Skip to main content Accessibility help
×
Hostname: page-component-77c89778f8-7drxs Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-07-22T13:23:12.529Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

1 - The Problem: Commerce and Corruption

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  06 November 2009

Ryan Patrick Hanley
Affiliation:
Marquette University, Wisconsin
Get access

Summary

SMITH'S DEFENSE OF COMMERCIAL SOCIETY

The following study focuses on Smith's understanding of the ills of commercial society and the response to these ills he set forth in order to maximize commercial society's benefits. Yet the very fact that Smith spent such effort on this problem suggests the depth of two convictions on his part (and perhaps suspicions on ours): first, that commercial society is too entrenched to be readily removed and replaced; and second, that commercial society, for all its possible shortcomings, remains very much worth saving given the magnitude of its benefits. So as not to lose sight of his steadfast and indeed unambivalent dedication to commercial society we would thus do well to begin by restating the specific benefits that prompted such dedication from Smith. They are two: first, commercial society's relief of poverty through the increases it makes possible in the material welfare of all; and second, commercial society's promotion of freedom by substituting interdependence for the direct dependence characteristic of social relations in earlier political and economic orders.

With respect to the first point, an ever-growing consensus has emerged among recent scholars that Smith was dedicated to the alleviation of poverty. I want to restate and extend this claim by calling particular attention to a less-emphasized but central element of this concern: namely, the confluence of Smith's emphasis on the vulgarity of the selfishness of the rich and his emphasis on its material benefits for the innocent poor.

Type
Chapter
Information
Publisher: Cambridge University Press
Print publication year: 2009

