Book contents
- Frontmatter
- Contents
- Preface
- 1 The history of economic thought and its role
- 2 The prehistory of political economy
- 3 William Petty and the origins of political economy
- 4 From body politic to economic tables
- 5 Adam Smith
- 6 Economic science at the time of the French Revolution
- 7 David Ricardo
- 8 The ‘Ricardians’ and the decline of Ricardianism
- 9 Karl Marx
- 10 The marginalist revolution: the subjective theory of value
- 11 The Austrian school and its neighbourhood
- 12 General economic equilibrium
- 13 Alfred Marshall
- 14 John Maynard Keynes
- 15 Joseph Schumpeter
- 16 Piero Sraffa
- 17 The age of fragmentation
- 18 Where are we going? Some (very tentative) considerations
- References
- Index of names
- Subject index
15 - Joseph Schumpeter
Published online by Cambridge University Press: 22 September 2009
- Frontmatter
- Contents
- Preface
- 1 The history of economic thought and its role
- 2 The prehistory of political economy
- 3 William Petty and the origins of political economy
- 4 From body politic to economic tables
- 5 Adam Smith
- 6 Economic science at the time of the French Revolution
- 7 David Ricardo
- 8 The ‘Ricardians’ and the decline of Ricardianism
- 9 Karl Marx
- 10 The marginalist revolution: the subjective theory of value
- 11 The Austrian school and its neighbourhood
- 12 General economic equilibrium
- 13 Alfred Marshall
- 14 John Maynard Keynes
- 15 Joseph Schumpeter
- 16 Piero Sraffa
- 17 The age of fragmentation
- 18 Where are we going? Some (very tentative) considerations
- References
- Index of names
- Subject index
Summary
Life
Joseph Alois Schumpeter (1883–1950) is one of the most frequently quoted economists in our days. Above all, many recall his idea that the process of economic development is generated by a succession of innovations achieved by entrepreneurs with the purchasing power supplied to them by bankers.
The attractiveness of Schumpeter's ideas stems, at least in part, from their twofold political implications. On the one hand, they bring to the fore entrepreneurs and bankers, the leading actors of the development process; at the same time, Schumpeter opposed Keynesian-type policy activism and considered crises a necessary evil, needed to stimulate the very vitality of capitalism. On the other hand, the view of a dynamic process endogenous to the economy and society, and of the decay of capitalism as the inevitable outcome of such dynamics, seems to align Schumpeter with Marx against the traditional theorising of economic equilibrium.
Schumpeter's thought is, however, far more complex and richer in lights and shadows than these contrasting evaluations might suggest. What remains truly alive today is the objective he propounds for economic science, namely to start from solid theoretical foundations and accomplish a theory of social change. As we shall see in § 2, in order to make headway along this road Schumpeter proposed as methodological canon the maximum possible flexibility: his theoretical building, extensive and complex, is made up of ‘analytical bricks’ bound together by a common pre-analytical view: not by a formally unified scheme, but by a broad representation of economic life.
- Type
- Chapter
- Information
- The Wealth of IdeasA History of Economic Thought, pp. 416 - 434Publisher: Cambridge University PressPrint publication year: 2005