Skip to main content Accessibility help
×
Hostname: page-component-848d4c4894-pjpqr Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-06-27T17:02:27.546Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

1 - Interwar Central Banks

A Tour d’ Horizon

from Part I - General

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  02 November 2023

Barry Eichengreen
Affiliation:
University of California, Berkeley
Andreas Kakridis
Affiliation:
Bank of Greece and Panteion University, Athens

Summary

This chapter is an overview of central banking developments between 1919 and 1939, highlighting the establishment and operation of 28 new central banks, most in what are now called emerging markets and developing countries. Inspired by expert advice and underpinned by foreign lending, the new banks were designed to function independently from political interference, and to defend the gold standard as part an international, rules-based network of cooperating institutions. The Great Depression revealed the flaws in this setup. As capital flows dried up and international cooperation faltered, the gold standard disintegrated, and central banks were unable to head off macroeconomic and financial collapse. Designed to fight inflation, they were ill-prepared to address financial fragility. In the wake of their failure, a two-pronged reaction set in. Central bank autonomy was curtailed, while monetary policy was subordinated to new policy objectives, including the support of import substitution in Latin America and central planning in Eastern Europe. At the same time, central banks’ powers expanded, as they were transformed into agents of state-led development policy. Thus, the new central banks of the 1920s and 1930s were integrally involved not just in post-First World War reconstruction and the Great Depression, but also in the key economic developments of the mid-20th century.

Type
Chapter
Information
Publisher: Cambridge University Press
Print publication year: 2023

1.1 Introduction

Central banks are ubiquitous. Of the 195 sovereign states in the world today, 185 have delegated money issuance, monetary policy, oversight of the payment system, and lender-of-last-resort functions to specialized institutions known as central banks.Footnote 1 Their pronouncements make headlines. These send tremors through money and asset markets, whose reaction central banks seek to channel using forward guidance and other communication. Ever-growing lists of their functions have entered college textbooks, as have tales of their exploits in helping countries navigate global financial shoals.

Such has not always been the case. A century ago, nearly two-thirds of the world’s sovereign states lacked a central bank (Figure 1.1). Central banking institutions then in existence commanded less authority. Their functions were circumscribed, their mandates ambiguous, their allegiances divided between multiple roles as commercial banks and appendages to the Treasury.

Figure 1.1 Sovereign states and central banks, 1820–2020

Source: See Appendix.

The key period of transition was the 1920s and 1930s. Between 1919 and 1939, twenty-eight new central banks were set up, most in what are now called emerging markets and developing economies. The studies collected in this volume examine the origins and early operation of these banks.Footnote 2

While an extensive literature documents the historical development of central banking in the now-advanced economies, the historical literature on central banking in emerging and developing countries, then and now, is more limited.Footnote 3 This imbalance deserves correction. Creating a central bank was seen as a key step in the process of modernization in late-developing economies. It was a step toward putting economic policy on a sound and stable footing and integrating emerging economies into the global system.

No sooner had the ink of newly drafted central bank statutes dried than the Great Depression swept across economies and political systems, putting new institutions to the test. Few interwar central banks successfully met the challenge. As a result of the political reaction to this failure, central banks became key agents in the Polanyian transition from the unfettered market system of the nineteenth century to the managed economy of the twentieth. In 1944, Karl Polanyi argued that the nineteenth-century combination of laissez-faire capitalism, unregulated labour markets, and the gold standard contained within it the seeds of this reaction, as popular opinion turned against the instability and inhumanity of market mechanisms (Polanyi, Reference Polanyi1944). New central banks had been established in the 1920s in an effort to temper the operation of this system. When they fell short (Schenk and Straumann, Reference Schenk, Straumann, Bordo, Eitrheim, Flandreau and Qvigstad2016), the economic and political crisis of the 1930s brought a Polanyian reaction. Private banks of issue were nationalized. Central banks were enlisted in managing the economy in cooperation with other branches of government. This set the stage for their role in supporting import substitution in Latin America and central planning in Eastern Europe during and after the Second World War. The newly established central banks of the 1920s and 1930s thus were integrally involved in the pivotal economic developments of the mid-twentieth century.

The ideas underpinning both the spread of central banking and the subsequent reaction are introduced in Chapter 2. Chapters 3 and 4 then focus on the role of the League of Nations and the Bank of International Settlements. These two organizations promulgated international standards for the structure and conduct of central banking (best practice, if you will) and sought to foster international cooperation amongst these newly created monetary institutions. Part II of the volume turns to eight country studies and two chapters of greater geographical ambition, one on Latin America and one on the British Dominions. All chapters nevertheless provide readers with the necessary political and economic background before tackling the key questions that run through the entire volume. Under what circumstances was each new bank established? What was the role of domestic and international players and how did they impact the structure, mandate, and powers of the resulting institutions? The authors are careful to distinguish de facto and de jure independence, as well as compliance (or otherwise) with the so-called rules of the game, which extended beyond the rules and regulations associated with the operation of the gold standard. All country studies discuss the impact of the Great Depression: the specific challenges to each economy, the monetary policy response, the extent to which policy was conditioned by each bank’s recent past, but also how it affected its future, not least by influencing the speed of economic recovery.

1.2 The Interwar Wave of New Central Banks

If not the father of all things, war was certainly the father of many of the new central banks of the 1920s. This was true of new states that emerged from the dissolution of the Habsburg, Ottoman, and Russian empires. It was equally true elsewhere, however, as old monetary arrangements were swept away and new banks were established.Footnote 4

Table 1.1 lists, in chronological order, the twenty-eight new central banks established between 1919 and 1939. Most of these institutions received statutory independence and a mandate to defend the value of the currency in terms of gold or gold-convertible foreign exchange.Footnote 5 As Harold James explains in Chapter 2, with extensive references to German experience, independence was designed to mitigate risks of fiscal and financial dominance that had become apparent with wartime and post-war inflation.Footnote 6 This, in a nutshell, was the argument behind the interwar drive to establish new central banks, and why most were established with the primary objective of averting inflation and maintaining the gold standard.

Table 1.1 Central banks established in the interwar years (in chronological order), 1919–1939

CountryCentral bankYearFootnote 1Interwar money doctors/foreign missionsFootnote 2
1YugoslaviaNational Bank of the Kingdom of Serbs, Croats, and Slovenes1920 [1884]Harry Arthur Siepmann, 1927
Banque de France, 1931
2South AfricaSouth African Reserve Bank1920Henry Strakosch, 1920*
Edwin Kemmerer and Gerhard Vissering, 1924–5
3LatviaBank of Latvia1922
4LithuaniaBank of Lithuania1922
5PeruCentral Reserve Bank of Peru1922 [1913]W. W. Cumberland (gov’t financial adviser, 1921–4*)
Edwin Kemmerer, 1931
6AustriaAustrian National Bank1923 [1816]LoN/Drummond Fraser, 1921; LoN/Arthur Salter, 1922*; LoN/Albert Janssen, 1923*; Francis Rodd (BIS) and Peter Bark (BoE), 1931; LoN/Carel Eliza ter Meulen and Otto Niemeyer, Reference Niemeyer1931.
Advisers: Charles Schnyder von Wartensee (1923); Anton von Gijn (1924–6); Robert Ch. Kay (1926–9); Gijsbert W. J. Bruins (1931–2), and Maurice P. Frère (1932–6).
7ColombiaCentral Bank of Colombia1923 [1905]Edwin Kemmerer, 1923* and 1930
8AustraliaCommonwealth Bank1924 [1920]Ernest Harvey (BoE), 1927
Otto Niemeyer (BoE) and T. E. Gregory, 1930
9HungaryHungarian National Bank1924 [1878]LoN/Arthur Salter and Joseph Avenol, 1923*
LoN/Henry Strakosch, 1924*
Advisers: Harry Arthur Siepmann (1924–6) and Henry J. Bruce (1931–6)
10PolandBank of Poland1924 [1918]Edward Hilton Young, 1923–4*
Edwin Kemmerer, 1925 and 1926
Adviser: Charles Dewey (1927–30)
11AlbaniaNational Bank of Albania1925LoN/Albert Calmès, 1922
LoN (indirectly)/ Mario Alberti, 1924–5*
Adviser: Jan Doekes Hunger, 1923–4*
12ChileCentral Bank of Chile1925Edwin Kemmerer, 1922, 1925,* and 1927
Adviser: Walter M. Van Deusen (1926–33)
13MexicoBank of Mexico1925Edwin Kemmerer, 1917*
14EstoniaBank of Estonia1926 [1919]LoN/Joseph Avenol and Alexander Loveday, 1925*
LoN/Albert-Édouard Janssen, 1926*
Adviser: Walter James Franklin Williamson
15CzechoslovakiaNational Bank of Czechoslovakia1926
16GuatemalaBank of Guatemala1926Edwin Kemmerer, 1919 and 1924
17EcuadorCentral Bank of Ecuador1927John Hord (gov’t financial adviser, 1922–6)
Edwin Kemmerer, Reference Kemmerer1926–7*
Adviser: Earl B. Schwulst (1927–8)
18BulgariaBulgarian National Bank1928 [1885]LoN/René Charron, 1926*
LoN/Otto Niemeyer, 1927*
Advisers: René Charron (1928–31), Jean Watteau (1931–2), Nicholas Koestner (1932–40)
19GreeceBank of Greece1928 [1920]LoN/Joseph Avenol, 1927*
Adviser: Horace G. F. Finlayson (1928–37)
20BoliviaCentral Bank of Bolivia1929 [1924]Edwin Kemmerer, 1927*
Adviser: Abraham F. Lindberg (1929–31)
21TurkeyCentral Bank of the
Republic of Turkey
1930Mr. Friedleb, 1927; Gerard Vissering, 1928*; Karl Mueller, 1929; Hjalmar Schacht, 1929*; Count Giuseppe Volpi, 1929*; Edwin Kemmerer, 1934
22EthiopiaBank of Ethiopia1931 [1906]Everett Colson (adviser to H. Selassie, 1930–5)*
23New ZealandReserve Bank of New Zealand1933Otto Niemeyer (BoE), 1930
24CanadaBank of Canada1934Lord Macmillan and Charles Addis (BoE), 1933*
25El SalvadorCentral Reserve Bank of El Salvador1934Frederick Francis Joseph Powell (BoE), 1934*
26ArgentinaCentral Bank of Argentina1935Otto Niemeyer (BoE), 1934
27IndiaReserve Bank of India1935Hilton Young Commission/Henry Strakosch, 1926*
28VenezuelaCentral Bank of Venezuela1939Hermann Max (Central Bank of Chile), 1939*

1. Years in [brackets] refer to the year a predecessor bank acquired de jure monopoly of issue in the country; when no such [year] appears, the new central bank was the first one to exercise such monopoly.

