google Scholar
Roelfsema, H. (2004), “Political Institutions and Trade Protection,” Tjalling C. Koopmans Research Institute Working Paper No. 04–06. Universiteit Utrecht, Utrecht.
Rogowski, R. and Kayser, M.A. (2002), “Majoritarian Electoral Systems and Consumer Power: Price-Level Evidence from the OECD Countries,”American Journal of Political Science 46(3): 526–39.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Roland, G. (2000), Transition and Economics: Politics, Markets and Firms, Cambridge MA: MIT Press.Google Scholar
Shleifer, A. (1997), “Government in Transition,”European Economic Review 41(3–5): 385–410.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Stigler, G.S. (1971), “The Theory of Economic Regulation,”Bell Journal of Economics and Management Science 2: 137–46, Spring.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Swinnen, J.F.M. (1994), “A Positive Theory of Agricultural Protection,”American Journal of Agricultural Economics 76(1): 1–14.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Swinnen, J.F.M. (2002), “Political Reforms, Rural Crises, and Land Tenure in Western Europe,”Food Policy 27(4): 371–94.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Swinnen, J.F.M. (2009), “Agricultural Protection Growth in Europe, 1870–1969”, Ch. 6 in Anderson, K. (ed.), Distortions to Agricultural Incentives: A Global Perspective, 1955–2007, London: Palgrave Macmillan and Washington DC: World Bank.Google Scholar
Swinnen, J.F.M., Banerjee, A.N and Gorter, H. (2001), “Economic Development, Institutional Change, and the Political Economy of Agricultural Protection: An Econometric Study of Belgium Since the 19th Century,”Agricultural Economics 26(1): 25–43.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Swinnen, J.F.M., Gorter, H., Rausser, G.C., and Banerjee, A. (2000), “The Political Economy of Public Research Investment and Commodity Policies in Agriculture: An Empirical Study,”Agricultural Economics 22: 111–22CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Swinnen, J.F.M. and Gorter, H. (1993), “Why Small Groups and Low Income Sectors Obtain Subsidies: The ‘Altruistic’ Side of a ‘Self-Interested’ Government,”Economics and Politics 5(3): 285–96.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Swinnen, J.F.M. and Rozelle, S. (2006), From Marx and Mao to the Market: The Economics and Politics of Agricultural Transition, London and New York: Oxford University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Thies, C.G. and Porche, S. (2007), “The Political Economy of Agricultural Protection,”Journal of Politics 69(1): 116–27.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Tracy, M. (1989), Government and Agriculture in Western Europe 1880–1988, 3rd ed., New York: Harvester Wheatsheaf.Google Scholar
Valenzuela, E. and Anderson, K. (2008), “Alternative Agricultural Price Distortions for CGE Analysis of Developing Countries, 2004 and 1980–84,” GTAP Research Memorandum No. 13, December. Available at http://www.gtap.agecon.purdue.edu/resources
Weingast, B.R. and Wittman, D. (eds.) (2006), The Oxford Handbook of Political Economy, London and New York: Oxford University Press.
,World Bank (2008), World Development Report 2008, Washington DC: World Bank.Google Scholar

Save book to Kindle

To save this book to your Kindle, first ensure coreplatform@cambridge.org is added to your Approved Personal Document E-mail List under your Personal Document Settings on the Manage Your Content and Devices page of your Amazon account. Then enter the ‘name’ part of your Kindle email address below. Find out more about saving to your Kindle.

Note you can select to save to either the @free.kindle.com or @kindle.com variations. ‘@free.kindle.com’ emails are free but can only be saved to your device when it is connected to wi-fi. ‘@kindle.com’ emails can be delivered even when you are not connected to wi-fi, but note that service fees apply.

Find out more about the Kindle Personal Document Service.

Available formats
×

Save book to Dropbox

To save content items to your account, please confirm that you agree to abide by our usage policies. If this is the first time you use this feature, you will be asked to authorise Cambridge Core to connect with your account. Find out more about saving content to Dropbox.

Available formats
×

Save book to Google Drive

To save content items to your account, please confirm that you agree to abide by our usage policies. If this is the first time you use this feature, you will be asked to authorise Cambridge Core to connect with your account. Find out more about saving content to Google Drive.

Available formats
×