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

References

Hont, Istvan and Ignatieff, Michael, “Needs and Justice in the Wealth of Nations: An Introductory Essay,” in Wealth and Virtue: The Shaping of Political Economy in the Scottish Enlightenment, ed. Hont, and Ignatieff, (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1983), 1–44CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Himmelfarb, Gertrude, The Idea of Poverty: England in the Early Industrial Age (New York: Knopf, 1984), 42–63Google Scholar
Muller, Jerry Z., Adam Smith In His Time and Ours: Designing the Decent Society (Princeton: Princeton University Press, 1993), esp. 8, 58, 72–73Google Scholar
Rothschild, Emma, Economic Sentiments: Adam Smith, Condorcet, and the Enlightenment (Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press, 2001), 62–71Google Scholar
Fleischacker, Samuel, A Third Concept of Liberty: Judgment and Freedom in Kant and Adam Smith (Princeton: Princeton University Press, 1999), 161–83Google Scholar
Rothschild, and Sen, Amartya, “Adam Smith's Economics,” in Cambridge Companion, 319–65
Smith, “is on the side of the men, who are less powerful and far more desperate than their masters” (The Enlightenment: An Interpretation, vol. 2: The Science of Freedom (New York: Norton, 1996), 365)Google Scholar
Pack, Spencer, Capitalism as a Moral System: Adam Smith's Critique of the Free Market Economy (London: Edward Elgar, 1991), 4, 140–42Google Scholar
Muller, , “The Portrait and the Painter,” Adam Smith Review 2 (2006): 229–30Google Scholar
Hont, , Jealousy of Trade: International Competition and the Nation-State in Historical Perspective (Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press, 2005), 91–99Google Scholar
Ignatieff, , “Smith, Rousseau, and the Republic of Needs,” in Scotland and Europe 1200–1850, ed. Smout, T. C. (Edinburgh: John Donald, 1986), 192Google Scholar
Phillipson, Nicholas, “Adam Smith as Civic Moralist,” in Wealth and Virtue, 188, 194, 200–201
Berry, Christopher, “Adam Smith: Commerce, Liberty and Modernity,” in Philosophers of the Enlightenment, ed. Gilmour, Peter (Edinburgh: Edinburgh University Press, 1989), 114–18Google Scholar
Schliesser, Eric, “Adam Smith's Benevolent and Self-Interested Conception of Philosophy,” in New Voices on Adam Smith, ed. Montes, and Schliesser, (London: Routledge, 2006), 346–47, 351Google Scholar
Hill, , “Adam Smith, Adam Ferguson and Karl Marx on the Division of Labour,” Journal of Classical Sociology 7 (2007): 346–47CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Fleischacker, , A Short History of Distributive Justice (Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press, 2004), esp. 4, 12–13, 17–19, 37–40, 62–68Google Scholar
Schliesser, Eric, “Wonder in the Face of Scientific Revolutions: Adam Smith on Newton's ‘Proof’ of Copernicanism,” British Journal for the History of Philosophy 13 (2005): 697–732CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Pack, and Schliesser, , “Smith's Humean Criticism of Hume's Account of the Origin of Justice,” Journal of the History of Philosophy 44 (2006): 47–63CrossRefGoogle Scholar
“Social Science and Humanism,” in The Rebirth of Classical Political Rationalism (Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 1989), 6
Mises, Ludwig, The Anti-capitalistic Mentality (Indianapolis: Liberty Fund, 2006 [1956]), 45Google Scholar
Pocock, , The Machiavellian Moment: Florentine Political Thought and the Atlantic Republican Tradition (Princeton: Princeton University Press, 1975)Google Scholar
Jack, Malcolm, Corruption and Progress: The Eighteenth-Century Debate (New York: AMS Press, 1989)Google Scholar
Hont, Istvan, “The Early Enlightenment Debate on Commerce and Luxury,” in The Cambridge History of Eighteenth-Century Political Thought, ed. Goldie, Mark and Wokler, Robert (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 2006), 379–418Google Scholar
Pangle, Thomas, “The Retrieval of Civic Virtue: A Critical Appreciation of Sandel's Democracy's Discontent,” in Debating Democracy's Discontent, ed. Allen, Anita L. and Regan, Jr. Milton C. (Oxford: Oxford University Press, 1998), 17–31CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Pocock, , Barbarism and Religion (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1999), vol. 3, p. 375)CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lerner, Ralph, “Commerce and Character: The Anglo-American as New-Model Man,” William and Mary Quarterly (1979)CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lerner, , The Thinking Revolutionary: Principle and Practice in the New Republic (Ithaca: Cornell University Press, 1987), 195, 202Google Scholar
Smith, Brian, “Adam Smith, the Concept of Leisure, and the Division of Labor,” Interpretation 34 (2006): 44Google Scholar