2. Missions comprising several experts are identified solely by the official who headed them, with additional details provided in corresponding chapters or notes; institutional affiliations are also noted, when relevant. LoN stands for League of Nations, BoE is Bank of England, and BIS is the Bank of International Settlements. Missions with an * are considered important for the establishment of the central bank.

Sources and notes on individual countries in the Appendix.

This mantra gained broad international currency, not least through the efforts of a network of central bankers, financiers, civil servants, and academics (Meyer, Reference Meyer1970; Schuker, Reference Schuker and Flandreau2003; Marcussen, Reference Marcussen2005). With missionary zeal the Bank of England encouraged the establishment of overseas clones of itself (Sayers, Reference Sayers1976: 201). Otto Niemeyer, senior Treasury official turned Bank adviser, was dispatched as money doctor to administer the appropriate medicine. Eager to check this British imperialism, the Banque de France launched missions to Romania and Poland.Footnote 7 The governor of the Federal Reserve Bank of New York, Benjamin Strong, shared Norman’s suspicion of politicians and his vision of a global network of cooperating central banks (Chandler, Reference Chandler1958: 281–285) and for his part encouraged American money doctors to spread the gospel. The most prominent American money doctor, Edwin Kemmerer, advanced this vision of central banking in Latin America and elsewhere on behalf of New York financial circles (Seidel, Reference Seidel1972; Drake, Reference Drake1989; Eichengreen, Reference Eichengreen, Calvo, Findlay, Kouri, de Macedo and Drake1989; Helleiner, Reference Helleiner2009).

Multilateral institutions such as the League of Nations also helped to disseminate new monetary ideology. Patricia Clavin (Chapter 3) explains how new ideas about central banking dovetailed with the League’s desire to limit state agency and relegate policy decisions to an international, rules-based depoliticized sphere. Intergovernmental conferences in Brussels in 1920 (under the League’s auspices) and Genoa in 1922 called on governments to return to the gold standard and establish central banks free of political control and open to cooperation. An Economic and Financial Organization (EFO) was set up within the League to gather intelligence and provide advice on economic and financial matters, including those related to central banking. Its representatives emphasized fiscal prudence, currency reform, and central bank independence, where the latter would be guaranteed by a statutory commitment to gold convertibility, limits on lending to the public sector, and a cap on state ownership.Footnote 8

Although the EFO projected itself as impartial and multilateral, it was close to London and the Bank of England in practice (Péteri, Reference Péteri1992). Its head, Arthur Salter, was British and had a collegial relationship with Norman. The US decision not to join the League tilted its scales toward London – much to the chagrin of the French, who remained suspicious of the League’s activities. These political tensions pushed central bankers away from the League and towards the Bank for International Settlements (BIS), which opened its doors in 1930 as a discreet venue for central bank cooperation away from meddlesome politicians (Toniolo, Reference Toniolo2005). As Piet Clement shows in Chapter 4, the vision behind the new organization extended far beyond the management of German reparations to functions previously performed by the League and that would later be entrusted to the Bretton Woods institutions.

1.3 Stabilization and Conditionality

New central banks were often set up in the effort to attract foreign capital. Bankers preferred lending to countries with a central bank on the gold standard. Hence developing countries eager to attract foreign capital could not afford to ignore their doctors’ prescriptions. Surveying Latin America for this volume (Chapter 12), Flores Zendejas and Nodari find no causal relationship between past macroeconomic performance and the establishment of new central banks; what mattered instead was the desire to attract foreign capital, which setting up a central bank promised to fulfil.

Similar considerations informed policy in Europe’s war-ravaged economies. With a trade surplus and no hyperinflation, policymakers in Czechoslovakia felt little pressure to tie their hands. But faced with the prospect of being excluded from international financial markets, they were coaxed into setting up a central bank, as Jakub Kunert explains in Chapter 8. In Chapter 11, Şevket Pamuk similarly describes how Turkish officials seeking to attract foreign investment invited foreign advisers, who paved the way for a new central bank in 1930.

Conditionality was strongest in supervised stabilizations. The League of Nations organized a string of programmes in the 1920s, four of which are covered by Hans Kernbauer (Austria, Chapter 5), Györgi Péteri (Hungary, Chapter 6), Andreas Kakridis (Greece, Chapter 9), and Roumen Avramov (Bulgaria, Chapter 10).Footnote 9 Austria was the first country to accept League assistance and submit to foreign control; this took the form of the appointment of a foreign commissioner in charge of fiscal policy and a foreign adviser to the new Austrian National Bank. The Austrian model was then exported to Hungary and Estonia. While Czechoslovakia and Poland also negotiated with Geneva, both ultimately rejected the League’s terms. Bulgaria and Greece were last to stabilize with the League’s assistance, their reforms tied to loans for refugee resettlement.

But conditionality was not unique to the League. As Cecylia Leszczyńska shows in Chapter 7, similar conditions underpinned Poland’s second stabilization in 1927, which was backed by the Federal Bank of New York and Banque de France and came on the heels of a Kemmerer mission. The abortive attempt by the BIS to stabilize the Spanish peseta in 1930, described by Clement, was taken from the same playbook.

Stabilization programmes, whether bilateral or multilateral, combined conditionality with external supervision. If independent central banks were meant to lend credibility to monetary policy, foreign enforcement was designed to enhance the credibility of stabilization and encourage fiscal and monetary rectitude.Footnote 10 Stabilization programmes could be painful and controversial. Political reaction was strong in Austria, for example, where stringent financial terms combined with heavy-handed intervention in the country’s relations with Germany; further, the role of international banks in the process fuelled antisemitism. In Hungary, the peg to sterling precipitated a painful Sanierungskrise in 1924–5; by 1926 an exasperated senior economist at the Hungarian National Bank complained to the League’s appointee, Harry Siepmann, that it might have been easier ‘to just gas Hungary with cyanide’ (see Péteri, Section 6.4). In Greece, controversies around stabilization toppled the coalition government, and calls for the abolition of the Bank of Greece persisted into the 1930s. In many ways, interwar adjustment programmes anticipated the post-1945 activities of the International Monetary Fund (IMF), in both their allegedly apolitical design and the political reaction they provoked.

A problem was the ‘one size fits all’ approach to stabilization and central bank design. Plans for new institutions derived from the experience of advanced countries were often ‘impracticable or even irrelevant’ to the problems of emerging markets.Footnote 11 As several chapters explain, shallow markets, combined with prohibitions on open-market operations aimed at preventing the indirect financing of public expenditure, limited the ability of central banks to control the money supply. The problem could be exacerbated by conflicts between the bank of issue and commercial banks (for example in New Zealand, Australia, and Argentina, among others) that previously possessed limited central banking powers. Such conflicts were acute when the new institution was not the sole treasurer to the state (as in Greece, Hungary, or Czechoslovakia). John Singleton calls central banks in this position ‘banks in waiting’. He attributes their weakness to money doctors who, eager to bind emerging markets to the gold standard, paid inadequate attention to the capacity of new central banks to provide services to their host governments and economies.Footnote 12

Did countries seeking to tap international capital markets have no choice but to adopt the model forced upon them? ‘Beggars cannot be choosers’ was Siepmann’s reaction to questions about the design of Hungary’s stabilization programme (Péteri, Section 6.3). His colleague in Greece, Horace Finlayson, noticed locals’ negative reaction to externally guided banking reform – how this reform was received with a mixture of suspicion and hostility. The new central bank was ‘nobody’s child’, an orphan placed on the country’s doorstep by foreign advisers. Questions of parenthood, or lack of programme ‘ownership’, as this problem is known in the literature on IMF adjustment programmes (James, Reference James and Flandreau2003), arose in several countries covered in this volume.

At the same time, external enforcement could be welcomed as a way of deflecting political fallout from reforms that domestic elites recognized as necessary but unpopular. This argument, made by Kernbauer (Chapter 5) for Austria, is implicit in a number of other instances described in these pages.Footnote 13 Foreigners, in addition to serving as convenient scapegoats, were instruments for settling domestic distributional conflicts. Domestic interest groups and foreign advisers, finding themselves in the same trenches, formed alliances. In Greece, for example, commercial banks were keen to use League of Nations advisers in support of their campaign to rid themselves of unprofitable state debt.

Sometimes, domestic resistance could be effective in checking foreign interference. Although Santaella (Reference Santaella1993) cites the absence of a single occasion when League of Nations’ advisers used their veto power as evidence of tough external enforcement (knowing that ambitious fiscal initiatives would be vetoed, no government dared implement them), this could equally be taken as evidence of the opposite. The correspondence between Niemeyer and Horace Finlayson, the British consultant charged with monitoring the Greek agreement, reveals a constant tug of war between Athens, London, and Geneva, sometimes resulting in the Bank of England and League of Nations having to agree to uncomfortable concessions. The ‘sneaking nationalization’ of Hungarian monetary management, over the objections of foreign advisers, is another example of how those responsible for the operation of these new institutions were sometimes able to deviate from their operational guidelines. In Bulgaria, domestic political opposition to privatizing the central bank, as advocated by foreign advisers, led to its indefinite postponement. Similarly, the Austrian National Bank systematically ignored its foreign advisers when providing liquidity to struggling banks.

1.4 Institutional Convergence?

By the late 1930s, central banks were operating in two-thirds of sovereign states, up from one-third in 1920 (Figure 1.1). Still, this appearance of institutional convergence masked the persistence of very different visions of central banking (Singleton, Reference Singleton2011: 58). If the League of Nations and leading central bankers envisioned an international network of cooperating banks tied to a liberal economic order, many new institutions were set up with nationalist and statist objectives (Helleiner, Reference Helleiner2003: 152).Footnote 14 Publics and politicians saw their central banks as symbols of national sovereignty. This was true of European successor states but also, for example, of Turkey, where money issue was wrested from the foreign-owned Imperial Ottoman Bank, marking the Republic’s break with the Ottoman past.Footnote 15 Inasmuch as new central banks were meant to attract foreign capital and investment, policymakers saw them as instruments of activist intervention rather than as constraints on government.

The tension between these visions is evident, for example, in the case of Britain and its empire. As Singleton explains in Chapter 13, by encouraging new banks of issue, London hoped to insulate monetary management from local political control and keep it within sterling’s orbit. The Dominions, by contrast, saw their new banks as a first step towards financial autonomy and active policy. Given this conflict over the meaning of independence, both sides risked disappointment.

But the struggle was not just between the metropolitan centre and colony but also within the metropolitan bureaucracy itself. G. Balachandran (Chapter 14) describes how early controversies surrounding the establishment of an Indian central bank reflected a power struggle between the Bank of England and the India Office. Both agreed on the importance of keeping Indians out of monetary affairs. But whereas the India Office insisted on direct control, Norman wanted policy in the hands of an institution free from the India Office’s political interference, but allied with the Bank of England. Decisions were postponed until the deflationary crisis of the 1930s made further delay untenable. India then became the first colony with its own central bank. But any illusions as to the true power of the new institution were dispelled when the India Office replaced the governor with a civil servant and in 1938 overruled a decision to devalue the rupee.

Colonialism distinguishes India’s case but also invites us, more generally, to think differently about central banks. One way or another, the new institutions were designed to remove management of monetary affairs from the domestic political arena at the very time when the latter was becoming more representative. Extension of the franchise, the rise of labour politics, and the growth of social spending after the First World War rendered governments more likely to prioritize employment over gold convertibility. As one money doctor put it: ‘the trend of political evolution the world over […] is in a direction which makes it less safe to entrust governments with the management of currencies than it may have been in pre-war days.’Footnote 16

If delegation to a technocratic body was meant to contain this problem, the results could be disappointing. The hope that political problems could be bypassed by institutional fiat proved an illusion. As several chapters reveal, the very process of de-politicization was political, not only in its motives, but also in its distributional consequences.

1.5 The Great Depression in Developing Economies – A Policy Dilemma

Many emerging markets and developing countries ran current account deficits in the 1920s, financing them with foreign – mainly US – capital.Footnote 17 After 1928, when stock market volatility and a shift in monetary policy brought US capital exports to a halt, debtors were forced to retrench. Countries reliant on US capital, such as Germany and Poland, slipped into recession even before the United States. Next came the collapse in commodity prices, precipitated by shrinking demand and dumping of supplies. Countries like Hungary, Poland, Bulgaria, Argentina, Australia, and Brazil, who specialized in agricultural exports, faced deteriorating terms of trade, falling incomes, and balance of payments difficulties. By 1931, most developing countries – including those that stabilized under League of Nations tutelage – were having trouble keeping current on their foreign debts. As capital- and commodity-market shocks compounded one another, the recession deepened and spread.

Deflation especially strained debtors, whose liabilities increased in real terms.Footnote 18 The pressure shifted to banks, and countries with weak financial systems experienced banking crises (Bernanke and James, Reference Bernanke, James and Hubbard1991). Emerging markets were vulnerable to these disturbances, especially in countries where banks financed long-term assets (for example loans and equity) with short-term foreign liabilities. When foreign capital fled, depositors followed, and banking crises morphed into currency crises.

In Europe’s successor states, the banks never fully recovered from hyperinflation or adjusted their business to new national borders. Austria’s crisis in May 1931 is the best known example, not least because it spread to Hungary and – once compounded by trouble in Germany – helped to push sterling off gold. The Creditanstalt debacle reveals how efforts to paper over bank troubles turned Austria into the weak link in Europe’s financial chain. But while domestic authorities may have been too soft on Austrian banks, Hans Kernbauer reminds us that foreign advisers were also too narrowly focused on fiscal and monetary discipline, to the neglect of financial fragilities. Back in 1924, they had vetoed an ambitious plan to re-capitalize Austria’s financial system on grounds of expense. With more radical measures off the table, mergers were instead used to paper over banking-sector weaknesses. This precarious financial edifice came crashing down in 1931.

More broadly, central banks designed to fight deficit-fuelled inflation were ill prepared to address financial fragility. Like the earlier institutions after which they were modelled, they did not consider prudential supervision as part of their mandate.Footnote 19 Nor did they have the expertise, information, and instruments needed to regulate the financial system. The Bank of Greece, for example, lobbied tirelessly for legislation requiring commercial banks to disclose detailed financial information and hold mandatory reserves, in a futile effort to control a market dominated by its predecessor, the National Bank.Footnote 20

Not that all new institutions were keen to police their banks. With more power came more responsibility, and a central bank responsible for commercial banks might be expected to act as a lender of last resort at times of crisis. Given a mandate to uphold the exchange rate at any cost, interwar central banks were at best ambivalent about this role. Intervention on behalf of the banking system invited speculation against the exchange rate; if investors feared devaluation, capital flight would undermine both the liquidity of the financial system and the central bank’s foreign exchange reserves. Thus, lender-of-last resort interventions were not only ineffective but could be counterproductive.

With the onset of the Depression, policymakers thus found themselves on the horns of a dilemma. The orthodox response was to stay on gold, raise taxes and discount rates, cut spending and credits, and thus preserve the foreign exchange necessary to maintain convertibility and service the country’s external obligations. This is what most countries did initially, while struggling to secure additional loans and re-negotiate existing liabilities, including war debts and reparations.

The alternative was to abandon the gold standard and reflate, prioritizing output and employment over the currency peg. But this was unappealing for countries that had struggled to return to international markets in the 1920s. Inasmuch as the gold standard inspired investor confidence, devaluation threatened access to foreign capital. Moreover, debtors with substantial foreign-currency liabilities would be hard pressed to avoid default if that debt was revalued, and default could trigger commercial retaliation if creditor nations imposed sanctions or raised tariffs.

There was also a third option, but it required international cooperation. Monetary expansion in surplus countries (as per the rules of the game), coordinated central bank intervention to support the exchange rate in countries facing financial distress, a general moratorium on debt and reparations payments, and even simultaneous devaluations could have mitigated adjustment pressures and deflation. But cooperation was hindered by divergent interpretations of the challenge at hand and divided opinions on such matters as war debts and reparations. Moreover, the very asymmetry inherent in the gold standard – that deficit countries felt pressure to adjust while surplus countries did not – undermined the symmetry of the international reaction.

Multilateral organizations, for their part, were little help. In Chapter 3, on the League of Nations, Clavin singles out the Gold Delegation’s inquiry into the operation of the gold standard, launched in 1928, as a turning point in the relationship between central banks and the League. Portrayed as technical, the inquiry inevitably acquired political overtones: any discussion of global monetary conditions raised questions about French and American gold accumulation that neither country wished to entertain. The Bank of England was not willing to jeopardize relations with the Federal Reserve, whose officials disapproved of the League’s proceedings and advocated moving the Delegation’s work to the BIS, newly created as a venue of central bank cooperation.

In the event, the BIS proved no more able than the League to muster a concerted response. An attempt in 1930 to provide credit facilities for investment faltered when the BIS’s Directors discovered that the Bank’s own liquidity was limited. A plan to finance a corporation to issue bonds and provide long-term credits was stymied by French concerns that it would drain capital from the Paris market. And the emergency loan to the Austrian central bank during the Creditanstalt crisis was only half what Austria requested and failed to stem the tide. Piet Clement asks whether these failures reflected difficult economic conditions or strained political circumstances. Without minimizing economic difficulties, he emphasizes the role of political conflict. Reparations were still outstanding, and the United States opposed any revision that might compromise its war debt claims. Opposed to the recently announced Austro–German customs union, France angrily scuttled proposals for a more ambitious Austrian rescue.