Danford, John, “Adam Smith, Equality, and the Wealth of Sympathy,” American Journal of Political Science 24 (1980): 688–89CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Viner, Jacob, Guide to John Rae's ‘Life of Adam Smith’ (New York: Augustus Kelley, 1965), 35–36Google Scholar
Raphael, , Adam Smith (Oxford: Oxford University Press, 1985), 71–72, 80Google Scholar
Wokler, , Rousseau (Oxford: Oxford University Press, 2001), 44CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lomonaco, Jeffrey, “Adam Smith's ‘Letter to the Authors of the Edinburgh Review’,” Journal of the History of Ideas 63 (2002): 659–76CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Colletti, Lucio, From Rousseau to Lenin (New York: New Left Books, 1972), 155–63, 195–215Google Scholar
Ignatieff, Michael, The Needs of Strangers (London: Picador, 1984), 107–31Google Scholar
Leigh, R. A., “Rousseau and the Scottish Enlightenment,” Contributions to Political Economy 5 (1986): 1–21CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Winch, Donald, Riches and Poverty: An Intellectual History of Political Economy in Britain, 1750–1834 (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1996), esp. 60, 66–75Google Scholar
Force, Pierre, Self-Interest Before Adam Smith: A Genealogy of Economic Science (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 2003), 20–47, 121–25, and 154–68CrossRefGoogle Scholar
From Geneva to Glasgow: Rousseau and Adam Smith on the Theater and Commercial Society,” Studies in Eighteenth-Century Culture 35 (2006): 183–211
Commerce and Corruption: Rousseau's Diagnosis and Adam Smith's Cure,” European Journal of Political Theory 7 (2008): 137–58CrossRef
Enlightened Nation Building: The ‘Science of the Legislator’ in Adam Smith and Rousseau,” American Journal of Political Science 52 (2008): 219–34CrossRef
Löwith, Karl, From Hegel to Nietzsche: The Revolution in Nineteenth-Century Thought, trans. Green, David E. (New York: Holt, Rinehart and Winston, 1964), 235–40, 260–62Google Scholar
Melzer, Arthur M., “Rousseau and the Problem of Bourgeois Society,” American Political Science Review 74 (1980): 1018–33CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Melzer, , The Natural Goodness of Man (Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 1990), 63–68Google Scholar
Bloom, Allan, Giants and Dwarfs: Essays, 1960–1990 (New York: Simon and Schuster, 1990), 179–81 and 211–13Google Scholar
Dannhauser, Werner, “The Problem of the Bourgeois,” in The Legacy of Rousseau, ed. Orwin, Clifford and Tarcov, Nathan (Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 1997)Google Scholar
Cooper, Laurence D., Rousseau, Nature, and the Problem of the Good Life (University Park, PA: Pennsylvania State University Press, 1999), 117–18Google Scholar
Rousseau, , “Discourse on the Origin of Inequality,” in The Discourses and Other Early Political Writings, trans. Gourevitch, Victor (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1997), 170–71Google Scholar
“The Paradox of Progress: Decline and Decay in The Wealth of Nations,” in Essays on Adam Smith, ed. Skinner, Andrew S. and Wilson, Thomas (Oxford: Clarendon Press, 1975), esp. 524, 528–32
Werhane, Patricia H., Adam Smith and His Legacy for Modern Capitalism (Oxford: Oxford University Press, 1991), 168–73Google Scholar
Adam Smith's Critique of International Trading Companies: Theorizing ‘Globalization’ in the Age of Enlightenment,” Political Theory 36 (2008): 185–212CrossRef
The Marx-Engels Reader, ed. Tucker, Robert C., 2nd ed. (New York: Norton, 1978), I.xiv.4–5, pp. 394, 399–400
Karl Marx: Selected Writings, ed. McLellan, David, 2nd ed. (Oxford: Oxford University Press, 2000), 402–5
Rosenberg, Nathan, “Adam Smith on the Division of Labour: Two Views or One?” Economica (new ser.) 32 (1965): 127–39CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lamb, Robert, “Adam Smith's Concept of Alienation,” Oxford Economic Papers 25 (1973): 275–85CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Meek, Ronald L., “Smith and Marx,” in Smith, Marx, and After (London: Chapman and Hall, 1977), 3–17CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hirschman, Albert O., The Passions and the Interests: Political Arguments for Capitalism Before Its Triumph (Princeton: Princeton University Press, 1997 [1977]), 100–13, esp. 105–6Google Scholar
Ignatieff, , “Smith, Rousseau and the Republic of Needs,” in Scotland and Europe, ed. Smout, , esp. 188, 197
Hont, and Ignatieff, , “Needs and Justice,” in Wealth and Virtue, ed. Hont, and Ignatieff, , 6–8, 43–44
Phillipson, , “Smith as Civic Moralist,” in Wealth and Virtue, esp. 179–81
Berry, , “Adam Smith and the Virtues of Commerce,” in NOMOS XXXIV: Virtue, 75, 82–84
Harpham, Edward J., “Liberalism, Civic Humanism, and the Case of Adam Smith,” American Political Science Review 78 (1984): 764–74CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Winch, , “Adam Smith and the Liberal Tradition,” in Traditions of Liberalism: Essays on John Locke, Adam Smith and John Stuart Mill, ed. Haakonssen, Knud (St. Leonards, New South Wales: Centre for Independent Studies, 1988), 89Google Scholar