Left to fend for themselves, emerging markets could either defend the exchange rate at the expense of economic activity; or accommodate their economy and financial system at the cost of abandoning the gold standard. Most took the orthodox route at first, hoping to secure a trickle of foreign capital. But as the trickle dried up entirely, their position became increasingly untenable, and they began leaving gold. After sterling’s devaluation in September 1931, these departures became a stampede. By the summer of 1933, when US President Franklin D. Roosevelt decried the ‘old fetishes of so-called international bankers’, Poland was one of the last developing countries still on the gold standard, not least because of its political and financial ties with Paris.Footnote 21

Departures from gold took different forms (Table 1.2). Devaluation was most common. But in countries where inflation had been steep, devaluation evoked memories of hyperinflation. Such countries therefore chose to combine capital controls with protectionism in order to ration foreign exchange and/or alter the de facto exchange rate while maintaining the de jure price of currency in terms of gold. Both Bulgaria and Hungary resisted altering their official exchange rates but were drawn into elaborate clearing arrangements with Germany. The Turkish lira also spent most of the 1930s officially pegged to gold, enjoying nominal stability behind stringent controls. Developing countries choosing to devalue were in any case reluctant to let their exchange rate float, so they sought to join one of the emerging currency blocs into which the post-1931 world was fragmented (Urban, Reference Urban2009). Most British Dominions, with the exception of Canada, quickly joined the sterling area. Greece let the drachma float for a few months before re-pegging to gold and following the Gold Bloc from a distance. Chile and Colombia imposed exchange controls in 1931 and devalued in 1932, after which their currencies followed the dollar.

Table 1.2 The Great Depression and interwar central banks (in alphabetical order)

Dates of:
CountryCurrencyOfficial gold standard suspensionExchange control enforcementFirst devaluation/depreciation from par
1AlbaniaAlb. frank4/39
2ArgentinaPaper peso16/12/2913/10/3111/29
3AustraliaAust. £17/12/293/30
4AustriaSchilling5/4/339/10/319/31; 4/34
5BoliviaBoliviano25/9/313/10/313/30
6BulgariaLev15/10/31
7CanadaCanadian $19/10/319/31
8ChilePeso19/4/3230/7/314/32
9ColombiaPeso24/9/3124/9/311/32
10CzechoslovakiaKoruna2/10/3111/34; 10/36
11EcuadorSucre8/2/322/5/32–7/10/32;
31/7/36–31/7/37
6/32
12El SalvadorColon7/10/318/33–10/3310/31
13EstoniaKroon28/6/3318/11/316/33
14EthiopiaBirr
15GreeceDrachma26/4/3228/9/314/32
16GuatemalaQuetzal4/33
17HungaryPengö17/7/31
18IndiaRupee10/31
19LatviaLat28/9/368/10/319/36
20LithuaniaLitas1/10/35
21MexicoPeso25/7/318/31
22New ZealandNZ £21/9/315/12/384/30
23PeruSol14/5/325/32
24PolandZloty26/4/36
25South AfricaSA £28/12/321/33
26TurkeyTurkish lira20/11/30
27VenezuelaBolivar1/12/369/30
28YugoslaviaDinar7/10/317/32
Sources: See Appendix.

At this point, the choice between outright devaluation and the pretence of a gold peg, propped up by protectionism and exchange controls, became secondary. What mattered now was whether governments and central banks, having regained a modicum of monetary autonomy, opted to use it. Since many exchange-control countries had histories of high inflation, policymakers were often reluctant to reflate aggressively. Eichengreen (Reference Eichengreen1992) compares countries that devalued with those maintaining the façade of the gold standard behind exchange controls. He confirms that exchange control countries were more reluctant to increase money supplies.

Timing also mattered. Countries that unshackled themselves sooner recovered faster (Eichengreen and Sachs, Reference Eichengreen and Sachs1985; Campa, Reference Campa1990). The depth of recessions in Poland and Czechoslovakia, to mention the most obvious examples from this volume, illustrate the costs of waiting too long before abandoning gold.

1.6 Central Bank Fetters

Were central banks uniformly part of the problem that was the Great Depression? After all, these institutions had been designed to uphold the gold standard, whose failings contributed to the depth of the Depression. Indeed, Simmons (Reference Simmons1996) argues that greater central bank independence perversely increased the system’s deflationary bias: zealous to stave off inflation, central banks in surplus countries were reluctant to increase their money supplies. By sterilizing gold inflows they deviated from the ‘rules of the game’ and shifted the entire adjustment burden onto deficit countries.

This line of criticism, developed in the earlier literature, focused on leading central banks in industrialized nations, specifically France and the United States, rather than on newly established banks in emerging markets. We have already mentioned how many central banks in emerging markets often had little leverage over domestic credit conditions. In the early stages of the Depression this handicap was a blessing, insofar as they lacked the policy tools to engineer an even more powerful monetary contraction. Moreover, the handful of tools at their disposal was frequently used to mitigate, rather than exacerbate, deflation. This is apparent in their lender-of-last-resort interventions, which – as the Austrian example reveals – led to further drains of foreign reserves, as well as in a reluctance to let foreign exchange losses affect domestic circulation (see the cases of Hungary and Greece). Unlike France and the United States, most emerging markets were deficit countries, where breaches of the rules of the game were countercyclical and reflationary rather than deflationary.

Ultimately, of course, such interventions were futile: they could neither offset deflation nor continue indefinitely so long as gold convertibility was maintained. Eventually reserves would run out and the policy trilemma would bind, at which point exiting the gold-standard system might become irresistible (Obstfeld et al., Reference Obstfeld, Shambaugh and Taylor2004). Did new central banks affect the timing of these exits? The evidence doesn’t speak clearly. Flores Zendejas and Nodari point out that Latin American countries still without a central bank were actually first to devalue. Focusing exclusively on eight European countries with central banks, Wolf (Reference Wolf2008) finds that those with more independent institutions abandoned the gold standard earlier.Footnote 22 Wandschneider (Reference Wandschneider2008) expands the sample to twenty-four countries but finds no correlation between central bank independence and the decision to leave gold.

Different conclusions reflect different country samples, but they are also indicative of the difficulty of quantifying central bank independence.Footnote 23 Interwar money doctors, like modern quantitative economic historians, focused on bank statutes as their measure of independence.Footnote 24 Statutory provisions alone, however, cannot shield central banks from interference, any more than they can depoliticize an inherently political process.Footnote 25 This is especially true of newly established institutions, which have little time to build reputations or forge domestic political alliances.

Foreign allies, when present, failed to make up for this shortfall. This is not surprising: where statutory independence had been a symbolic gesture designed to placate foreign creditors, it was disregarded once international lending collapsed after 1929. In Czechoslovakia, for example, Jakub Kunert points out that the Banking Office, legally a department of the Ministry of Finance, was arguably more independent than its successor, the central bank, which was overruled by the government on exchange rate policy. In Poland, the regime of Józef Piłsudski eagerly awaited the term of the American central bank adviser to end so that it could ‘stage a war to subjugate the Bank of Poland to the government’ (Leszczyńska, Section 7.6). In Greece, the decision to stay on gold after sterling’s devaluation was taken by the prime minister, who dismissed the central bank governor.Footnote 26

Although distinguishing de facto from de jure independence is useful, doing so still doesn’t provide an unambiguous guide to 1930s gold-standard policy. Some independent central banks resisted political pressures to devalue, but others faced the opposite challenge of resisting pressure from the government to stay on gold. By 1929, Poland’s Piłsudski had effectively subjugated the central bank; its foreign adviser was gone, and a new governor, Władysław Wróblewski, had replaced his less compliant predecessor. As the recession deepened, the Bank of Poland recommended leaving the gold standard, only to be overruled by the government, Piłsudski insisting that a strong currency was needed to avoid inflation.Footnote 27 Similarly, Pamuk explains how the Turkish monetary authorities remained conservative in the 1930s despite autonomy from the government. Recalling high inflation during the First World War, they were unwilling to experiment with the lira.

This brings us to a central theme of this volume. Central banks are embedded within a broader network of institutions, political and societal relations, shared experiences, and ideas that shape their actions and effects (McNamara, Reference McNamara2002: 55). In this context, establishment of a new, independent central bank and subsequent pursuit of monetary orthodoxy, rather than one determining the other, may both reflect a deeper common cause. Harold James hints at this when he reaches back to Adam Posen’s (Reference Posen and O’Brien1993) seminal paper on the role of financial interests and history in creating a broader ‘culture of stability’ that explains both low inflation and central bank independence.Footnote 28 Memories of past inflation discouraged developing countries from leaving the gold standard in the 1930s, just as they had encouraged the establishment of independent central banks in the 1920s. Even where new banks were associated with more orthodox policy, the effect was not necessarily causal.

If the advent of new central banks does not explain subsequent policy choices, then what does? Why did some countries take longer to leave the gold standard than others? The possibility that they might be able to continue borrowing made some countries more patient, as we have seen. So did concerns over foreign retaliation in the event of a debt default. The association of the return to gold with national prestige discouraged politicians from sacrificing the political capital invested in stabilization. Interest groups standing to lose from devaluation defended orthodox policy, while those hurt by deflation pushed back (Frieden, Reference Frieden2014). Less democratic regimes were able to ignore such pressures for longest. In emerging markets, fear of inflation was compounded fear of floating (Calvo and Reinhart, Reference Calvo and Reinhart2002), which is why governments opted for capital controls and re-pegged after devaluing. It is why none of the countries discussed in this volume used their new-found freedom to pursue aggressive monetary expansion (cf. Mitchener and Wandschneider, Reference Mitchener and Wandschneider2015). The experience of the 1920s made policymakers err on the side of caution. The tragedy in the deflationary circumstances of the 1930s was that caution was the last thing required.

1.7 The Legacy

Surveying the landscape of interwar central banks, the Canadian economist Wynne Plumptre noted that ‘one of the primary tenets of accepted central banking thought has been the importance of keeping central banks politically independent’ (Plumptre, Reference Plumptre1940: 23). By the time this sentence was written at the end of the 1930s, it was already out of date. In the wake of the Great Depression, an event widely interpreted as signifying the failure of market liberalism, governments reclaimed the powers delegated to central banks.

Often, radical measures had to await a new government. Following sterling’s devaluation in 1931 and the shift from Labour to the new Conservative-led National Government, Norman noticed an ‘immediate redistribution of authority and responsibility’ from the Bank to the Treasury (cited in Clay, Reference Clay1957: 437; see also Kynaston Reference Kynaston, Roberts and Kynaston1995). In the United States, the Roosevelt administration pushed the central bank aside; a series of legislative reforms, starting with the Thomas Amendment granting the President the power to alter the dollar price in gold, curtailed the independence of the Federal Reserve.Footnote 29 Similar steps were taken by Leon Blum’s government in France shortly before the Gold Bloc unravelled in 1936 (Mouré, Reference Mouré2002: 221–226).

Central banks in emerging markets followed suit, as their recently acquired powers were returned to national governments. Governors were replaced; statutes were revised. In New Zealand, the Reserve Bank built at Niemeyer’s behest was barely two years old when the new Labour government nationalized it.Footnote 30 Most banks surveyed in this volume experienced a shift in the locus of power. Those that did not either had little power to begin with (as in India) or faced a divided government too weak to impose its will (for example Australia).Footnote 31

Signalling the ‘triumph of discretion over automaticity’, the departure from gold gave policymakers leeway to experiment (Cairncross and Eichengreen Reference Cairncross and Eichengreen1983: 4). In Latin America, central banks engaged in re-discounting and open-market operations in an effort to encourage reflation. These policies have been heralded as a reaction against money-doctor orthodoxy and a mark of monetary emancipation. But Flores Zendejas and Nodari argue that the reality was more complex, at least when it comes to Edwin Kemmerer, who himself became a champion of counter-cyclical monetary policy in the 1930s and nudged Latin American central bankers toward greater activism.

Simultaneously, the rise in state activism involved central banks in additional facets of economic policy. From the 1930s, they were called on to manage clearing balances and exchange stabilization funds, provide liquidity to the state and banking sectors, and refinance specialized credit institutions’ lending to farmers and industry. Tasked with administering exchange controls and clearing arrangements, they became agents of regulation and dirigisme. Their organizational charts and employee rosters expanded accordingly. The Bank of Greece, having started with a spartan staff of 400 in 1928, employed almost 2,200 people in 1940. Bulgaria’s Finance Minister noted in 1933 how the country’s ‘entire economic life [was now] concentrated’ in the hands of the central bank, a transformation that paved the way for its future role as the communist monobank (Avramov, Section 10.6). In the aftermath of banking crises, and now freed from the gold standard, central banks embraced their role of lenders of last resort. In some cases, that role extended to prudential supervision and bank regulation. Central banks took advantage of their new relationship to the state and of the swing of opinion against financial liberalism to consolidate their authority and tilt the balance of power away from commercial banks.Footnote 32

These late 1930s trends then were reinforced by the exigencies of the Second World War. Now fiscal dominance was expected, not abhorred. Following the war, acute dollar shortages threatened post-war reconstruction. Borders again were redrawn, while Britain and France became embroiled in a reluctant retreat from empire not unlike that experienced earlier by the Austrians and Ottomans. Interwar history seemed destined to repeat itself.

But this time was different. Thanks to memories of interwar experience, reparations and war debts were minimized. With the advent of the Cold War, the United States financed Europe’s trade deficit with Marshall Plan funds. The international monetary system was redesigned following Anglo-American blueprints negotiated at Bretton Woods. Exchange rates were again pegged, but now they were made more adjustable. Capital controls were authorized to shield countries from destabilizing hot money flows, and the IMF was charged with monitoring economic policies and helping countries with balance of payments difficulties. Much like its interwar predecessors, the Fund fashioned itself as an apolitical, rule-based agent of international cooperation. Continuity extended to personnel: Per Jacobson, an early member of the EFO staff transferred to the BIS in 1931, became IMF managing director in the 1950s.

For central banks, the end of the Second World War did not signal a return to earlier concerns over independence and financial liberalism. To the contrary, central banks coordinated closely with governments and continued to expand their range of responsibilities and interventions (Singleton, Reference Singleton2011: 128ff). Policy implementation now relied on direct controls (lending caps, reserve requirements, restrictions on bank asset holdings, and so on), while exchange controls provided leeway to pursue domestic policy objectives without sparking immediate balance of payments problems (Eichengreen, Reference Eichengreen2019). Policy outcomes were favourable, though whether this was a cause or consequence of the post-war golden age of economic prosperity is debatable.

In this new post-war environment, central banks possessed less independence but more power. Under Soviet-style central planning, the extreme case, they were fully integrated into the state-owned banking apparatus. But even elsewhere, emphasis on state intervention and modernization meant that central banks established in the 1920s and 1930s now became instruments of development policy, allowing the authorities to allocate credit and target industries in pursuit of economic growth. Before long, they were joined by another post-colonial wave of new central banks. The gold standard was gone, but the call at the 1920 Brussels Conference for all nations to establish their own central banks echoed down the years.

The coda then came in the 1980s and 1990s, as additional reforms were put in place in response to the failures (as well as the successes) of these credit-allocation and targeting policies, and specifically in response to the problem of accelerating inflation. This entailed renewed emphasis on the virtues of central bank independence (Bade and Parkin 1982; Alesina and Summers Reference Alesina and Summers1993). That emphasis manifested itself in steps to enhance the independence of established central banking institutions (the Bank of England, for example) and in the creation of new ones (the European Central Bank, arguably the most independent central bank of all). The reforms of the 1920s anticipated this contemporary paradigm. A look back at that history, through the lens of the studies that follow, sheds light on the circuitous route by which we got here.

Footnotes

1. Years in [brackets] refer to the year a predecessor bank acquired de jure monopoly of issue in the country; when no such [year] appears, the new central bank was the first one to exercise such monopoly.

2. Missions comprising several experts are identified solely by the official who headed them, with additional details provided in corresponding chapters or notes; institutional affiliations are also noted, when relevant. LoN stands for League of Nations, BoE is Bank of England, and BIS is the Bank of International Settlements. Missions with an * are considered important for the establishment of the central bank.

1 The definition implicit in this formulation is functional and cannot be applied uniformly or historically; many of today’s central banks started with a subset of these functions. Capie et al. (Reference Capie, Goodhart, Fischer and Schnadt1994: 5) bypass this hurdle by arguing that ‘in one sense, we recognise [central banking] when we see it’.

2 Of twenty-eight central banks established between 1919 and 1939, twenty-two are covered by the various country-specific case studies and comparative chapters in this volume. The list includes the Reserve Bank of India, even though India did not become a free nation until 1947 or adopt a constitution until 1950 (and thus is excluded from the interwar data underlying Figure 1.1). Countries not considered in this volume are Estonia, Yugoslavia, Latvia, Lithuania, Albania, and Ethiopia; for recent literature in English, see Troitiño et al. (Reference Troitiño, Kerkmäae and Hamulák2019) on Estonia, Jeftic (2021) for Yugoslavia, Puriņš (Reference Puriņš2012) on Latvia, Ahmetaj (Reference Ahmetaj, Anamali, Muka and Myftraj2017) on Albania, and Mauri (Reference Mauri2011) on Ethiopia.

3 Limited should not be misunderstood to mean non-existent. Holtfrerich et al. (Reference Holtfrerich, Reis and Toniolo1999) offer two chapters on central banks in emerging and developing countries. Contributions to Cottrell (Reference Cottrell1997) focus on Central and Eastern Europe. Maxfield (Reference Maxfield1998) covers the post-Second World War period, when central banks were set up differently in newly independent countries (also evident in our Figure 1.1). Earlier work includes Kirsch and Elkin (Reference Kirsch and Elkin1932) and de Kock (Reference de Kock1954), while very recent contributions include Jacome (Reference Jacome2015) and Caldentey and Vernengo (Reference Caldentey, Vernengo, Battilossi, Cassis and Yago2019). Distinct but related is scholarship on monetary management before the emergence of central banks (de Cecco, Reference de Cecco1975; della Paolera and Taylor, Reference Della Paolera and Taylor2001), and on so-called money doctors advising on the design of monetary institutions (Drake, Reference Drake1989; Flandreau, Reference Flandreau2003).

4 Other well-known aspects of the war’s financial legacy, such as the structural imbalances emanating from wartime shifts in producers, markets, and borders, the complications arising from reparations and inter-allied debt, the 1920–1 recession and countries’ diverse roads to stabilization are not discussed in this introduction, which has a narrower focus. Needless to say, these developments influenced the new institutions. Feinstein et al. (Reference Dertilis, Costis and Feinstein1995) offer a succinct summary.