Winch, , “Commercial Realities, Republican Principles,” in Republicanism: A Shared European Heritage, ed. Skinner, Quentin and Gelderen, Martin (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 2002), vol. 2, pp. 294–96Google Scholar
Berry, , “Smith Under Strain,” European Journal of Political Theory 3 (2004): 455CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Robertson, John, The Case for the Enlightenment: Scotland and Naples 1680–1760 (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 2005), 394–96CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Rousseau, , “Fragments politiques,” in Œuvres complètes, ed. Gagnebin, Bernard and Raymond, Marcel (Paris: Gallimard, Bibliothèque de la Pléiade, 1959–95), vol. 3, p. 502Google Scholar
Lovejoy, Arthur O., Reflections on Human Nature (Baltimore: Johns Hopkins University Press, 1961), 208–15; cf. 150, 190–91Google Scholar
West, Edwin G., “Adam Smith and Rousseau's Discourse on Inequality: Inspiration or Provocation?” Journal of Economic Issues 5 (1971): 64CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Force, , “Self-Love, Identification, and the Origin of Political Economy,” Yale French Studies 92 (1997): 57–58Google Scholar
Todorov, Tzvetan, “Living Alone Together,” New Literary History 27 (1996): 6CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Fraser, Nancy and Honneth, Axel, Redistribution or Recognition? A Political-Philosophical Exchange (London: Verso, 2003)Google Scholar
Brennan, Geoffrey and Pettit, Philip, The Economy of Esteem: An Essay on Civil and Political Society (Oxford: Oxford University Press, 2004)CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Greenfeld, Liah, “When the Sky Is the Limit: Busyness in Contemporary American Society,” Social Research 72 (2005): 315–38Google Scholar
Otteson, , “Unintended Order Explanations in Adam Smith and the Scottish Enlightenment,” in Liberalism, Conservatism, and Hayek's Idea of Spontaneous Order, ed. Hunt, Louis and McNamara, Peter (London: Palgrave Macmillan, 2007), esp. pp. 21, 25, 30CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hope, Vincent, “Smith's Demigod,” in Philosophers of the Scottish Enlightenment, ed. Hope, (Edinburgh: Edinburgh University Press, 1984), esp. 157, 160, 166Google Scholar
“Theory and Discourse: The 6th Edition of The Theory of Moral Sentiments,” in Virtuous Discourse (Edinburgh: John Donald, 1987), p. 183)
“analytical hierarchicalism” (The “Vanity of the Philosopher”: From Equality to Hierarchy in Post-Classical Economics (Ann Arbor: University of Michigan Press, 2005), xvi
Parfit, Derek, “Equality or Priority?” Ratio 10 (1997): 201–20CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Rousseau, , Letter to d'Alembert, trans. Bloom, (Ithaca: Cornell University Press, 1960), 135–6nGoogle Scholar
Manent, , Tocqueville and the Nature of Democracy, trans. Waggoner, John (Lanham, MD: Rowman and Littlefield, 1996), 48–52, 61–65Google Scholar
Nieli, Russell, “Spheres of Intimacy and the Adam Smith Problem,” Journal of the History of Ideas 47 (1986): 611–24CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Heath, Eugene, “The Commerce of Sympathy: Adam Smith on the Emergence of Morals,” Journal of the History of Philosophy 33 (1995): 447–66CrossRefGoogle Scholar

Save book to Kindle

To save this book to your Kindle, first ensure coreplatform@cambridge.org is added to your Approved Personal Document E-mail List under your Personal Document Settings on the Manage Your Content and Devices page of your Amazon account. Then enter the ‘name’ part of your Kindle email address below. Find out more about saving to your Kindle.

Note you can select to save to either the @free.kindle.com or @kindle.com variations. ‘@free.kindle.com’ emails are free but can only be saved to your device when it is connected to wi-fi. ‘@kindle.com’ emails can be delivered even when you are not connected to wi-fi, but note that service fees apply.

Find out more about the Kindle Personal Document Service.

Available formats
×

Save book to Dropbox

To save content items to your account, please confirm that you agree to abide by our usage policies. If this is the first time you use this feature, you will be asked to authorise Cambridge Core to connect with your account. Find out more about saving content to Dropbox.

Available formats
×

Save book to Google Drive

To save content items to your account, please confirm that you agree to abide by our usage policies. If this is the first time you use this feature, you will be asked to authorise Cambridge Core to connect with your account. Find out more about saving content to Google Drive.

Available formats
×