5 This was the gold-exchange standard, which was meant to economize on scarce gold supplies; limits on the purchase of gold bullion to large quantities and the withdrawal of all gold coin from circulation were other aspects of the post-war gold standard (Eichengreen, Reference Eichengreen2019: 59).

6 Insulated from political interference and operating at arm’s length from business, central banks were designed to resist pressures to finance budget deficits and provide inflationary credits to the private sector. In modern parlance, central bank independence was expected to solve the problem of time-inconsistency by requiring commitment to monetary rules (Kydland and Prescott, Reference Kydland and Prescott1977; Barro and Gordon, Reference Barro and Gordon1983). Despite its ‘rediscovery’ in the context of rational expectations, the underlying idea was hardly new, especially in post-war years. Historical parallels date back at least as far to the central banks of Norway, Denmark, and Austria-Hungary, which were established after the end of the Napoleonic wars (Capie et al. Reference Capie, Goodhart, Fischer and Schnadt1994: 5). For a discussion of the German experience with central bank independence since the nineteenth century, see Holtfrerich (Reference Holtfrerich and Toniolo1988).

7 Pierre Quesnay and Charles Rist played important roles in the stabilization of the leu, while the latter also became an adviser to the Bank of Romania. Romania is excluded from Table 1.1 because the National Bank of Romania had been established in 1880, and the reforms carried out in 1929 did not produce a stark discontinuity – see Cottrell (Reference Cottrell and Gourvish2003), Mouré (Reference Mouré and Flandreau2003), and Chiappini et al. (Reference Chiappini, Torre and Tosi2019).

8 New institutions would be set up as private joint stock companies.

9 See League of Nations (1945); the only two cases not covered in this volume are Estonia and Danzig.

10 Santaella (Reference Santaella1993) sees League stabilizations as attempts to overcome commitment problems à la Barro and Gordon (Reference Barro and Gordon1983); in a similar vein, but with a modern focus, Reinsberg et al. (Reference Reinsberg, Kern and Rau-Göhring2021) discuss the IMF’s rationale and record of prescribing structural loan conditions to increase central bank independence. Whether conditionality is bilateral or multilateral may affect credibility and thus impact financial outcomes and access to credit; Flores Zendejas and Decorzant (Reference Flores Zendejas and Decorzant2016) make this argument explicitly for the interwar years and League stabilizations.

11 Triffin (Reference Triffin and Harris1944: 101); Triffin was writing about central banks in Latin America, but his point could easily be extended to the other countries examined in this volume. Plumptre (Reference Plumptre1940) makes the same argument about central banks in the Dominions; In Chapter 13 John Singleton reviews several of the interwar textbooks on central banking.

12 Flores Zendejas and Nodari counter that banks designed by Kemmerer missions were less rigid than those influenced by British money doctors, but neither were able to use conventional tools such as discounts and open-market operations to control their markets.

13 Similarly, several countries invited foreign intervention for reasons of foreign policy: Hungary sought British assistance to offset the pressure of the Little Entente; Poland turned to the United States and France to deflect territorial revisionism by Russia and Germany. But inasmuch as these examples substitute one form of leverage (financial) for another (foreign policy support), they are less revealing of ownership.

14 To be fair, Norman and Strong also hoped that the new institutions would bolster their own national currencies, not least by keeping their foreign exchange reserves with the Fed or the Bank of England, while using London and New York to raise new capital. Norman’s messianic zeal was thus also ‘for the good of sterling’ (see Péteri, Section 6.3). The Polish decision to base the złoty on the Latin Monetary Union franc, discussed by Leszczyńska, probably reflects similar motives.

15 Note how greater central bank independence, formally understood as autonomy from the state’s financial needs, thus took on several additional meanings: independence from other countries, independence from foreign capital, and so on.

16 Henry Strakosch to Basil Blackett, 17.10.1925; Treasury: Papers Otto Niemeyer, National Archives, T176/25B; see also Eichengreen (Reference Eichengreen1992: 31) and de Cecco (Reference de Cecco1994: 3).

17 This was part of the rebalancing of international payments that had occurred after the war, which undermined the stability of the gold standard. The United States became the largest international creditor. France and the United Kingdom remained net lenders, but their position was significantly diminished, while the rest of Europe became a net debtor, Germany absorbing more than half the capital inflows. Inasmuch as they recycled the dollars necessary to cover Europe’s current account deficit with the United States, US loans were crucial in maintaining interwar monetary stability – until they came to a sudden stop (Feinstein and Watson, Reference Feinstein, Temin, Toniolo and Feinstein1995; Accominotti and Eichengreen, Reference Accominotti and Eichengreen2016).

18 Czechoslovakia stands out among our case studies as a net creditor spared the initial impact of the ‘sudden stop’ in capital flows. But it was not spared from the debilitating effects of protracted deflation. In 1931, the country’s trade surplus turned to deficit. By the following year, industrial production was down 40% from its 1929 level.

19 De Cecco (Reference de Cecco1994) also points out that the US Federal Reserve, tasked with bank supervision, was a partial exception to this rule; this suggests another reason to distinguish between central banks set up by European and American money doctors (see Chapter 12, this volume).

20 A minimum reserve requirement had been inserted by Henry Strakosch in the original drafts of the 1927 stabilization plan negotiated in Geneva, but it was subsequently removed at the request of the Greek government, acting under the advice from the National Bank. When the proposal resurfaced in 1931, commercial banks resisted bitterly, going so far as to appeal to J. M. Keynes, who – clearly oblivious to Greek realities – suggested an agreement reached amicably between all parties, rather than through legislative fiat; the proposal was watered down in subsequent parliamentary debate.

21 On Roosevelt’s bombshell message and its effect on the World Economic Conference in London, see Clavin (Reference Clavin1992) and Eichengreen and Uzan (Reference Eichengreen, Uzan, Evans, Jacobson and Putnam1993).

22 Wolf (Reference Wolf2008) claims this was presumably because countries with more independent central banks were less worried about the potential loss of credibility from devaluation. But since a credible reputation is established by being hard-nosed, one could easily have expected the opposite to be the case – especially in the case of new central banks.

23 Not least because independence itself is open to different definitions; for a critique, see Hartwell (Reference Hartwell2018).

24 An important aspect of those statutes, in the eyes of British money doctors and the League of Nations, was setting up central banks as joint stock companies with private investors. Other measures included ceilings and prohibitions on state lending, long tenures for senior bank management (whose appointment was subject to government approval), and statutory mandates to maintain convertibility (Ulrich, Reference Ulrich1931; de Cecco, Reference de Cecco1994; Capie et al. Reference Capie, Goodhart, Fischer and Schnadt1994).

25 For critiques of the modern central bank independence literature in this vein, see Forder (Reference Forder1998 and Reference Forder2005) and, more recently, Hartwell (Reference Hartwell2018); the case of the US Federal Reserve is examined by Conti-Brown (Reference Conti-Brown2017), as well as by Binder and Spindel (Reference Binder and Spindel2017).

26 Nor did bank ownership matter. Australia’s state-owned bank was better at resisting political pressure than its privately owned counterpart in South Africa.

27 Polish monetary policy did not change until after Piłsudski’s death in 1935.

28 The fact that many interwar central banks were established after inflation had been brought down suggests that both monetary stability and central bank independence were caused by some deeper, structural effect.

29 A more radical economist, Marriner Eccles, was installed as Chairman in 1934 (Meltzer, Reference Meltzer2003: 415–486).

30 This was an extreme case: however widespread after the Second World War, central bank nationalizations were rare in the late 1930s, although the subordination of monetary policy to the Ministry of Finance was not. Denmark and Canada are the only other cases (Capie et al. Reference Capie, Goodhart, Fischer and Schnadt1994: 23), though some other statutory changes were equivalent to de facto nationalizations (Mouré Reference Mouré2002: 222).

31 Mexico’s reforms in the early 1930s, which sought to enhance central bank autonomy, are less an exception to the rule than a reminder that statutory provisions cannot guarantee de facto independence.

32 An interesting example from the developed world comes from Eccles’ initiatives and the passing of the 1935 Banking Act, which helped the Federal Reserve consolidate its power (Meltzer Reference Meltzer2003: 484–486); for a survey of bank supervision laws around the world, see Zahn (Reference Zahn1937); in most cases, supervision was shared with another public agency.

References

Accominotti, Olivier and Eichengreen, Barry (2016). ‘The Mother of All Sudden Stops: Capital Flows and Reversals in Europe, 1919–32’. Economic History Review, 69(2): 469492.Google Scholar
Ahmetaj, Lavdosh (2017). ‘Establishment of the National Bank of Albania and the Society for Economic Development of Albania (SVEA)’, in Anamali, Armela, Muka, Majlinda, and Myftraj, Ervin (eds.), Proceedings of 13th ASECU Conference on Social and Economic Challenges in Europe, 2016–2020, organized by Aleksander Moisiu University, 19–20 May. Durres, Albania: Aleksander Moisiu University, 510519.Google Scholar
Alesina, Alberto and Summers, Lawrence (1993). ‘Central Bank Independence and Macroeconomic Performance: Some Comparative Evidence’. Journal of Money, Credit and Banking, 25(2): 151162.Google Scholar
Barro, Robert J. and Gordon, David B. (1983). ‘Rules, Discretion and Reputation in a Model of Monetary Policy’. Journal of Monetary Economics, 12(1): 101121.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bernanke, Ben and James, Harold (1991). ‘The Gold Standard, Deflation and Financial Crisis in the Great Depression: An International Comparison’, in Hubbard, Glenn R. (ed.), Financial Markets and Financial Crises. Chicago: National Bureau of Economic Research, 3368.Google Scholar
Binder, Sarah and Spindel, Mark (2017). The Myth of Independence: How Congress Governs the Federal Reserve. Princeton: Princeton University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Cairncross, Alec and Eichengreen, Barry (1983). Sterling in Decline – the Devaluations of 1931, 1949 and 1967. Oxford: Basil Blackwell.Google Scholar
Caldentey, Esteban and Vernengo, Matias (2019). ‘The Historical Evolution of Monetary Policy in Latin America’, in Battilossi, Stefano, Cassis, Youssef, and Yago, Kazuhiko (eds.), Handbook of the History of Money and Credit. Singapore: Springer Nature, 953980.Google Scholar
Calderón, José Molina (2018). El Banco Central de Guatemala, 1926−1946: Antecesor del Banco de Guatemala. Guatemala City: Banco de Guatemala, Seminario de Investigadores Económicos de Guatemala.Google Scholar
Calvo, Guillermo A. and Reinhart, Carmen M. (2002). ‘Fear of Floating’, Quarterly Journal of Economics, 117(2): 379408.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Campa, José Manuel (1990). ‘Exchange Rates and Economic Recovery in the 1930s: An Extension to Latin America’. Journal of Economic History, 50(3): 677682.Google Scholar
Capie, Forrest, Goodhart, Charles, Fischer, Stanley, and Schnadt, Norbert (1994). The Future of Central Banking: The Tercentenary Symposium of the Bank of England. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Carrasco, Camilo (2009). Banco Central de Chile, 1925−1964: Una historia institucional. Santiago: Banco Central de Chile.Google Scholar
Chandler, Lester V. (1958). Benjamin Strong, Central Banker. Washington, DC: The Brookings Institution.Google Scholar
Chiappini, Raphaël, Torre, Dominique, and Tosi, Elise (2019). ‘Romania’s Unsustainable Stabilization: 1929–1933’. GREDEG Working Papers 2019–43, Université Côte d’Azur, France.Google Scholar
Clavin, Patricia (1992). ‘“The Fetishes of So-called International Bankers”: Central Bank Co-operation for the World Economic Conference, 1932–3’. Contemporary European History, 1(3): 281311.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Clay, Henry (1957). Lord Norman. London: Macmillan/New York: St Martin’s Press.Google Scholar
Conti-Brown, Peter (2017). The Power and Independence of the Federal Reserve. Princeton: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Cottrell, Philip (ed.) (1997). Rebuilding the Financial System in Central and Eastern Europe, 1918–1994. London: Routledge.Google Scholar
Cottrell, Philip (2003). ‘Central Bank Co-operation and Romanian stabilisation, 1926–1929’, in Gourvish, Terry (ed.), Business and Politics in Europe, 1900–1970: Essays in Honour of Alice Teichova. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 106144.Google Scholar
de Cecco, Marcello (1975). Money and Empire: The International Gold Standard, 1890–1914. Oxford: Blackwell.Google Scholar
de Cecco, Marcello (1994). ‘Central Banking in Central and Eastern Europe: Lessons from the Interwar Years’ Experience’. IMF Working Paper, October, WP/94/127, Washington, DC: International Monetary Fund.Google Scholar
de Kock, Gerhard (1954). A History of the South African Reserve Bank, 1920–52. Pretoria: J. L. Van Schaik.Google Scholar
Dedinger, Béatrice and Girard, Paul (2021). ‘How Many Countries in the World? The Geopolitical Entities of the World and Their Political Status from 1816 to the Present’. Historical Methods: A Journal of Quantitative and Interdisciplinary History, 54(4): 208227.Google Scholar
Delfino, Carlos Hernández (2020). ‘La creación del Banco Central de Venezuela’. Tiempo y Espacio, 38(74): 61119.Google Scholar
Della Paolera, Gerardo and Taylor, Alan (2001). Straining at the Anchor: The Argentine Currency Board and the Search for Macroeconomic Stability, 1880–1935. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.Google Scholar
Drake, Paul W. (1989). The Money Doctor in the Andes. Durham, NC: Duke University Press.Google Scholar
Eichengreen, Barry (1994 [1989]). ‘House Calls of the Money Doctor: the Kemmerer Missions to Latin America, 1917–1931’, in Calvo, Guillermo A., Findlay, Ronald, Kouri, Pentti J.K., and de Macedo, Jorge Braga (eds.), Debt, Stabilization and Development: Essays in Memory of Carlos Díaz-Alejandro. Oxford: Blackwell; reprinted in Drake, Paul W. (ed.) (1994). Money Doctors, Foreign Debts, and Economic Reforms in Latin America from the 1980s to the Present. Wilmington, DE: Scholarly Resources, 110132.Google Scholar
Eichengreen, Barry (1992). Golden Fetters: The Gold Standard and the Great Depression, 1919–1939. New York: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Eichengreen, Barry (2019). Globalizing Capital: A History of the International Monetary System. Princeton: Princeton University Press (third edition).Google Scholar
Eichengreen, Barry and Sachs, Jeffrey (1985). ‘Exchange Rates and Economic Recovery in the 1930s’. Journal of Economic History, 45(4): 925946.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Eichengreen, Barry and Uzan, Marc (1993). ‘The 1933 World Economic Conference as an Instance of Failed International Cooperation’, in Evans, Peter B., Jacobson, Harold K., and Putnam, Robert D. (eds.), Double-Edged Diplomacy: International Bargaining and Domestic Politics, Studies in International Political Economy, Vol. 25. Berkeley: University of California Press,171206.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Feinstein, Charles H., Temin, Peter, and Toniolo, Gianni (1995). ‘International Economic Organization: Banking, Finance, and Trade in Europe between the Wars’, in Feinstein, Charles H. (ed.), Banking, Currency, and Finance in Europe between the Wars. Oxford: Clarendon Press, 975.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Flandreau, Marc (ed.) (2003). Money Doctors: The Experience of Financial Advising, 1850–2000. London: Routledge.Google Scholar
Flores Zendejas, Juan H. (2021). ‘Money Doctors and Latin American Central Banks at the Onset of the Great Depression’. Journal of Latin American Studies, 53(3): 429463.Google Scholar
Flores Zendejas, Juan H. and Decorzant, Yann (2016). ‘Going Multilateral? Financial Markets’ Access and the League of Nations Loans, 1923–8’. Economic History Review, 69(2): 653678.Google Scholar
Forder, James (1998). ‘Central Bank Independence: Conceptual Clarifications and Interim Assessment’. Oxford Economic Papers, 50(3): 307334.Google Scholar
Forder, James (2005). ‘Why Is Central Bank Independence so Widely Approved?Journal of Economic Issues, 49(4): 843865.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Frieden, Jeffry (2014). Currency Politics: The Political Economy of Exchange Rate Policy. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Hartwell, Christopher A. (2018). ‘On the Impossibility of Central Bank Independence: Four Decades of Time- (and Intellectual) Inconsistency’. Cambridge Journal of Economics, 43(1): 6184.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Helleiner, Eric (2003). The Making of National Money: Territorial Currencies in Historical Perspective. Ithaca, NY: Cornell University Press.Google Scholar
Helleiner, Eric (2009). ‘Central Bankers as Good Neighbours: US Money Doctors in Latin America during the 1930s’. Financial History Review, 16(1): 525.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Holtfrerich, Karl L. (1988). ‘Relations between Monetary Authorities and Governmental Institutions: The Case of Germany from the 19th Century to the Present’, in Toniolo, Gianni (ed.), Central Banks’ Independence in Historical Perspective. Berlin, Boston: De Gruyter, 105159.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Holtfrerich, Karl L., Reis, Aaime, and Toniolo, Gianni (eds.), (1999). The Emergence of Modern Central Banking from 1918 to the Present. London: Ashgate.Google Scholar
Ibañez Najar, Jorge Enrique (1990). ‘Antecedentes legales de la creación del Banco de la República’, in Banco de la República (Colombia), , El Banco de la República: Antecedentes, evolución y estructura. Bogotá: Banco de la República, 194237.Google Scholar
Jacome, Luis (2015). ‘Central banking in Latin America: from the gold standard to the golden years’. IMF Working Paper no. 15/60.Google Scholar
James, Harold (2003). ‘Who Owns “Ownership”? The IMF and Policy Advice’, in Flandreau, Marc (ed.), Money Doctors: The Experience of International Financial Advising 1850–2000. London and New York: Routledge, 78102.Google Scholar
Jevtic, Aleksandar R. (2021). ‘Gold Rush: The Political Economy of the Yugoslavian Gold Exchange Standard’. Financial History Review, 29(1): 5271.Google Scholar
Kirsch, Cecil and Elkin, Winifred (1932). Central Banks, London: Macmillan.Google Scholar
Kydland, Finn E. and Prescott, Edward S. (1977). ‘Rules rather than Discretion: The Inconsistency of Optimal Plans’. Journal of Political Economy, 85(3): 473492.Google Scholar
Kynaston, David (1995). ‘The Bank of England and the Government’, in Roberts, Richard and Kynaston, David (eds.), The Bank of England: Money, Power and Influence, 1694–1994. Oxford: Clarendon Press, 1955.Google Scholar
League of Nations (1940). Statistical Year-Book of the League of Nations. Geneva: League of Nations Economic Intelligence Service.Google Scholar
League of Nations (1945). The League of Nations Reconstruction Schemes in the Inter-war Period. Geneva: Publications Department of the League of Nations.Google Scholar
Marcussen, Martin (2005). ‘Central Banks on the Move’. Journal of European Public Policy, 12(5): 903923.Google Scholar
Mauri, Arnaldo (2011). ‘A Nationalization of a Bank of Issue Carried Out in a Soft Way: The Case of the Establishment of the Bank of Ethiopia’. Working Paper No. 2011–01, Università Degli Studi di Milano Dipartimento di Scienze Economiche Aziendali e Statistiche, http://dx.doi.org/10.2139/ssrn.1740565.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Maxfield, Sylvia (1998). Gatekeepers of Growth: The International Political Economy of Central Banking in Developing Countries. Princeton: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
McNamara, Kathleen R. (2002). ‘Rational Fictions: Central Bank Independence and the Social Logic of Delegation’. West European Politics, 25(1): 4776.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
McQueen, Charles Alfred (1926). Latin American Monetary and Exchange Conditions. Washington, DC: Government Printing Office.Google Scholar
Meltzer, Alan H. (2003). A History of the Federal Reserve, Vol. I, 1913–1951. Chicago and London: University of Chicago Press.Google Scholar
Meyer, Richard Hemmig (1970). Banker’s Diplomacy: Monetary Stabilization in the Twenties. New York and London: Columbia University Press.Google Scholar
Mitchell, Jade (ed.) (2021). Central Bank Directory 2022. Riskbooks – Infopro digital.Google Scholar
Mitchener, Kris James and Wandschneider, Kirsten (2015). ‘Capital Controls and Recovery from the Financial Crisis of the 1930s’. Journal of International Economics, 95(2): 188201.Google Scholar
Mouré, Kenneth (2002). The Gold Standard Illusion: France, the Bank of France, and the International Gold Standard, 1914–1939. New York: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Mouré, Kenneth (2003). French Money Doctors, Central Banks, and Politics in the 1920s,” in Flandreau, Marc (ed.), Money Doctors: The Experience of International Financial Advising 1850–2000. London and New York: Routledge: 138165.Google Scholar
Naranjo Navas, Cristian Paúl (2017). ‘Fundación del Banco Central del Ecuador’, in Marichal, Carlos and Gambi, Thiago (eds.), Histoira bancaria y monetaria de América Latina (siglos XIX y XX): Nuevas perspectivas. Santander: Editorial de la Universidad Cantabria; Alfenas (Brasil): Universidade Federal de Alfenas, 397428.Google Scholar
Nodari, Gianandrea (2019). ‘“Putting Mexico on Its Feet Again”: The Kemmerer Mission in Mexico, 1917–1931’. Financial History Review, 26(2):223246.Google Scholar
Obstfeld, Maurice, Shambaugh, Jay, and Taylor, Alan M. (2004). ‘Monetary Sovereignty, Exchange Rates, and Capital Controls: the Trilemma in the Interwar Period’. Staff Papers – International Monetary Fund, 51(Special Issue): 75108.Google Scholar
Pankhurst, Richard (1963). ‘Ethiopian Monetary and Banking Innovations in the Nineteenth and early twentieth centuries’. Journal of Ethiopian Studies, 1(2): 64120.Google Scholar
Péteri, György (1992). ‘Central Bank Diplomacy: Montagu Norman and Central Europe’s Monetary Reconstruction after World War I’. Contemporary European History, 1(3): 233258.Google Scholar
Plumptre, Arthur F. W. (1940). Central Banking in the British Dominions. Toronto: University of Toronto Press.Google Scholar
Polanyi, Karl (1944). The Great Transformation. New York: Farrar & Reinhart.Google Scholar
Posen, Adam S. (1993). ‘Why Central Bank Independence Does Not Cause Low Inflation: There Is No Institutional Fix for Politics’, in O’Brien, Richard (ed.), Finance and the International Economy, Vol. 7. Oxford: Oxford University Press, 4065.Google Scholar
Puriņš, A¯ris (2012). ‘The Bank of Latvia, 1922–1940’, in The Bank of Latvia XC. Riga: Latvijas Banka, 4886, www.bank.lv/en/news-and-events/other-publications/bank-of-latvia-xc.Google Scholar
Reinsberg, Bernhard, Kern, Andreas, and Rau-Göhring, Matthias (2021). ‘The Political Economy of IMF Conditionality and Central Bank Independence’. European Journal of Political Economy, 68(2), 101987.Google Scholar
RIIA (1938). The Baltic States: Estonia, Latvia, Lithuania. Prepared by the Information Department of the Royal Institute of International Affairs. London, New York, Toronto: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Santaella, Julio A. (1993). ‘Stabilization Programs and External Enforcement’. Staff Papers – International Monetary Fund, 40(3): 584621.Google Scholar
Sato, Jun (2012). ‘The Bank of England Financial Advisory Missions to Latin America during the Great Depression: From the Perspective of the Periphery’, in Asia-Pacific Economic and Business History Conference. Canberra: Australian National University.Google Scholar
Sayers, Richard S. (1976). The Bank of England, 1891–1944. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Schenk, Catherine R. and Straumann, Tobias (2016) ‘Central Banks and the Stability of the International Monetary Regime’, in Bordo, Michael D., Eitrheim, Øyvind, Flandreau, Marc, and Qvigstad, Jan F. (eds.), Central Banks at a Crossroads: What Can We Learn from History? Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 319355.Google Scholar
Schuker, Stephen A. (2003). ‘Money Doctors between the Wars: The Competition between Central Banks, Private Financial Advisers, and Multilateral Agencies, 1919–39’, in Flandreau, Marc (ed.), Money Doctors: The Experience of International Financial Advising 1850–2000. London and New York: Routledge, 4977.Google Scholar
Seidel, Robert N. (1972). ‘American Reformers Abroad: The Kemmerer Missions in South America’. Journal of Economic History, 32(1): 520545.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Sember, Florencia (2018). ‘Challenging a Money Doctor: Raúl Prebisch vs Sir Otto Niemeyer on the Creation of the Argentine Central Bank’. Research in the History of Economic Thought and Methodology, 36: 5579.Google Scholar
Simmons, Beth A. (1996). ‘Rulers of the Game: Central Bank Independence during the Interwar Years’. International Organization, 50(3): 407443.Google Scholar
Simutis, Anicetas (1942). The Economic Reconstruction of Lithuania after 1918. New York: Columbia University Press.Google Scholar
Singleton, John (2011). Central Banking in the Twentieth Century. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Toniolo, Gianni (2005). Central Bank Cooperation at the Bank for International Settlements, 1930–1973. Studies in Macroeconomic History. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Triffin, Robert (1944). ‘Central Banking and Monetary Management in Latin America’, in Harris, Seymour E. (ed.), Economic Problems of Latin America, New York and London: McGraw-Hill Book Co, 93116.Google Scholar
Troitiño, David R., Kerkmäae, Tanel, and Hamulák, Ondrej (2019). ‘The League of Nations: Legal, Political and Social Impact on Estonia’. Slovak Journal of Political Sciences, 19(2): 7593.Google Scholar
Ulrich, Edmond (1931). Les principes de la réorganisation des banques centrales en Europe après la guerre. Paris: Librairie du Recueil Sirey.Google Scholar
Urban, Scott (2009). ‘The Name of the Rose: Classifying 1930s Exchange-rate Regimes’. Oxford University Economic and Social History Working Paper, No.76 (April).Google Scholar
Wandschneider, Kirsten (2008). ‘The Stability of the Interwar Gold Exchange Standard: Did Politics Matter?Journal of Economic History, 68(1): 151181.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Wolf, Nikolaus (2008). ‘Scylla and Charybdis: Explaining Europe’s Exit from Gold, January 1928–December 1936’. Explorations in Economic History, 45(4): 383401.Google Scholar
Zahn, Johannes C. D. (1937). Die Bankaufsichtsgesetze der Welt: in deutscher Sprache. Berlin: de Gruyter.Google Scholar
Figure 0

Figure 1.1 Sovereign states and central banks, 1820–2020

Source: See Appendix.
Figure 1

Table 1.1 Central banks established in the interwar years (in chronological order), 1919–1939

Sources and notes on individual countries in the Appendix.
Figure 2

Table 1.2 The Great Depression and interwar central banks (in alphabetical order)

Sources: See Appendix.

Save book to Kindle

To save this book to your Kindle, first ensure coreplatform@cambridge.org is added to your Approved Personal Document E-mail List under your Personal Document Settings on the Manage Your Content and Devices page of your Amazon account. Then enter the ‘name’ part of your Kindle email address below. Find out more about saving to your Kindle.

Note you can select to save to either the @free.kindle.com or @kindle.com variations. ‘@free.kindle.com’ emails are free but can only be saved to your device when it is connected to wi-fi. ‘@kindle.com’ emails can be delivered even when you are not connected to wi-fi, but note that service fees apply.

Find out more about the Kindle Personal Document Service.

Available formats
×

Save book to Dropbox

To save content items to your account, please confirm that you agree to abide by our usage policies. If this is the first time you use this feature, you will be asked to authorise Cambridge Core to connect with your account. Find out more about saving content to Dropbox.

Available formats
×

Save book to Google Drive

To save content items to your account, please confirm that you agree to abide by our usage policies. If this is the first time you use this feature, you will be asked to authorise Cambridge Core to connect with your account. Find out more about saving content to Google Drive.

Available formats
×